View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Connecting the Dots on Monetary Policy

Charles L. Evans
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Wisconsin Economic Forecast Luncheon
Wisconsin Bankers Association
Madison, Wisc.
January 7, 2016

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CHICAGO
The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
Those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

Connecting the Dots on Monetary Policy
Charles L. Evans
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago

Introduction
Good afternoon and thank you. Before I begin my remarks today, I should note that my
comments reflect my own views and do not necessarily represent those of my
colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) or within the Federal
Reserve System.
For me, the start of each new year marks a time for contemplating the past and for
looking forward to the future. As many of you likely do, I begin each year optimistically,
resolving to do things better, such as exercising more and eating more healthily. But as
the months pass, I generally get sidetracked, despite the best of intentions. Of course,
this is the year it will be different.
Recently, when I was putting together my forecast for the economy, I was struck by the
realization that in each of the past six years I began with an optimistic view of how fast
the economy was going to grow — only to be disappointed with the numbers coming in
below my projections. To be candid, my batting average has been similar to my
forecasts for exercise and healthy eating. For example, as 2015 began, I was expecting
growth for the year to be in the range of 2-1/2 to 3 percent. Instead, it looks like real
gross domestic product (GDP) rose roughly 2 percent. As errors go, this isn’t a
particularly big one. But it is a noticeable one, and continues a string of downside
misses that, frankly, has been getting tiresome.
So what about this year? Well, I’ve scaled things back a bit, and anticipate the economy
will grow in the range of 2 to 2-1/2 percent in 2016. So, close to or a bit better than this
past year. I also expect the unemployment rate to come down a couple of tenths and
end the year at about 4-3/4 percent.
The central point underlying my forecast is that the fundamentals for most components
of domestic spending are good. Most importantly, we’ve seen a substantial
improvement in labor markets over the past several years. The unemployment rate is
currently 5.0 percent; that’s down from its high of 10.0 percent in late 2009. Let me put
this into context: One of the two goals for Federal Reserve policy mandated by
Congress is to help the economy achieve maximum employment. Along with most of my
colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee, I judge that maximum employment
is consistent with an unemployment rate that averages a little under 5 percent over the
longer run. Now a few other labor market indicators — such as the large number of
people who are employed part time but who would prefer a full-time job and subdued
wage growth — suggest there remains some additional resource slack beyond what is
indicated by the unemployment rate alone. So I don’t think we have quite met our
employment mandate. But we certainly have made great progress toward meeting that
goal.
2

Healthy labor markets portend continued job gains, growth in households’ income, and
buoyant consumer confidence. These developments, along with low energy prices and
some further increases in household wealth, should support fairly solid gains in
consumer spending. Furthermore, as I’ll talk about more in a minute, my forecast also
assumes interest rates will stay quite low for some time. This should help bolster
consumer spending — for example, low borrowing rates helped push new motor vehicle
sales in 2015 to near-record levels. Healthy labor markets and low interest rates will
also help housing markets. Indeed, although new home building still remains below
what would be considered normal, growth in residential investment has picked up over
the past couple of quarters. Another plus for domestic spending is that the recent
budget deal should mean we’ll see a modest increase in federal spending this year.
Developments abroad, however, are offsetting the positive momentum in domestic
fundamentals to some degree. The slow-down in global economic growth — notably in
emerging markets — and uncertainty about future prospects have contributed to a rising
dollar and declining commodity prices over the past two years. As a result, U.S.
manufacturers and agricultural producers that sell their products in global markets face
challenges — as do oil, gas and mining companies and their suppliers. That said, if
foreign growth prospects and the dollar stabilize, as most expect, these headwinds on
domestic growth should dissipate. Still, we should not expect the international sector to
be an engine for U.S. growth for some time.
My Growth Forecast in Context
Now, by historical standards, GDP growth in the range of 2 to 2-1/2 percent doesn’t
seem particularly optimistic. It’s in line with the average annualized growth rate of 2.2
percent since the end of the Great Recession. By comparison, GDP growth averaged
closer to an annual rate of 3.5 percent over the previous three expansions. What’s
going on?
Of course, the financial crisis and the ensuing Great Recession had far-reaching
negative effects. And even though we’ve come a long way in healing those wounds,
some related headwinds still remain and will take some time to dissipate. But other
factors could also be in play that mean lower long-run growth may be a troubling feature
of the U.S. economy even after the effects of Great Recession are behind us.
Broadly speaking, an economy’s long-run growth potential depends upon increases in
its productive resources and the technological improvements that enable those
resources to produce more. One important productive resource is labor. Here,
demographic trends are working against us. The U.S. Census Bureau projects that the
population aged 16 and over will grow a little less than 1 percent per year for the rest of
this decade; this is lower than what we experienced during the late 1990s, when
average annual growth of the adult population was 1.3 percent.
Moreover, our population is greying. Over the next 10 years, the share of the population
that is 65 or older is expected to increase about 4 percentage points from 15 to 19
percent.
3

This aging of the population and other long-running trends have been bringing down the
fraction of the population that is actually in the labor force since about 2000. The labor
force participation rate has also likely been pushed somewhat lower by what was, for
many years, a poor labor market. 1 However, the labor force participation rate dropped
approximately 2-1/2 percentage points even as labor market conditions began to
improve. And estimates suggest the decline will continue, reducing the growth of
available workers in the long run by 0.3 percentage points per year. 2 Slower growth in
available workers translates into less potential output growth.
As I just mentioned, economic growth over the longer run also depends upon
technological progress. Unfortunately, we can’t measure technological progress directly.
Instead, it is inferred as a residual only after accounting for other tangible reasons for
growth in a measure that is referred to as total factor productivity (TFP). By its very
nature, TFP is not measured precisely, and it’s difficult to discern its underlying trends.
Nonetheless, there have been noticeable shifts in estimated TFP growth in the past
several decades. From the early 1970s to the mid-1990s, the growth rate of TFP slowed
down from its post-World War II highs. With the advances in information technology and
their widespread adoption, we experienced a surge in TFP growth from the mid-1990s
to the mid-2000s. Since then, however, TFP growth has reverted to its pre-1994 pace. 3
Moreover, there is concern among many analysts that it may now be persistently lower
than in the past. If this weaker TFP growth proves to be the new normal, potential
economic growth would decline in tandem.
Whether these factors that hold down the potential growth rate of the economy are
temporary or more permanent is a matter of considerable debate. But if you come down
on the side that these are quite persistent developments, then you must conclude that
we face a lower potential growth rate today than we did in previous post- World War II
expansions.
This assessment is reflected to some degree in the economic projections of FOMC
participants. Four times a year, the FOMC releases its Summary of Economic
Projections (SEP), which gives FOMC participants’ forecasts of key economic variables
over the next three years and for the longer run. 4 As recently as January 2012, FOMC
participants assessed the long-run potential growth rate of the economy to be in the 21/4 to 3 percent range. 5 Today, the median participant believes that longer-run real
GDP growth is only 2.0 percent. Even the most optimistic of my colleagues places this
number only slightly higher at 2.3 percent.

1

The labor force participation rate dropped 1 percentage point while the unemployment rate escalated
during the downturn.
2
This projection contrasts with what happened during the late 1990s, when increasing labor force
participation was raising available labor supply by 0.1 to 0.2 percent per year.
3
For example, Congressional Budget Office (2015) and Fernald (2014) provide estimates of TFP growth
and discuss the changes that have taken place in the past.
4
For the most recent summary, see Federal Open Market Committee (2015b).
5
See Federal Open Market Committee (2012).
4

When measured against these benchmarks, my forecast of GDP rising in the range of 2
to 2-1/2 percent in 2016 doesn’t look so bad. It’s simply saying that the economy will
expand near its longer-run productive capabilities. This number may be disappointing —
we would certainly like stronger sustainable growth — but there is nothing much that
monetary policy can do about working-age population growth, labor force participation
trends, and technical progress. These trend estimates are the benchmarks we must
take as given when deciding how to set monetary policy.
Lower Potential Growth, Lower Equilibrium Interest Rates
That is not to say, however, that these benchmarks do not influence policy. Importantly,
lower potential output growth implies lower returns to investment. As a result, the
equilibrium real interest rates, which are consistent with fully employed resources, are
lower in an economy with lower potential output growth. And, of course, lower real rates
imply lower nominal rates even when inflation is at its target. So, the equilibrium federal
funds rate, which is associated with a neutral monetary policy — policy that is neither
expansionary nor contractionary — is lower in an economy with a lower potential output
growth. Therefore, the FOMC must take estimates of potential output growth into
account when calibrating the stance of monetary policy.
Of course, there are other reasons why equilibrium interest rates are likely lower than
they were before the crisis. For example, former Fed Chair Ben Bernanke has
discussed frequently the global savings glut. As the world population has aged and as
residents of fast-growing emerging economies have grown wealthier, the saving rate in
most countries has increased. This has resulted in a larger pool of funds seeking safe,
profitable opportunities for investment. However, domestic investment opportunities in
most of these countries have not kept pace with the increased saving rates. This higher
supply of investable funds relative to domestic demand has driven down interest rates
worldwide. In addition, former Treasury Secretary Lawrence Summers has expanded on
these influences, speculating that soft aggregate demand worldwide has discouraged
structural investment and capital stock growth — his view of the “secular stagnation”
hypothesis. These two ideas are closely related.
All of these factors imply that the federal funds rate consistent with a neutral stance for
monetary policy may be lower than we used to think. How big might these changes be?
Well, in December, FOMC participants’ projections for the longer-run nominal federal
funds rate were in the range of 3 to 4 percent, with the median projection at 3.5
percent. 6 Three years ago, when forecasts of potential growth were higher, the
Committee was projecting the long-run funds rate would be in the range of 3-1/4 to 41/2 percent — about 50 basis points higher than today’s estimates. 7
What Is Next for Monetary Policy?
So we are likely headed toward a lower resting point for the federal funds rate than
before. What is the path to that level likely to look like over the next several years?
6
7

Federal Open Market Committee (2015b).
Federal Open Market Committee (2012).
5

As I’m sure you are aware, in December the FOMC voted to increase the target range
for the federal funds rate by 25 basis points to 1/4 to 1/2 percent. It was the first time
since June 2006 that the FOMC has raised its policy rate. As Chair Janet Yellen
explained during her press conference after the meeting, “With the economy performing
well and expected to continue to do so, the Committee judged that a modest increase in
the federal funds rate target is now appropriate, recognizing that even after this increase
monetary policy remains accommodative.” 8
Yellen’s words underscore the intention for the stance of monetary policy to remain
accommodative for some time, and the Committee’s latest statement anticipates making
gradual adjustments during policy normalization. 9 But, if we are near our employment
mandate and the prospects for growth look solid, why are we expecting to take this
gradual approach? What is different during this tightening cycle?
One issue is that the equilibrium, or the neutral, federal funds rate can move over the
business cycle for a variety of reasons, and can be either above or below its long-run
level. Currently, we think some remaining fallout from the financial crisis and
international headwinds mean that the neutral level of the federal funds rate today is
even lower than it will be in the long run. By some estimates, the equilibrium inflationadjusted rate is currently near zero. This rate should rise gradually as the headwinds
fade over time. But until they do, monetary policy rates must be even lower than they
otherwise would be to provide adequate accommodation for economic growth.
Persistently Low Inflation
But that is only part of the answer to why monetary policy rates are below long-run
neutral levels. The other part is that we have yet to achieve our inflation goal. We need
to pursue a sufficiently accommodative monetary policy if we are to achieve the inflation
goal over the medium term.
Thus far, my remarks have focused on only one aspect of our policy goals: full
employment. But monetary policy has another objective: The other goal Congress has
set for us is the achievement of price stability. The FOMC interprets this objective to
mean that inflation should average 2 percent over the medium term as measured by the
Price Index for Personal Consumption Expenditures (PCE).
We have not done well relative to this objective. Over the past eight years, PCE inflation
has averaged 1.5 percent, with the latest reading at just 0.4 percent. We often look at
core inflation, which strips out the volatile food and energy components, as a good
indicator of where total inflation is likely to be headed over the next year or so. Well,
core inflation has been just 1.3 percent over the past 12 months.
Overall inflation is being held down in part by lower energy prices. The higher dollar is
also weighing on both total inflation and core inflation. I expect these effects to dissipate
as we move through the year. Further improvements in labor markets and growth in
8
9

Yellen (2015).
Federal Open Market Committee (2015a).
6

economic activity should also boost inflation. And so I see inflation moving up gradually
to approach our 2 percent inflation target within the next three years.
However, there are some downside risks to this forecast. We might see further declines
in energy prices or greater appreciation of the dollar. In addition, undershooting our 2
percent inflation target for as long as we have invites the risk of the public beginning to
expect persistently low inflation in the future. If this mindset becomes embedded in
decisions regarding wages and prices, then getting inflation back to 2 percent will be
that much more difficult. Here, I find it troubling that the compensation for prospective
inflation built into a number of financial market asset prices has drifted down
considerably over the past two years. More recently, some survey-based measures of
inflation expectations, which had previously seemed unmovable, have also edged
down. So to achieve our inflation target — and to provide a buffer against downside
risks — it is appropriate that we follow a gradual path to policy normalization.
What is the gradual path that FOMC participants anticipate? Here is the well-known “dot
plot,” which shows FOMC participants’ views of the appropriate target federal funds rate
at the end of each of the next three years and in the longer run. Each participant’s fed
funds rate forecast is shown as a distinct dot at each of these time horizons. The chart
I’m showing here is the most recent one we did for last December’s FOMC meeting.

Focus for a moment on the median policy projections, indicated by the red dots. Most of
my colleagues thought that it would be appropriate to raise the target federal funds rate
7

at our last meeting. By the end of 2016, the median participant envisioned the fed funds
rate to be about a percentage point higher than it is today. With eight FOMC meetings a
year, this path is consistent with the target federal funds rate, on average, increasing by
25 basis points at every other FOMC meeting. By historical standards, this is certainly a
gradual path. It is even slower than the so-called measured pace of increases over the
2004–06 tightening cycle, which was 25 basis points per meeting.
Overall, I think appropriate policy is consistent with some of the most accommodative
dots on the chart. One reason I arrive at this conclusion is because I am less optimistic
about the inflation outlook than most of my colleagues. Given the persistently-lowinflation record of the past six years and given how slowly inflation evolves when it is at
such low levels, it may be difficult to return inflation to target over the next two or three
years. So I’m in favor of very gradual policy normalization to help ensure that we meet
our inflation goal within a reasonable amount of time. Moreover, as I have argued many
times, prudent risk management calls for a slower removal of accommodative monetary
policy. From my perspective, the costs of raising the federal funds rate too quickly far
exceed the costs of removing accommodation too slowly. So taking both of these
concerns into account — and considering how I think economic conditions will evolve
over time — I believe that policy should plan to follow an even shallower path for the
federal funds rate than currently envisioned by the median FOMC participant.
I would like to conclude by noting that as much as we would like to be able to convey
the exact timing and magnitude of future policy actions, there is no single,
predetermined rate path that is consistent with a gradual approach. This is because
while our goal is clear — to reach our dual mandate targets — our view of the road
ahead may need to be modified. It is what you hear FOMC participants and market
commentators often refer to as being “data dependent.” To use a metaphor, it’s a little
like my golf game. My plan is to hit a drive smack down the center of the fairway; stick
an iron close to the pin; and drain a putt for the birdie. But my actual shot-making
depends upon how well I judge the crosswinds or if that unfair bounce off the sprinkler
head leaves me with a nasty lie in the fairway bunker. As I stand on the tee and think
through my approach, one thing is certain: I have to play the next shot from wherever I
end up. Adjustments may need to be made.
So it is with monetary policy. My views are not set in stone. If the incoming data move
my inflation projections up, I would adjust my policy views in tandem and would raise
my federal funds rate projection more quickly than I currently envision. If we were hit by
an unexpected shock that set back the growth outlook, I would favor a more
accommodative policy than I envision today. This is what it means to be data
dependent. Of course, I will not be alone in taking this approach. As the December
FOMC statement announcing the policy change made clear over the coming months
and years, “the actual path of the federal funds rate will depend on the economic
outlook as informed by incoming data.” 10
Thank you.
10

Federal Open Market Committee (2015a).
8

References
Colby, Sandra L., and Jennifer M. Ortman, 2015, Projections of the Size and
Composition of the U.S. Population: 2014 to 2060, Current Population Reports, U.S.
Census Bureau, No. P25-1143, March, available at
https://www.census.gov/content/dam/Census/library/publications/2015/demo/p251143.pdf.
Congressional Budget Office, 2015, An Update to the Budget and Economic Outlook:
2015 to 2025, report, Washington, DC, August, available at
https://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/114th-congress-2015-2016/reports/50724Update-OneColumn_1.pdf.
Federal Open Market Committee, 2015a, press release, Washington, DC, December
16, https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20151216a.htm.
Federal Open Market Committee, 2015b, Summary of Economic Projections,
Washington, DC, December 16, available at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomcprojtabl20151216.htm.
Federal Open Market Committee, 2012, Summary of Economic Projections,
Washington, DC, February 29, available at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/mpr_20120229_part4.htm#17779.
Fernald, John G., 2014, “Productivity and potential output before, during, and after the
Great Recession,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, working paper, No. 201415, June, available at http://www.frbsf.org/economic-research/files/wp2014-15.pdf.
Yellen, Janet L., 2015, press conference transcript, December 16, available at
https://www.federalreserve.gov/mediacenter/files/fomcpresconf20151216.pdf.

9