View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Output Gaps and Robust Policy Rules
2010 European Banking & Financial Forum
Czech National Bank
Prague, The Czech Republic
March 23, 2010

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

Output Gaps and Robust Policy Rules
2010 European Banking & Financial Forum
Czech National Bank
Prague, The Czech Republic
March 23, 2010
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Introduction
Today I would like to discuss how monetary policymakers should approach setting policy
in a world in which economic data are measured imprecisely. This is a challenge for
policymakers not only in times of crisis but in normal times as well.
I am sure many of you know of the seminal work by John Taylor, in which he showed
that monetary policymakers appear to follow a rule in setting interest rates. These rules
relate the policy interest rate to the behavior of key macroeconomic variables such as
inflation and real activity. As I’ll discuss in a moment, I am in favor of a systematic, rulebased approach to monetary policy, primarily because it limits discretion and improves
economic stability by reducing policy uncertainty. But I will argue that choosing the
particular form of the rule must be done with great care, because many of the economic
variables that could be used in setting policy are in fact poorly measured.
For example, many policymakers focus on measures of economic slack, such as the
output gap or the unemployment gap, to provide guidance for policy. Broadly speaking,
the output gap refers to the deviation of output from some level deemed optimal, often
called “potential output.” Likewise, the unemployment gap is the deviation of
unemployment from an unemployment rate that represents “full employment.” But
how should we measure “potential output” and “full employment”?
One approach is to estimate potential output using the trend in actual output. Another
approach derives an estimate based on a model of the production function for the
economy. However, various studies have shown that such statistical measures of
potential output or full employment are very imprecise. Moreover, the most common
statistical constructs for these variables often have little in common with their relevant
theoretical counterparts. What’s more, different models of the economy can lead to
different theoretical concepts for such output gap or unemployment gap variables. So
relying on these constructed gap variables in the formulation of policy forces the central
bank to operate under a high degree of uncertainty.
1

Today, I will discuss an approach to dealing with such uncertainty – namely, relying on
systematic, rule-like behavior, in which the policy interest rate responds to the deviation
of inflation from a target. If the policy rule includes a measure of real activity, it is the
change in the level of activity or growth rate, rather than the output gap or the
unemployment gap.
The Benefits of Rules
Why use rules? At least since the work of Henry Simons, economists have understood
and debated the benefits of rules versus discretion in policymaking. 1 The modern and
more rigorous treatment of this issue is found in the seminal work of Finn Kydland and
Ed Prescott. 2 In their Nobel Prize-winning work, they demonstrated that a credible
commitment by policymakers to behave in a systematic, rule-like manner over time
leads to better economic outcomes than discretion. In monetary policy, less
discretionary behavior and a commitment to more systematic behavior have been
shown to lead to more economic stability – lower and less volatile inflation and less
volatile output.
Using a well-formulated, simple interest-rate rule as a benchmark is one way to achieve
many of the benefits of a commitment to systematic monetary policy. Because such a
rule is transparent and easy to monitor, it helps the public form expectations of future
policy and determine when a central bank is deviating from normal policy. Sometimes
deviations from the simple rule may be required – for example, during an economic
crisis like the one we’ve just experienced, or in the aftermath of the 9/11 attacks. In
these cases, monetary policymakers must communicate the reasons for the deviations
and how they intend to return policy to the norm. Following such a policy framework
based on a simple rule as a guideline and communicating any deviations will enhance
the policymakers’ credibility for following a systematic monetary policy, which leads to
additional benefits.
But what rule should we use? It’s important that our policy rule be robust enough to
work in a variety of economic conditions or stages of the business cycle, that it perform
well in a variety of economic models, and that it recognize that economic data are
measured imprecisely and are subject to revision. These criteria lead me to support a
rule based on deviations of inflation from the policymakers’ inflation target and on the
growth rate of output, rather than on the output gap commonly used in many variants
of the well-known Taylor-rule.

1

Henry C. Simons, “Rules versus Authorities in Monetary Policy,” Journal of Political Economy, 44:1
(January 1936).
2
Finn E. Kydland and Edward C. Prescott, “Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal
Plans,” Journal of Political Economy, 85 (January 1977), pp. 473-91.

2

The Problem with Gaps
Three problems arise when trying to rely on output or employment gaps to guide policy
choices in real time. First, theory does not always suggest that desirable policy should
be based on an output gap measure at all – it depends on the particular model and the
type of economic shocks that are hitting the economy. 3 Second, even in theoretical
models in which optimal policy is based on an output gap measure, such measures are
inherently unobservable and therefore must be statistically estimated. And third, the
most common statistical measures of the output gap do not correspond particularly well
to the theoretical measures that are relevant for policy decisions.
In other words, policy actions that respond to our typical measures of output gaps might
not improve economic welfare or economic stability. For example, consider a
technological improvement that increases the potential level of output more than the
level of actual output, perhaps because firms can’t adjust their labor and capital levels in
response until their current employment and equipment contracts expire. Such a
situation would result in a negative output gap – that is, actual output that is below
potential. But suppose our estimate of potential output is based on the trend in actual
output. The estimate of potential output based on such a longer-term trend would not
increase as much as actual output, leading to a positive measured output gap – actual
output that is above the estimated trend. Thus, the policy response suggested by this
statistical gap measure would be exactly the opposite of what the true gap would
indicate.
Another problem with statistical measures of gaps is that they are based on data that
are subject to significant revisions over time and that are significantly affected by the
choice of the sample period used to estimate them. 4 It turns out that the revisions to
output gap estimates are often nearly the same size as the output gap measures
themselves – which means that an estimated output gap observed in real time could
completely disappear or even change sign as the data are revised and updated. Thus,
these estimated gaps could easily point monetary policy in the wrong direction at the
time decisions have to be made.
Research has shown that data uncertainties are not just theoretical curiosities. They
have caused actual problems when policy has been based on mismeasured gaps,
resulting in unnecessary economic instability. A particularly poignant example is the

3

For example, in Michael Woodford’s model, the change in the theoretical gap, not the level of the gap, is
the relevant variable for welfare calculations and hence the relevant variable to which the interest rate
should respond. See Michael Woodford, “Optimal Monetary Policy Inertia,” NBER Working Paper 7261
(August 1999).
4
Both of these components of mismeasurement are explored in Athanasios Orphanides and Simon van
Norden, “The Unreliability of Output Gap Estimates in Real Time,” Review of Economics and Statistics,
84:4 (November 2002), pp. 569-83.

3

Great Inflation of the 1970s in the U.S.5 While I do not believe that mismeasurement is
the sole reason for the stagflation of that era, I do believe it was a contributing factor.
Part of the problem appears to have been caused by basing monetary policy on
unemployment gaps. Over much of the 1970s, real-time estimates of the natural rate of
unemployment indicated that the economy was operating below its full-employment
potential. In fact, the opposite was true. This misperception led to an inflationary bias
to policy, as policymakers reacted to the mismeasured unemployment gap. 6
In contrast, a good case can be made that the Fed seemed to follow more robust rules
during the mid to late 1990s, responding aggressively to deviations of inflation from a
target and to economic growth — not gaps. By doing so, the Fed averted a large
deflation that would have occurred if it had used real-time unemployment or output
gaps. 7 Chairman Greenspan’s choice not to base monetary policy on gaps had its
precursor under the leadership of William McChesney Martin. During most of Martin’s
chairmanship, the Fed raised interest rates early in recoveries, responding to economic
growth rather than gaps. 8
The Implications of Data Uncertainty for Monetary Policy Design
Policymakers should not base policy on poorly estimated data, and they should try to
minimize the degree to which the data uncertainty affects policy. 9 If policymakers
responded aggressively to mismeasured gaps, they would essentially build a policy error
into their rule. This would be counterproductive, increasing the variance of the true
output gap and inflation. 10
So, if we have problems in measuring output gaps, what type of rule should we use? I
believe it makes more sense to use an interest rate rule that responds aggressively to
movements in inflation relative to a target and, if it responds to real economic activity,
responds to a measure of the change in economic activity itself rather than some
deviation from unobserved potential. 11 While measures of the growth rate of output
5

See Athanasios Orphanides, “Monetary Policy Rules and the Great Inflation,” American Economic Review
Papers and Proceedings, 92:2 (May 2002), pp. 115-20.
6
See Orphanides (2002).
7
See Athanasios Orphanides and John C. Williams, “Robust Monetary Policy Rules with Unknown Natural
Rates,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2002), pp. 63-118.
8
See Robert L. Hetzel, The Monetary Policy of the Federal Reserve: A History (Cambridge University Press,
2008).
9
Useful papers are Orphanides and Williams (2002) and Athanasios Orphanides, “Monetary Policy
Evaluation with Noisy Information,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 50:3 (April 2003), pp. 605-31.
10
See Orphanides (2003).
11
See Bennett T. McCallum and Edward Nelson, “Performance of Operational Policy Rules in an Estimate
Semi-Classical Structural Model,” in John B Taylor, ed., Monetary Policy Rules (University of Chicago Press,
1999); Bennett T. McCallum, “Should Monetary Policy Respond Strongly to Output Gaps,” American
Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 91 (May 2001), pp. 258-62; and Carl E. Walsh, "Implications of
a Changing Economic Structure for the Strategy of Monetary Policy," in Monetary Policy and Uncertainty:

4

are also subject to data revisions, they are not dependent on an unobservable construct
associated with the level of output. Moreover, the measurement errors in growth rates
don’t tend to cumulate, which can often happen with mismeasured levels.
My preferred approach also is consistent with the idea that, as economic growth
accelerates, the economy’s underlying real rate of interest also rises, signaling the need
for tighter monetary policy. This is likely to keep policy ahead of the curve rather than
behind it — lowering rates sooner in a cyclical downturn and raising them earlier in a
recovery.
Summary
In summary, I believe that simple rules serve as a useful benchmark for setting
monetary policy. They allow policymakers to be more systematic and less discretionary
in their approach to policy. A commitment to systematic behavior has been shown to
result in more economic stability and lower inflation. Rules allow both policymakers
and the public to more easily discern when actual policy is deviating markedly from the
norm. When such deviations occur, policymakers would need to communicate the
reason. Thus, rules can lend more transparency to monetary policymaking.
In constructing a simple rule, though, we must choose our variables carefully. My
remarks have outlined three problems that arise when trying to base policy rules on an
output gap or an unemployment gap. Basing policy on such an ill-measured variable has
led to policy errors in the past and could do so in the future as well. In my view, policy
should respond aggressively to movements in inflation from a target, and if it responds
to economic activity, it should respond to measures of economic growth rather than an
output gap.
This approach has important implications in the current environment as various
economies around the world begin to recover from the global financial crisis and the
Great Recession. Although there is a good deal of uncertainty about the pace of those
recoveries, as the expansions continue, central banks will eventually need to tighten
monetary conditions. My remarks today are intended to highlight that statistical
measures of output gaps or unemployment gaps could very well appear to remain quite
wide, even when increases in economic growth and the outlook for inflation call for
such tightening. Explaining such decisions about the appropriate stance of monetary
policy will be challenging, and central bankers will need to communicate with the public
about these issues well in advance of their decisions to ensure that their policy actions
are not misunderstood.

Adapting to a Changing Economy, a symposium sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 28-30, 2003, pp. 297-348.

5