View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Perspectives on the U.S. Economy and
Monetary Policy
Monetary Policy and Banks and the Rise of Global Protectionism
Global Interdependence Center
Banque de France
Paris, France
March 10, 2014

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

Perspectives on the U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy
Monetary Policy and Banks and the Rise of Global Protectionism
Global Interdependence Center
Banque de France
Paris, France
March 10, 2014
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Note: President Plosser presented similar remarks to the Official Monetary and Financial
Institutions Forum in London, England, on March 6, 2014.

Highlights
• President Plosser expects growth of about 3 percent in 2014. He also expects the
unemployment rate to continue its steady decline and to reach about 6.2 percent by the
end of 2014. Inflation expectations will be relatively stable, and inflation will move up
toward the FOMC target of 2 percent over the next year.
•

President Plosser believes the Federal Open Market Committee has to revamp its current
forward guidance regarding the future federal funds rate path because the 6.5 percent
unemployment threshold has become irrelevant.

•

President Plosser favors providing more information on policymakers’ reaction function,
which indicates how policy will evolve as economic conditions change.

•

President Plosser favors a more systematic, less discretionary approach to monetary policy.
He believes it is time to switch from an interventionist mode for monetary policy to one that
is more systematic.

Introduction
I am delighted to return to the Banque de France and to join my friend Governor
Christian Noyer on this panel. The Global Interdependence Center (GIC) has once again
organized another opportunity to exchange views and discuss important topics on truly
global issues.

1

The Banque de France is in its third century, having been founded in 1800. Last week, I
spoke in London, where the Bank of England has been operating since 1694. So, I
hesitate to mention that the Federal Reserve is marking its 100th anniversary this year.
The Federal Reserve Act of 1913 created a uniquely American approach to a central
bank – a decentralized central bank – with 12 independent Federal Reserve Banks
around the country and a Board of Governors in Washington, D.C. This unique
governance structure requires that I forewarn you that the views I express are my own
and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve System or my colleagues on
the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC).
Economic Conditions
The U.S. economy is now nearly five years into a recovery that began in June 2009. The
recovery has been lackluster in many ways, yet it has made considerable progress
nonetheless. The unemployment rate, for example, has fallen from its peak of 10.0
percent to 6.7 percent. Employment gains have restored some 8 million jobs since the
trough, representing more than 90 percent of the jobs lost since the peak. Stock prices
have recovered, housing prices are up, and earnings at many businesses are healthy. It
is my general view that the U.S. economy is on firmer footing today than it has been in
several years. This is a cause for some optimism for continued progress in 2014.
In recent weeks, there has been a blizzard of economic reports, which have come in
weaker than expected. I believe that weakness largely reflects the severe winter
weather rather than a frozen recovery. So, we must be wary of attaching too much
significance to the latest numbers. As a monetary policymaker, I prefer to take a longer
view rather than let our decisions be whipsawed by the most recent statistics, which are
often noisy and subject to revision. Because monetary policy tends to work with a lag,
we must keep our attention focused on the intermediate- to longer-term underlying
trends if we are to make wise decisions.
Based on the latest GDP numbers revised last month, the U.S. economy performed
2

noticeably better in the second half of 2013 than in the first half. Specifically, real
output grew at a 3.3 percent pace in the second half of the year compared with 1.8
percent in the first half.
While this is far from the robust growth that many would like to see, it continues to
represent steady progress and an improving economy. My forecast calls for about 3
percent growth in 2014. This is in line with the central tendency of 2.8 to 3.2 percent
growth reported by my colleagues on the FOMC in December 2013.
There has been discussion of some recent weakness in consumer spending, housing
starts, and housing sales. For instance, in January, total retail sales fell by 0.4 percent;
housing starts dropped sharply in January by 2 percent compared with the level of a
year ago; and existing home sales dropped about 5 percent from a year ago. While
some softening in home sales might be expected from the rise in mortgage rates, those
rates are still very low by historical standards, and new home sales surged in January,
rising to their highest level since 2008. Despite the mixed housing data, continued
household formation constitutes a source of growth in housing demand. So, I expect
that housing will continue its recovery in 2014, once we get past the severe weather.
Consumer spending, which accounts for more than two-thirds of U.S. GDP, proved to be
quite resilient in 2013, despite the rise in payroll taxes at the start of the year, a
government shutdown, significant uncertainties about future tax policy, and the
implications of health-care reform.
Going forward, I expect that there will be less fiscal drag on the economy in 2014 than
we saw in 2013. Moreover, rising home prices and stock prices have helped improve
consumer balance sheets. I have frequently noted that one reason for the less-thanrobust growth in consumption during this recovery has been the deleveraging efforts by
consumers. With consumers carrying too much debt, spending was inevitably going to
give way to more saving as consumers attempted to restore the health of their balance
sheets. That process has been playing out, and the drag from deleveraging is waning. In
3

addition, steady, moderate job growth has led to modest increases in income. I foresee
somewhat more robust spending by consumers in the coming year as these trends
continue.
Weather also affected recent manufacturing numbers in the U.S. The Philadelphia Fed’s
Business Outlook Survey of manufacturers in our region has been a reliable indicator of
national manufacturing trends in the U.S. In February, the diffusion index of current
activity fell into negative territory for the first time in nine months. However, most
respondents attributed the weakness to the severe winter weather. Consistent with
such comments, expectations for manufacturing activity six months ahead increased in
February.
On the job front, the February employment report posted payroll gains of 175,000 jobs,
following an increase of 129,000 jobs in January, and 84,000 in December. All three of
these numbers most likely reflected in part the effect of the unusually severe winter
weather.
As we look at the employment averages over several months, the news remains
positive. Based on the latest revision, firms added an average of 194,000 jobs per
month in 2013, which is a somewhat better pace than in 2012. This consistent pace of
job growth was enough to drop the unemployment rate to 6.7 percent in February,
which is a full percentage point lower than a year ago. I expect that the unemployment
rate will reach about 6.2 percent by the end of 2014, and, if anything, that may prove
too pessimistic. Given the recent trends, an unemployment rate below 6 percent is
certainly plausible.
In terms of the other part of the Fed’s mandate, inflation has been running somewhat
below the FOMC’s long-run goal of 2 percent. The Fed’s preferred measure of inflation
is the year-over-year change in the price index for personal consumption expenditures,
or PCE inflation. It came in at 1.1 percent last year. It is important to defend our 2
percent inflation target both from below and above. Yet, I anticipate, as the FOMC
4

indicated in its most recent statement, that inflation will move back toward our target
over time. Economic growth is firming, and some of the factors that have held inflation
down, such as the one-time cut in payments to Medicare providers, are likely to abate
over time.
An additional and important determinant of actual inflation is consumer and business
expectations of inflation. I am encouraged that inflation expectations remain near their
longer-term averages and consistent with our 2 percent target. Given the large amount
of monetary accommodation that we have added and continue to add to the economy, I
think there is some upside risk to inflation in the longer term.
Of course, with any forecast, there are risks. While there continues to be some
downside risk to growth, for the first time in years, I see the potential for more upside
risk to the economic outlook. We need to consider this possibility as we calibrate
monetary policy.
Monetary Policy
So let me turn to some issues for monetary policy. The Federal Reserve has taken
extraordinary policy actions to support the economic recovery. The Fed has lowered its
policy rate — the federal funds rate — to essentially zero, where it has been for more
than five years. Since the policy rate cannot go any lower, the Fed has attempted to
provide additional accommodation through large-scale asset purchases. We are now in
our third round of this quantitative easing.
Since September 2012, the FOMC has added about $1.3 trillion in long-term Treasuries
and mortgage-backed securities to its balance sheet through this program, buying at a
pace of $85 billion a month in 2013. This program, known as QE3, is already twice the
size of the last round of asset purchases initiated in November 2010, known as QE2.
In December 2013, the Committee announced that it would reduce the pace of
purchases from $85 billion to $75 billion per month. In January, it announced a further
5

reduction to $65 billion. The FOMC is now on a path of measured reductions, which, if
continued, will end the purchase program later this year. If the economy continues to
improve, we could find ourselves still trying to increase accommodation in an
environment in which history suggests that policy should perhaps be moving in the
opposite direction.
In addition to asset purchases, the Fed is using forward guidance as a policy tool, which
is intended to inform the public about the way monetary policy is likely to evolve in the
future. In this dimension, the FOMC has indicated that it intends to leave the policy rate
near zero well past the time that the unemployment rate falls below the 6.5 percent
threshold. The FOMC had previously indicated that this was the earliest point at which
it would consider raising interest rates, especially if projected inflation continues to run
below the Committee’s 2 percent target.
Even though the FOMC has said that it doesn’t anticipate raising rates when the
economy crosses that threshold, I believe that with the economy so close to the
unemployment threshold, we face a communications challenge. In particular, we have
not described how policy will be conducted after the unemployment rate falls below 6.5
percent.
Communication Challenges
But before we offer further forward guidance, it is important to be clear about what this
forward guidance is supposed to accomplish. As that famous American baseball player
Yogi Berra is reported to have said, “You have to be careful if you don’t know where
you’re going because you might end up somewhere else.”
One way to think of forward guidance is that it is just another step toward increased
transparency and effective communication of monetary policy. This approach seeks to
clarify how policymakers will alter policy as economic conditions change, that is, to
describe a reaction function. By being more transparent about how policy will evolve as

6

a function of economic conditions, this approach can help the public form more
accurate expectations about the future path of monetary policy.
Economists have learned that expectations play an important role in determining
economic outcomes. When businesses and households have a better understanding of
how monetary policy is likely to evolve, they can make more informed spending and
financial decisions. If policymakers can reduce uncertainty about the course of
monetary policy, the economy is likely to perform more efficiently.
Of course, in order to communicate something about the reaction function, you have to
have one. That means in order to succeed with this approach to forward guidance,
policymakers must be able to agree on how they will systematically respond to changes
in economic conditions. To be useful, however, the reaction function need not be
mechanistic. Qualitative information about such a function and how it will be
implemented can also be useful and meaningful. Nevertheless, some degree of
commitment to abide by the specified reaction function is necessary if the
communication is to achieve the desired result of reducing policy uncertainty and
providing meaningful forward guidance.
A somewhat different rationale or view of forward guidance is that it is a way of
increasing accommodation when the policy rate is at or near the zero lower bound.
Some models suggest that when you are at the zero lower bound, it can be desirable, or
optimal, to indicate that future policy rates will be kept “lower for longer” than might
otherwise be the case. Thus, policymakers may want to deliberately commit to
deviating from what they would otherwise choose to do under normal conditions, such
as following a Taylor-like rule. In these models, such a commitment would tend to raise
inflation expectations and lower long-term nominal rates, thereby inducing households
and businesses to spend more today.
This approach asks more of forward guidance than just articulating a reaction function.
It takes more credibility and commitment because it requires policymakers to directly
7

influence and manage the public’s beliefs about the future policy path that differs from
how policymakers behaved in the past. As I have indicated in previous speeches, this
approach to forward guidance can backfire if the policy is misunderstood. 1 For example,
if the public hears that the policy rate will be lower for longer, it may interpret this news
as policymakers saying that they expect the economy to be weaker for longer. If that is
the interpretation of the message, then the forward guidance will not succeed and may
even weaken current spending.
The FOMC has not been clear about the purpose of its forward guidance. Is it purely a
transparency device, or is it a way to commit to a more accommodative future policy
stance to add more accommodation today? This lack of clarity makes it difficult to
communicate the stance of policy and the conditionality of policy on the state of the
economy.
I believe there is another – perhaps more fundamental – tension underlying forward
guidance and communication. Forward guidance in either of the two approaches I have
discussed requires a degree of commitment to conduct future policy in some particular
manner. Commitment is central to the success of either approach. Yet, I would suggest
that the old “rules versus discretion” debate is alive and well. This, of course, is not a
new tension within the FOMC, nor is it one that is likely to go away in the near term.
But the heightened weight and prominence given to forward guidance as a policy tool
has certainly shined a spotlight on this longstanding debate.
The desire to maintain flexibility to respond to “events on the ground” is a strong one.
One can make the case that discretion is deeply ingrained in most policy institutions,
particularly the Fed. Yet, the desire to maintain discretion is anathema to the
commitment required for successful forward guidance. Policymakers cannot maintain
discretion and simultaneously commit to forward guidance and expect that guidance to
be effective.
1

See Charles I. Plosser, “Forward Guidance,” speech to the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy
Research’s (SIEPR) Associates Meeting, February 12, 2013, Stanford, CA.

8

Conclusion
In summary, I believe that the U.S. economy is continuing to improve at a moderate
pace. We are likely to see growth of around 3 percent in 2014. Prospects for labor
markets will continue to improve, and I expect the unemployment rate will continue to
decline, reaching 6.2 percent or lower by the end of 2014. I also believe that inflation
expectations will be relatively stable and that inflation will move up toward our goal of 2
percent over the next year.
On monetary policy, we must back away from increasing the degree of policy
accommodation in a manner commensurate with an improving economy. Reducing the
pace of asset purchases in measured steps is moving in the right direction, but the pace
may leave us well behind the curve if the economy continues to play out according to
the FOMC forecasts.
Even after the asset purchase program has ended, monetary policy will still be highly
accommodative. As the expansion gains traction, the challenge will be to reduce
accommodation and to normalize policy in a way that ensures that inflation remains
close to our target, that the economy continues to grow, and that we avoid sowing the
seeds of another financial crisis.
Let me conclude with this thought. Over the past five years, the Fed and, dare I say,
many other central banks have become much more interventionist. I do not think this is
a particularly healthy state of affairs for the central banks or our economies. The crisis
in the U.S. has long passed. With a growing economy and the Fed’s long-term asset
purchases coming to an end, now is the time to contemplate restoring some semblance
of normalcy to monetary policy.
In my view, the proper role for monetary policy is to work behind the scenes in limited
and systematic ways to promote long-term growth and price stability. But since the
onset of the financial crisis, central banks have become highly interventionist in their
efforts to manipulate asset prices and financial markets in general as they attempt to
9

fine-tune economic outcomes. This approach has continued well past the end of the
financial crisis. While the motivations may be noble, we have created an environment
where “it is all about the Fed.” Market participants focus entirely too much on how the
central bank may tweak its policy, and central bankers have become too sensitive and
desirous of managing prices in the financial world. I do not see this as a healthy
symbiotic relationship for the long term.
If financial market participants believe that their success depends primarily on the next
decisions of monetary policymakers rather than economic fundamentals, our capital
markets will cease to deliver the economic benefits they are capable of providing. And
if central banks do not limit their interventionist strategies and focus on returning to
more normal policymaking aimed at promoting price stability and long-term growth,
then they will simply encourage the financial markets to ignore fundamentals and to
focus, instead, on the next actions of the central bank.
I hope we can find a way to normalize the role of monetary policy to one that is less
interventionist, less discretionary, and more systematic. I believe our longer-term
economic health will be the beneficiary.

10