View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Welcoming Remarks

Financial Interdependence in the World’s Post-Crisis Capital Markets
Presented by GIC in partnership with the Philadelphia Council for Business Economics, the CFA
Society of Philadelphia, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
2010 Global Conference Series (Part III)
March 3, 2010

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

Welcoming Remarks
Financial Interdependence in the World’s Post-Crisis Capital Markets
Presented by GIC in partnership with the Philadelphia Council for Business Economics, the CFA Society
of Philadelphia, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

2010 Global Conference Series (Part III)
March 3, 2010
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
________________________________________________________________________
Opening
Good morning and welcome to the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. The
Philadelphia Fed has had a long relationship with the Global Interdependence Center.
For more than 30 years, we have participated in GIC meetings with policy leaders from
around the globe. We have benefited from the many good ideas that have emerged
from these discussions.
That is why the Philadelphia Fed is proud to host today’s event — part three in this
timely conference series on financial interdependence in the world’s post-crisis capital
markets.
As you see in the agenda, we will hear perspectives from members of Congress,
investment experts, and economists. I am particularly pleased that the keynote speaker
is my colleague Eric Rosengren, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.
The financial crisis of the last two years will alter the structure and performance of
global capital markets in many ways. Competition and market forces will change many
financial products and the way they are delivered. Financial products and innovations
that failed the market test will disappear or change. And that is how it should be. We
should not underestimate the power of the market and its adaptability.
Yet global financial markets will also be shaped, for better or worse, by the nature of
financial regulatory reforms under consideration by lawmakers in numerous countries.
For example, recent discussion in Washington has centered on which regulatory agency
should have which supervisory powers and over what types of institutions. One
proposal would eliminate the Fed’s oversight of state-chartered member banks in favor
of a focus on the largest institutions. Other proposals would transfer all bank
1

supervision and regulation to a separate, single bank regulator. Taking away the Fed’s
supervisory role on Main Street or Wall Street would be unwise. As the central bank,
the Fed has the depth of experience and expertise to monitor banks of all sizes. And
these responsibilities support and complement the central bank’s ability to meet its
Congressional mandates for financial stability and monetary policy.
In 1997, the U.K. took bank regulation from the Bank of England and gave it to the
Financial Services Authority. Based on its experience with a separate regulator during
this crisis, the U.K. government is considering moving regulatory activity back into the
central bank — just the opposite of some U.S. proposals.
Chairman Bernanke submitted a report to Congress that clearly outlines the sound
reasons for retaining bank supervision in the Federal Reserve. 1 The current crisis
underscores the importance of having a regulatory framework that addresses both the
safety and soundness of individual institutions and the macro-prudential risks of the
financial system as a whole. Given the Fed’s traditional central banking roles, including
having lender of last resort responsibilities, overseeing the stability of financial and
payment systems, and setting monetary policy, it is uniquely situated within the
government with the necessary expertise to deliver on both pieces of this regulatory
mandate.
In my view, the proposals for regulatory reshuffling, at best, miss the point of what is
required for meaningful reform and, at worst, weaken the current regulatory
framework. The real danger is that such proposals increase the likelihood of future
crises rather than fixing the problem. Instead of elaborate restructuring, I suggest we
focus on three key initiatives that will truly improve our regulatory system.
First, I believe Congress should amend the bankruptcy code to include a new chapter for
large nonbank financial institutions. In my view, the most important issue any reform
must address is the too-big-to-fail problem. Without a credible resolution mechanism
to allow the orderly failure of large and interconnected financial firms, we will be setting
the stage for the next crisis.
Foremost on the agenda should be the recognition that no firm should be too big to fail.
Any resolution mechanism should address systemic risk without requiring taxpayer
support. To foster market discipline and reduce moral hazard, the resolution
mechanism must ensure that a failed firm’s shareholders are wiped out and that
creditors bear losses. Most important, the resolution mechanism must be credible.
Managers, owners, and creditors must believe that firms on the verge of failure will, in
1

See “The Public Policy Case for a Role for the Federal Reserve in Bank Supervision and Regulation,”
January 2010.
http://www.federalreserve.gov/BoardDocs/RptCongress/supervision/supervision_report.pdf.

2

fact, be allowed to fail. Therefore, we must limit regulatory discretion or forbearance
and the potential for political interference. The resolution regime must not become a
mechanism for more bailouts. I am concerned that the current legislative proposals
allow far too much discretion and could lead to more bailouts, not fewer.
Given these criteria, I believe a modified bankruptcy process would be a better
mechanism than proposals to expand the bank resolution process under FDICIA to cover
nonbank financial firms and bank holding companies. It seems far too easy in the heat
of a crisis to deem that systemic risks are too high to let an institution fail. Yet, as we
have seen, when firms expect to be protected from failure, they take greater risks at the
taxpayer’s expense and, in so doing, sow the seeds of other crises.
No doubt, lawmakers will need to work out the details of a new bankruptcy chapter,
including who would force an institution into bankruptcy. I would favor allowing not
only the regulator, but also creditors, to place a troubled financial firm into bankruptcy
when it is unable to meet its financial obligations. This would enhance market discipline
and lower regulatory discretion.
Another issue involves how to handle qualified financial contracts, including swaps,
repos, and derivatives of those firms in bankruptcy. Current law exempts these
contracts from various provisions of the bankruptcy code, including the automatic stay
provisions. In other words, the contracts are permitted to close out even though the
firm is in bankruptcy. Some argue that these exemptions prevent systemic risk. Yet
others argue that these exemptions actually raised the systemic risks surrounding Bear
Stearns, AIG, and Lehman. 2
The international nature of these large financial firms means that we must work to
ensure international coordination of a bankruptcy process. Yet it is not uncommon or
impossible to fail international firms. We also need to ensure a timely bankruptcy
process, so the bankruptcy proceedings do not drag out for years. I do not think that
either of these challenges is insurmountable.
I am not arguing to replace the current process of resolving small and medium-sized
bank failures outside of bankruptcy — the FDIC has demonstrated its ability to resolve
these institutions quickly (usually over a weekend) and at relatively low cost to the
taxpayer. However, the handling of the largest financial institutions during this crisis has
persuaded me that the system cannot easily expand to encompass large firms without
biasing the outcomes toward bailouts rather than resolution. Thus, I favor a bankruptcy
mechanism as a more credible solution to the too-big-to-fail problem.

2

See Thomas H. Jackson and David A. Skeel, Jr., “Bankruptcy, Banks, and Non-Bank Financial Institutions,”
manuscript prepared for the Wharton Financial Institutions Center Workshop “Cross-Border Issues in
Resolving Systemically Important Financial Institutions,” February 12, 2010.

3

My second recommended action is to clarify the Federal Reserve’s umbrella supervision
role for financial holding companies. Under current legislation, the Federal Reserve
supervises bank holding companies and serves as umbrella supervisor of financial
holding companies, while the appropriate functional regulators supervise the
subsidiaries. For example, the SEC supervises an investment-banking subsidiary, while a
state insurance commission supervises an insurance subsidiary, and the designated
federal or state bank supervisor watches over the commercial banking subsidiary.
To reduce regulatory burdens, the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act limits the Federal Reserve’s
power to examine subsidiaries that have a functional regulator. So the Fed has relied on
the functional regulator for information about holding company subsidiaries. I believe
Congress should clarify that the Fed has umbrella supervisory powers and the
responsibility to exercise them, including collecting supervisory information on the
holding company and all of its subsidiaries on a routine basis. These changes would not
broaden the supervisory powers of the Fed – or any other agency. Indeed, under
Gramm-Leach-Bliley, the Fed has been given authority to examine and take action
against any subsidiary that may pose a material risk to the financial safety and
soundness of an insured depository affiliate, or the domestic or international payment
systems. Clarifying the Fed’s umbrella supervisory role would encourage regulators to
work together to take a comprehensive look at the systemic risks of consolidated
financial organizations. This thorough review of each firm would help the Fed in its
macro-prudential mission to help ensure financial stability and the integrity of the
payments system.
Further, I believe Congress should also clarify the Fed’s financial oversight
responsibilities by requiring a semi-annual Financial Stability Report for Congress and
the public, much as it requires the Fed to submit its Monetary Policy Report. This report
would also improve the transparency and accountability of the Fed’s financial oversight
responsibilities, which would help ensure public trust and credibility.
My third recommended action is to integrate market discipline into our regulatory
structure rather than relying solely on more regulations. Consider regulations governing
financial institution capital. One of the lessons of the financial crisis is the speed with
which capital ratios can decline. A firm can move from “well-capitalized” to
“undercapitalized” almost overnight, and then face enormous difficulties in raising
capital during a crisis. This argues in favor of raising regulatory capital ratios for
financial institutions.
Yet, rather than simply raising capital requirements, regulators should marshal market
forces by requiring financial firms to hold contingent capital in the form of convertible
debt that would convert into equity in periods of financial stress. Contingent capital
would be less costly than simply raising capital requirements, since it is triggered only
under bad economic conditions, when capital is most costly to obtain. Thus, it reduces
the incentives for financial firms to seek ways to evade dramatically higher capital
4

requirements. The ready contingent capital also avoids the need for fire sales of assets
to raise capital, which can exacerbate an economic downturn. And perhaps most
important, it can reduce the necessity of government rescues and bailouts.
Contingent capital would enhance both regulatory supervision and market discipline.
The market price of such debt would provide regulators with a valuable signal about the
financial health of the firm and about the market’s perception of systemic risk. In
addition, the threat of the debt’s conversion to equity would mobilize creditor
discipline. We should also consider requiring higher levels of capital for banks that pose
greater systemic risks. This might be done by basing capital requirements not only on
credit risk but also on liquidity risk and asset growth. These steps would strengthen
market discipline and improve financial stability. And regulators can add these capital
requirements without additional legislation.
I believe these three actions would go a long way toward improving financial stability.
Enacting a credible bankruptcy process to solve the too-big-to-fail problem, clarifying
the Fed’s umbrella supervision and financial stability roles, and enhancing market
discipline are steps we must take to lower the probability of a future crisis. We could
simplify the entire financial regulatory legislative initiative by focusing on these three
key elements. We do not need huge new bureaucracies, or a complete restructuring of
our regulatory agencies.
These are a few of my own thoughts on post-crisis reform. Today, we’ll have the
opportunity to hear many more and consider how to progress toward a sound solution
that will safeguard the integrity of our market mechanisms. I look forward to the
presentations and discussion.

5