View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Reducing Financial Fragility by Ending Too Big to Fail

Eighth Annual Finance Conference
Boston College Carroll School of Management
Boston, MA
June 6, 2013

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

Reducing Financial Fragility by Ending Too Big to Fail
Eighth Annual Finance Conference
Boston College Carroll School of Management
Boston, MA
June 6, 2013
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Introduction
When Congress passed the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act three
years ago, one of the highest priorities was to ensure that never again would U.S. taxpayers
need to bail out any bank or financial institution deemed too big to fail. The first two sections
of Dodd-Frank attempted to address the issue. Title I focused on expanded oversight and
regulation of systemically important financial institutions – known as SIFIs – and Title II called
for establishing an orderly resolution authority to resolve a failing systemically important firm
without threatening financial stability.
The idea that a failing financial firm must be rescued to prevent risks to overall financial stability
is at the heart of the most controversial aspects of the recent financial crisis. Having the
government intervene to rescue a private firm is largely anathema to the idea of a free market
economy. Just as reaping the rewards of success is an essential element of a market economy,
bearing the costs of failure is equally important and necessary. The noted economist Allan
Meltzer has said, “Capitalism without failure is like religion without sin. It doesn’t work.” 1 A
real or perceived guarantee that taxpayers will backstop losses distorts effective decisionmaking, encourages excessive risk-taking, and leads to financial fragility. Indeed, we often fail

1

See Allan Meltzer, “Asian Problems and the IMF,” Cato Journal, 17:3 (Winter 1998) pp. 267-74.

1

to recognize that government policies or safety nets distort incentives in the financial sector in
ways that can aggravate rather than diminish financial fragility.
Today, I will discuss why I think current efforts to eliminate the problem of too big to fail may
not be sufficient. I will also propose how a simpler approach to capital requirements and a
more rule-like resolution process can offer more effective and less complex solutions to ending
too big to fail and thus reduce financial fragility. The first line of defense is to expect that all
financial firms will maintain sufficient levels of capital to absorb losses arising from negative
shocks, thus significantly reducing the risk of failure. It is striking to think of the number of
financial firms that failed or were rescued during the crisis that were thought to be “well
capitalized.” Obviously, they were not. The second requirement for ending too big to fail is to
establish a rule-based framework that permits a large financial institution to, in fact, fail
without placing the financial system at risk. Large financial firms and their creditors should not
be shielded by government guarantees or by regulatory discretion. Making it clear that
creditors will face significant losses in bankruptcy and will not be rescued forces creditors to
more studiously assess counterparty risk. It also provides greater incentives for them to enforce
more discipline on the borrower’s risk-taking activities.
Before I turn to specific proposals, permit me to reiterate some principles that help guide my
thinking about the right approach to regulatory reform. I should point out that these are my
own views and are not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve System or my colleagues on the
Federal Open Market Committee.
The Value of Simple, Robust Regulations
In the context of monetary policy, I have long advocated simple, robust rules and transparent
communications. 2 Robust rules are important because they are intended to work well in a
variety of environments. This reflects our limited knowledge about the true determinants of
2

See, for example, Charles I. Plosser, “Transparency and Monetary Policy,” University of California, Santa Barbara
Economic Forecast Project, May 3, 2012, and Charles I. Plosser, “Output Gaps and Robust Policy Rules,” 2010
European Banking & Financial Forum, Czech National Bank, March 23, 2010.

2

economic outcomes. Economists have also come to understand that using policies that are
optimal in one specific economic model can often deliver very poor outcomes if that model
proves incorrect. So a policy rule that operates well under a wide range of models is a better
and more robust approach.
The same approach applies to the design of regulatory frameworks as well. Because the
financial world is very complex, there is merit in simple, transparent regulatory solutions
designed to work reasonably well in a wide range of situations. We want rules that regulators
can enforce without having superhuman knowledge or foresight. However, we can predict with
virtual certainty that private actors will seek to evade regulatory restrictions and taxes. This is
often called “regulatory arbitrage.” We also know that enforcement costs rise as firms’
incentives to evade regulations increase.
In my view, simple mechanisms that are harder to evade – and even better, mechanisms that
utilize market forces to discipline firm behavior – are superior to an elaborate list of rules that
seeks to cover every possible outcome. Simple and transparent regulatory mechanisms make it
easier for market participants to predict how regulators are likely to behave. This, in turn,
makes it easier for regulators to credibly commit to implementing the regulations in a
consistent manner.
Yet regulators continue to write thousands of pages of rules. In many cases, they are rules that
proscribe activities for financial institutions. Unfortunately, such rules quickly become out of
date as financial markets and products evolve. For example, regulations were not well
equipped to deal with the myriad of structured products that developed during the decade
leading up to the crisis. Do we really believe that another thousand pages of regulations will
prevent the next crisis? Rather than trying to create regulatory rules that govern activities and
place ever-increasing burdens on regulators to get it exactly right, we should be insisting on
simple frameworks that increase market incentives to monitor and discipline the behavior of
firms.

3

I would also note that as regulation becomes ever more complex, compliance and enforcement
costs rise significantly. Andrew Haldane of the Bank of England has argued that regulation of
the financial sector is exploding, with the cost of compliance and supervision following suit. He
argues that we could be more effective and more efficient by simplifying our approach to
regulatory reform. 3 I whole-heartedly endorse this general approach.
Bank Capital and Too Big to Fail
The most effective preventive measure to reduce the probability that a financial firm will fail in
the first place is adequate capital. In addition, higher levels of capital may permit regulatory or
market intervention before a firm actually fails, thereby making bankruptcy or bailouts
unnecessary. The recognition of the importance of capital is acknowledged in Title I of DoddFrank, which gives regulators the power to assign a capital surcharge for systemically important
financial institutions. However, deciding on what level of capital to require is not trivial.
Current Basel III proposals call for a SIFI surcharge of 1 to 2.5 percent, which I fear may simply
be too low.
In addition to equity capital, requiring SIFIs to hold subordinated debt instruments, such as
contingent capital, may be a simpler and less costly approach to increase capital requirements.
The fact that market participants have already been adopting the use of contingent convertible
bonds (CoCos) in various forms suggests that it might be more efficient to draw on reverse
convertible debt instruments rather than to impose drastic increases in equity capital. The
appeal of reverse convertible debt is that it automatically becomes equity when, for example,
the firm’s capital falls below some trigger. These instruments allow a firm’s equity capital to
increase automatically when the firm comes under sufficient stress. 4

3

Andrew Haldane and Vasileios Madouros, “The Dog and the Frisbee,” the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City’s
36th Economic Policy Symposium, “The Changing Policy Landscape,” Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 31, 2012.

4

The Squam Lake Group has proposed another interesting form of capital, deferred compensation for managers.
They suggest that perhaps 20 percent of managers’ compensation be deferred for five years and that this
compensation is forfeited if the firm enters distress (according to some well-defined notion of distress, perhaps

4

There have been a number of proposals for the design of CoCos. 5 My preference is to use a
market-based trigger — for example, a trigger linked to the market value of the bank’s equity —
and to set the trigger high enough so that the bank’s true economic capital remains positive
when conversion is triggered. A market-based trigger will react to the most current
information, unlike triggers based on book values or regulatory decisions. Even more
important, since the trigger does not depend on regulatory discretion, it is more transparent
and less likely to lead to regulatory forbearance. 6 Setting the trigger high enough so that the
bank’s net worth is still substantially positive reduces the likelihood of the need for bankruptcy
or resolution.
Economists have identified a number of potential complications with the use of CoCos having
market-based triggers. Some critics have voiced concerns about the possibility of destabilizing
bear runs and short-selling stocks of troubled banks as these firms approach the triggers. While
these concerns should be taken seriously, I do not believe they are compelling showstoppers.
For example, using average stock prices over a length of time and putting some restrictions on
short-selling by holders of CoCos should reduce concerns about excessive noise in stock prices.
These approaches would also reduce the possibility of bear runs to force conversion. 7
Because these instruments would be treated as a form of debt until conversion, they could
serve the same function as higher capital and, accordingly, satisfy capital requirements but may
the conversion of its reverse convertibles). Squam Lake Group, “Aligning Incentives at Systemically Important
Financial Institutions,” March 25, 2013.
5

Charles Calomiris and Richard Herring, “How to Design a Contingent Convertible Debt Requirement That Helps
Solve Our Too-Big-to-Fail Problem,” Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, Spring 2013, 25(2):21-44 (publication
forthcoming) includes a table summarizing the main elements of most proposals. See also Charles I. Plosser,
remarks to the Philadelphia Fed Policy Forum: Policy Lessons from the Economic and Financial Crisis, Philadelphia,
PA, December 4, 2009, and Charles I. Plosser, “Convertible Securities and Bankruptcy Reforms: Addressing Too Big
to Fail and Reducing the Fragility of the Financial System,” remarks to the Conference on the Squam Lake Report:
Fixing the Financial System, New York, NY, June 16, 2010, for more on the value of these instruments.

6

CoCos with market-based triggers set at high levels provide a form of prompt corrective action using market
forces, rather than relying on regulatory forces alone. Of course, I expect that regulators would take heed when a
firm nears conversion.
7

Some economists have pointed out the risk that CoCos can lead to multiple equilibria, but as shown in Calomiris
and Herring (2013), there are ways to address such an issue.

5

be less costly than equity capital or long-term subordinated debt. More important, this
approach provides the firm with choices about how and when to raise capital, with market
prices functioning as an important signal. This gives firms and markets a key role in keeping
financial institutions healthy, thus reducing the burden on regulators to monitor and prescribe
remedial action on a real-time basis.
Place Greater Weight on Simple Leverage Ratios
Perhaps more important than how to measure capital is how to measure assets. Basel II and III
emphasize risk-weighted assets as the primary measure of the asset base and focus on the ratio
of Tier 1 capital to risk-weighted assets as the core measure of capital adequacy. There is
probably no better example of rule writing that violates the basic principles of simple, robust
regulation than risk-weighted capital calculations. Haldane and Maldouros provide a rough
estimate of the increasing complexity of the Basel rules by using the number of pages of
documentation for each successive Basel accord. Basel I had 30 pages of documentation on
risk-weighting. Basel II increased that to 347 pages. And now Basel III requires 616 pages to
provide guidance on risk-weighted capital. 8 We have a wealth of examples in which riskweighted capital rules have permitted very risky activities by institutions with little or no
capital. 9 In addition, there is evidence that even for relatively simple portfolios the measure of
risk-weighted assets can vary significantly across banks. 10
The problems with risk-weighted capital requirements suggest that we should move to a
simpler, more transparent approach. I would prefer more emphasis on the simple leverage
8

See Haldane and Madouros (2012).

9

See, for example, Acharya, Schnabl, and Suarez’s account of the collapse of the asset-backed commercial paper
market. Viral V. Acharya, Philipp Schnabl, and Gustavo Suarez, “Securitization Without Risk Transfer,” Journal of
Financial Economics, March 2013.

10

Researchers at the Bank of International Settlements conducted an experiment to see how a relatively simple
portfolio of long and short positions would be treated for calculating risk-weighted capital at 16 global banks. They
found wide variations, even for these simple portfolios. Interestingly, although the banks’ own models were a
significant source of variation, the largest source of variation was different regulatory treatments by the banks’
home country regulators. “Regulatory Consistency Assessment Programme (RCAP) — Analysis of Risk-Weighted
Assets for Market Risk,” BIS (Jan 2013).

6

ratio — the ratio of capital to unweighted assets. 11 Specifically, we should adopt a framework
that relies on simple but higher leverage ratios. We should also require these simple ratios to
increase with the size, interconnectedness, and complexity of the institution. This means that
required leverage ratios rise with the size and complexity of the institution. Regulators would
worry less about what activities or products a firm could engage in but would impose a “tax” in
the form of more capital for becoming more systemically important.
We should be aware that higher capital requirements may drive activities outside the regulated
banking sector or that U.S. banks would become less competitive if capital requirements were
higher here than in other countries. However, we should keep in mind that increasing capital
requirements for SIFIs permits banks to engage in arbitrage by shrinking and becoming less
interconnected, precisely the intention of the increased capital charges. But that will be the
decision of the firm and the marketplace based on economies of scale and other efficiency
considerations, not on regulatory dictates. Also, current analyses suggest that even
significantly higher capital requirements are unlikely to be prohibitively costly. 12
A New Bankruptcy Mechanism
Requiring SIFIs to hold significantly more capital can reduce the probability of failure, but it
cannot and should not eliminate all risk of failure. When a troubled bank cannot recapitalize
itself in private markets, we need a credible mechanism to resolve the failing firm without a

11

See Thomas M. Hoenig, “Basel III Capital: A Well-Intended Illusion,” speech to the International Association of
Deposit Insurers, April 9, 2013, and William Poole, “Banking Reform: A Free Market Perspective,” speech to the
31st Annual Monetary and Trade Conference, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, April 17, 2013. Hoenig has
argued that the simple leverage ratio be the primary measure of capital adequacy and that risk-weighted assets be
used as a supplementary regulatory tool, precisely reversing the Basel ordering.
12

Hanson, Kashyap, and Stein estimate that a 10-percentage-point increase in a bank’s tier-1-to-risk-weightedcapital ratio would raise its weighted average cost of capital by 25 to 45 basis points. Baker and Wurgler arrive at
the somewhat higher range of 60 to 90 basis points. See Samuel Hanson, Anil Kashyap, and Jeremy Stein, “A
Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25 (1), Winter 2011, and
Malcolm Baker and Jeffrey Wurgler, “Would Stricter Capital Requirements Raise the Cost of Capital? Bank Capital
Regulation and the Low Risk Anomaly,” Working paper, New York University, March 15, 2013.

7

bailout. I believe that the orderly resolution authority of Dodd-Frank’s Title II is a step forward
but falls short.
I do not want to go into detail here, but let me outline some of the main elements of DoddFrank’s approach. The orderly liquidation authority can be invoked only when the Federal
Reserve and another regulator petition the Treasury (and ultimately the President) to take the
firm into receivership because it poses systemic concerns. Under Title II, the FDIC is given
expansive discretionary powers. Notably, the FDIC can draw on Treasury funds to pay off
creditors if the FDIC believes that this is necessary to prevent systemic risk problems. 13
While Title II improves our ability to wind down SIFIs, it is ultimately biased toward bailouts.
Remember that Title II resolution is available only when there are concerns about systemic risk.
Just imagine the highly political issue of determining whether a firm is systemically important,
especially if it has not been designated so by the Financial Stability Oversight Committee
beforehand. The delay in making this determination will make the firm harder to resolve and
likely lead to some sort of bailout.
The discretionary aspect of Title II also makes it subject to other political pressures. Creditors
will perceive that their payoffs will be determined through a regulatory resolution process,
which could be influenced through political pressure rather than subject to the rule of law. This
generates uncertainty, lacks transparency, and will ultimately undermine the effectiveness of
market discipline.
A new bankruptcy mechanism customized for financial firms and applicable to all financial
firms, whether systemically important or not, could alleviate most of the potential problems
caused by the discretionary and targeted nature of Title II. 14 By being more systematic and
13

To be clear, these powers are not unlimited. Indeed, by law, the FDIC must claw back the money for any
privileged creditors who receive more than they would have received in a straight liquidation if the resolution
leads to losses for the Treasury.

14

This partially addresses another dilemma for macroprudential regulation. Economists and regulators have yet to
come up with a clear definition of what “systemically important” really means.

8

rule-like, a bankruptcy resolution framework would largely eliminate the potential for bailouts,
thereby increasing the firm’s incentives to avoid actions that might result in bankruptcy.
One proposed bankruptcy mechanism is to add a new Chapter 14 to the Bankruptcy Code. 15
Under this system, a specialized federal judge, who could call upon the expertise of a special
master, would oversee the resolution process. While the FDIC, or another regulator, could
trigger a bankruptcy filing and would be one of the participants, ultimate decision-making
would rest with the judge. Judicial authority, rather than regulatory discretion, would
determine any deviations from absolute priority. The opportunities for drawing on Treasury
funds would be more limited and carefully circumscribed.
Let me be clear. I prefer that a specialized bankruptcy resolution mechanism like Chapter 14
supplant Title II, not supplement it. The coexistence of two separate resolution mechanisms
presents difficulties. Most notably, once a firm has entered bankruptcy, regulators might
nonetheless invoke Title II. This possibility will certainly complicate managers’ and claimants’
expectations and incentives. That said, if a bankruptcy resolution mechanism for financial firms
were offered, I believe that both regulators and firms may prefer to avoid Title II in most
circumstances. In particular, bankruptcy could be employed without raising the threat of
systemic risk, which is necessary to invoke Title II. So, while I believe that a resolution regime
with Chapter 14 could fully supplant Title II, a regime with Chapter 14 supplementing Title II is a
significant improvement over one with Title II alone.
Conclusion
Can we reduce financial fragility by ending too big to fail? I think we can, but I believe the
current efforts may come up short. Importantly, we should seek to increase capital buffers for
financial institutions and to simplify capital regulation by reducing or eliminating the everincreasing complexity of risk-weighted capital calculations. Furthermore, if we are to end
15

See Thomas H. Jackson, “Bankruptcy Code Chapter 14: A Proposal,” February 2012 and Thomas H. Jackson and
David A. Skeel, Jr., “Dynamic Resolution of Large Financial Institutions,” Institute for Law and Economics, Research
Paper, No. 13-03.

9

discretionary bailouts and the associated moral hazard problems that they create, we should
seek more rule-like methods to resolve failing firms, such as a new Chapter 14 bankruptcy
mechanism. Finally, we should design regulations that encourage rather than discourage
markets to monitor risk-taking and reduce our reliance on regulators’ discretion and judgment.
Rules and regulations are inevitably backward-looking, while markets are forward-looking and a
better judge of the financial fragility of an institution in real time. These mechanisms will
change the incentives of firms, market participants, and regulators in ways that provide us with
a better chance of ending too big to fail and promote a more stable financial system.

10