View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The National Economic Outlook and
Monetary Policy

Presented to the Greater Johnstown Cambria County Chamber of Commerce
Johnstown, PA
October 8, 2013

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

The National Economic Outlook and Monetary Policy
Greater Johnstown Cambria County Chamber of Commerce
October 8, 2013
Johnstown, PA
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Highlights:
• President Charles Plosser provides his economic outlook and notes that since there is little
evidence that additional asset purchases will improve the economic recovery, the time has
come for an expeditious phaseout of the purchase program.
• He indicates that the FOMC missed an excellent opportunity to begin this tapering process
in September, which illustrates just how difficult it will be to initiate any steps toward
normalization of monetary policy.
• Delaying the decision to taper the asset purchase program without clear and significant
departures from prior guidelines suggested the FOMC was changing the goalposts and
deviating from June’s forward guidance. Because the FOMC failed to adjust the pace of
asset purchases at that meeting, he believes the FOMC undermines the credibility of its own
forward guidance.
• President Plosser expects growth of around 3 percent in 2014. He expects unemployment
rates near 7 percent by the end of this year or early next year and close to 6.25 percent by
the end of 2014. Inflation expectations will be relatively stable, and inflation will move up
toward the FOMC target of 2 percent over the next year.
• President Plosser notes that while some of the decline in labor force participation has been
a result of transitory factors, the labor markets are also adjusting to longer-term structural
adjustments driven by demographics and technological advancements. Monetary policy
would be ineffective in counteracting such structural trends – and it should not be used to
try to do so.

Introduction
I want to thank the Greater Johnstown Cambria County Chamber of Commerce and
Johnstown Area Regional Industries (JARI) for hosting today’s luncheon. I especially
want to thank Glenn Wilson, president and CEO of AmeriServ Financial, Inc., and Bill
Polacek, president and CEO of JWF Industries, who both serve on advisory councils for

1

the Philadelphia Fed. Their valuable contributions to the councils help to ensure that
your local business conditions factor into the formulation of monetary policy.
Later this year, the Federal Reserve System will begin its centennial year, marking 100
years from the signing of the Federal Reserve Act on December 23, 1913, by President
Woodrow Wilson. The centennial period will run through the 100th anniversary of
when the 12 Federal Reserve Banks opened their doors on November 16, 1914.
While many Americans hear about the Fed in the news every day – perhaps a bit too
much these days – not everyone knows how we work or how we are structured. So, I
will begin with a little background on the Fed before I talk about my thoughts on the
economic outlook and monetary policy.
I have often described the Federal Reserve System as a uniquely American form of
central banking – a decentralized central bank. To understand how it came to be, it is
useful to review a little history. Just a few blocks from the Philadelphia Fed stand the
vestiges of our country’s two earlier attempts at a central bank, dating back to the early
years of our nation when Philadelphia was the major financial and political center of the
country.
Alexander Hamilton, our nation’s first secretary of the Treasury, championed the first
Bank of the United States, which received a 20-year charter from Congress and operated
from 1791 to 1811. Although the First Bank’s charter was not renewed, the War of 1812
and the ensuing inflation and economic turmoil convinced Congress to establish the
second Bank of the United States, which operated from 1816 to 1836. However, like its
predecessor, the Second Bank did not have its charter renewed by Congress. Both
institutions failed to overcome the public’s mistrust of centralized power and special
interests.
It took nearly 80 years before Congress tried again to establish a central bank. The
outcome was a new central bank with a unique governance structure designed to
decentralize authority and promote public confidence. With the passage of the Federal
2

Reserve Act of 1913, Congress provided for the establishment of independently
chartered regional Reserve Banks throughout the country, overseen by a Board of
Governors in Washington, D.C.
The act created a Reserve Bank Organization Committee to divide the country into no
fewer than eight and no more than 12 Federal Reserve Districts. As you can imagine,
almost immediately after the law was enacted, the committee started receiving
numerous letters and telegrams from local business owners, bankers, farmers, and
others, making the case for why a Reserve Bank should be located in their area. The
committee held meetings in 18 cities around the country before submitting a report to
Congress in April 1914, naming 12 cities as sites for Federal Reserve Banks. The Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia serves the Third District, which includes Delaware, the
southern half of New Jersey, and the eastern two-thirds of Pennsylvania.
The Reserve Banks distribute currency, act as a banker’s bank, and generally perform
the functions of a central bank, including serving as the bank for the U.S. Treasury. A
central bank also guides the country’s monetary policy. Within the Federal Reserve, the
body that makes monetary policy decisions is the Federal Open Market Committee, or
the FOMC. In establishing the FOMC in 1935, Congress gave votes to the seven
Governors in Washington and five Reserve Bank presidents. The current arrangement
has the New York Fed president serving as a permanent member and four of the other
11 presidents serving one-year terms on a rotating basis.
This structure ensures that our national monetary policy has its roots not just in
Washington or on Wall Street but also on Main Streets across our diverse nation.
Whether we vote or not, all Reserve Bank presidents attend the FOMC meetings,
participate in the discussions, and contribute to the Committee's assessment of the
economy and policy options. The Committee meets eight times a year to set monetary
policy. It discusses economic conditions and, in normal times, adjusts short-term
interest rates to best achieve the goals of monetary policy that Congress has set for us
in the Federal Reserve Act. Specifically, in 1977, Congress revised the act to instruct the
3

Fed to conduct policy “so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment,
stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.” Since moderate long-term
interest rates generally result when prices are stable, it is often said that Congress has
given the Fed a “dual mandate.”
The structure of the Fed was deliberately designed to preserve a diversity of views and
to provide checks and balances. Indeed, I believe the diversity of opinion around the
FOMC table is one of its great strengths, but that diversity of views also requires me to
note that I speak for myself and not for the Federal Reserve Board or for my colleagues
on the Federal Open Market Committee.
Now let me turn to the state of our economy as we enter the final quarter of 2013.
Economic Conditions
The economic expansion began in July 2009 – more than four years ago. It hasn’t been
a smooth path – frankly, it never is – and growth has been somewhat weaker than many
anticipated. However, progress is being made, and there are signs of broad-based
underlying strength in the economy.
The economy expanded at an annualized rate of 2.5 percent in the second quarter of
this year, up from 1.1 percent in the first quarter and just 0.4 percent in the fourth
quarter of 2012.
Fiscal drag, especially at the federal level, has weighed somewhat on economic growth
over the past three quarters. In the fourth quarter of 2012, sharp declines in federal
government spending subtracted 1.3 points from overall GDP, and in the second
quarter, it subtracted 0.2 points. Most of the decline has been in national defense
spending.
In contrast, the private sector has performed much better. Approximately half of the
second-quarter growth came from higher personal consumption, which was well
distributed across durable goods, nondurable goods, and services. The moderate pace
4

of spending was stronger than many expected. They had feared that the increased
payroll taxes and other sources of fiscal constraint would significantly depress the
consumer, but those concerns proved overblown. Improvements in household balance
sheets, reflecting lower leverage and higher net worth, as well as moderate growth of
disposable personal income, have supported spending this year.
Business investment also contributed to growth in the second quarter, but investment
has been increasing at only a modest pace so far this year. While sentiment has
improved, the data on new orders and shipments of nondefense capital goods do not
point to much of a pickup, at least in the near term. Better news comes from the
manufacturing sector, which has shown encouraging signs of late. The September
national ISM manufacturing survey and our own Business Outlook Survey of
manufacturers in the Third District each registered their fourth consecutive month of
expansion. Additionally, respondents to our recent survey were the most optimistic
they have been since the spring of 2011.
Nevertheless, as I travel the District and the country and talk to business leaders about
their plans for capital spending and hiring, uncertainty about the course of fiscal policy is
a common theme in their discussions. Most mention the stalemate in Washington and
the uncertainties over tax and spending policies, and especially health care. There is no
question that such factors are restraining investment and hiring and contributing in a
significant way to the sluggish recovery.
Housing, however, remains a bright spot. The housing sector has shown significant
improvement over the past two years. Housing inventories are down, sales are up, and
prices are now rising in many localities. Construction spending has also expanded,
though activity has leveled off in recent months, which may reflect higher mortgage
rates.
I expect overall economic growth to accelerate to around 3 percent next year, a pace
that is slightly above trend. This is far from the robust growth that many would like to
5

see, but uncertainties loom large. Nevertheless, it represents steady progress and an
improving economy. My forecast is in line with those of my colleagues on the FOMC,
whose most recent projections had a central tendency of growth of 2.0 to 2.3 percent
for 2013, accelerating to 2.9 to 3.1 percent in 2014.
The moderate pace of expansion has supported sustained growth in payroll
employment and declines in the unemployment rate. Monthly job gains averaged
180,000 for the first eight months of this year, very similar to last year’s pace. The
sustained expansion in payrolls means that the U.S. has regained more than threequarters (78 percent) of the 8.7 million jobs lost in the Great Recession. Pennsylvania
has seen a similar improvement, also regaining about 78 percent of the 258,000 jobs it
lost.
The unemployment rate has improved, dropping from 8.1 percent in August 2012 to 7.3
percent in August 2013, the most recent number available. The total number of people
unemployed has declined by 1.2 million over the past 12 months and is down 4 million
since the peak in October 2009.
I anticipate that over the next year the unemployment rate will continue to decline at
about the same pace we’ve seen over the past two years. This should lead to an
unemployment rate of about 6.25 percent by the end of next year. This makes me
somewhat more optimistic than many of my FOMC colleagues, who don’t see the
unemployment rate reaching 6.5 percent until sometime in the first half of 2015.
Many analysts have dismissed the steady decline in the unemployment rate because it
has been driven to some degree by people dropping out of the labor force rather than
finding jobs. Such actions depress the labor force participation rate. But even the
unemployment rate measures that include these discouraged workers and those
working part time for economic reasons have shown sustained declines as the recovery
has progressed.

6

It is important to recognize that labor force participation is influenced not only by the
state of the business cycle but also by longer-term factors, like demographics. For
example, labor force participation for those aged 16 to 19 years has declined 7.2
percentage points since the start of the recession in December 2007, a sharp drop, to be
sure. But in the seven-year period before the recession, participation by that age group
fell 11 percentage points. For those aged 20 to 24 years, participation has fallen 3.6
percentage points since the start of the recession, the exact same trend as in the
preceding seven-year period. In fact, every age group except those aged 55 and older
saw decreasing participation rates well before the recession. And the overall
participation rate was falling too.
This longer-term decline in labor force participation is separate from the decline we
typically see during recessions. For example, independent of the business cycle, the
entry of more women into the labor force was a major factor in the rising participation
rate for several decades. Our earliest data are from 1948, and at that time, only one in
three women were in the labor force. That rate nearly doubled to a peak of 60 percent
in the late 1990s. Since then, though, female participation has been drifting down. In
addition, the male labor force participation rate has been declining steadily since we
started collecting data in 1948. Some of the decline in both male and female
participation is attributable to the aging baby boomers, who entered their prime
working years in the 1970s and 1980s. As that generation moves through older age
brackets, participation becomes lower, bringing down the overall rate. A broad research
agenda is attempting to distinguish how much recent declines in participation can be
explained by these demographic trends and how much is cyclical or transitory, but the
estimates vary greatly. 1 Still, there is widespread acknowledgment that the monthly job
1

Researchers at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago estimate that nearly half of the decline in
participation over the past 13 years is attributable to these long-running demographic trends. See Daniel
Aaronson, Jonathan Davis, and Luojia Hu, “Explaining the Decline in the U.S. Labor Force Participation
Rate,” Chicago Fed Letter, No. 296, March 2012. Also, the Chicago Fed estimates that the monthly job
growth required to bring down the unemployment rate is sharply lower than what was required in the
1980s and 1990s, when labor force participation rates were increasing. See Daniel Aaronson and Scott
Brave, “Estimating the Trend in Employment Growth,” Chicago Fed Letter, No. 312, July 2013.

7

growth required to bring down the unemployment rate is considerably lower than what
was required in the 1980s and 1990s when labor force participation rates were
increasing. Consequently, while some of the decline in labor force participation is
cyclical, there is certainly a secular component too. Monetary policy would be
ineffective in counteracting such demographic and secular trends – and it should not be
used to try to do so.
What monetary policy is designed to do, at least over the long run, is control inflation.
In my view, price stability is the key part of our mandate. The Fed’s preferred gauge for
inflation, the change in the price index for personal consumption expenditures, or PCE,
has averaged about 1.8 percent over the past three years and 2 percent over the past 20
years. Over the past year, it has averaged 1.2 percent. This is below the FOMC’s longrun goal of 2 percent, and some have voiced concerns about deflation. I do not perceive
that we will have a deflation problem. Some of the lower readings on inflation appear
to reflect some transitory factors, such as the cut in payments to Medicare providers
imposed earlier this year as part of the sequester. More recent readings have been
closer to goal, and I anticipate, as the FOMC indicated in its most recent statement, that
inflation will move back toward our target over the medium term. I do see some upside
risk to inflation in the intermediate to longer term given the large amount of monetary
accommodation we have added and continue to add to the economy.
Monetary Policy
So let me turn to some observations about monetary policy. Over the past five years,
the Federal Reserve has taken extraordinary actions to support the economic recovery.
The Fed has lowered its policy rate — the federal funds rate — to essentially zero,
where it has been for almost five years. Since the policy rate cannot go lower, the Fed
has attempted to provide additional accommodation through large-scale asset
purchases, or quantitative easing. These purchases have greatly expanded the size and
lengthened the maturity of the assets on the Fed's balance sheet.

8

The Fed is also using communications to inform the public about how monetary policy is
likely to evolve in the future. In Fed speak, this is called forward guidance. On interest
rates, the FOMC has said that it expects to keep the fed funds rate at essentially zero at
least until the unemployment rate falls to 6.5 percent, so long as inflation one to two
years ahead is projected to be no more than 2.5 percent and the public’s inflation
expectations remain well anchored. It also anticipates that the highly accommodative
stance of monetary policy will remain appropriate for a considerable time after the
economic recovery strengthens.
On asset purchases, the FOMC has indicated that it will continue the purchases until the
outlook for the labor market has improved substantially in the context of price stability.
In addition, at his June press conference, Chairman Bernanke indicated that if incoming
economic data were broadly consistent with the FOMC’s economic projections, which
anticipated continued gains in labor markets, moderate growth that picks up, and
inflation that moves back toward the 2 percent target over time, then the FOMC would
begin to reduce the pace of its purchases sometime this year. And if the economy
evolves as expected, we would continue to reduce the pace and end the purchases
around the middle of next year.
After the June press conference and over the course of the summer, there was an
increasingly widespread public belief that the FOMC would begin to reduce the pace of
its asset purchases in September. Yet at that September meeting, the Committee
decided to make no change in monetary policy. The Fed continues to purchase $40
billion of agency mortgage-backed securities and $45 billion of longer-term Treasury
securities each month. Proceeds of maturing or prepaid securities are being reinvested.
As a result, the Fed's balance sheet, which includes about $3.7 trillion in assets, is
growing at a pace of about $85 billion a month. The decision to maintain the pace of
purchases and await more evidence of sustained economic progress came as quite a
surprise to the public and there ensued widespread public debate about the FOMC’s
communications surrounding its policy intentions.
9

In my view, the incoming data between the June and September meetings were largely
in line with our June forecasts. While it is true that the FOMC projections for 2013 were
revised down slightly, the differences between the central tendencies reported in June
and September were statistically and economically insignificant.
To delay tapering of our current asset purchase scheme without clear and significant
departures from prior guidelines suggested the FOMC was changing the goalposts and
deviating from June’s forward guidance. This undermines the credibility of the
Committee and reduces the effectiveness of forward guidance as a policy tool. It also
contributes to additional uncertainty regarding the future course of monetary policy.
The decision not to begin tapering our asset purchases was also read in some quarters
as a sign that the FOMC had become much less confident that growth would be
sustained in the manner the Committee envisioned in June. Thus, we undermined our
own credibility as well as the public’s confidence in the economy. These were not the
messages that I wanted to send. Thus, I disagreed with the decision not to go forward
with a modest reduction in the pace of our asset purchases.
The Fed’s balance sheet is expanding rapidly due to these purchases and complicating
the eventual exit from this period of extraordinary monetary ease. There is little
evidence that continued efforts to increase accommodation through asset purchases
will lead to any significant improvement in the labor markets or economic growth.
Thus, I believe the time has come for an expeditious phaseout of the purchase program.
Conclusion
In summary, I believe that the economy is continuing to improve at a moderate pace.
We are likely to see growth of around 2.5 percent this year, but that pace should pick up
to around 3 percent in 2014. Prospects for labor markets will continue to improve
gradually, and I expect unemployment rates near 7 percent by the end of this year and
6.25 percent by the end of 2014. I believe that inflation expectations will be relatively
stable and that inflation will move up to our goal of 2 percent over the next year.
10

Based on this outlook and the improvement in labor market conditions, I believe it
would be appropriate for the Fed to begin to reduce the pace at which we are
expanding our balance sheet and to bring the purchase program to a close. We missed
an excellent opportunity to begin this tapering process in September. In my mind, this
illustrates just how difficult it is going to be to wean ourselves off the extraordinary
process of increasing accommodation we have embarked upon and begin to normalize
monetary policy in a timely manner that ensures a healthy and stable economy in the
future. Because the FOMC failed to adjust the pace of asset purchases in response to
the improvement in economic conditions, I believe the FOMC undermines the credibility
of its own forward guidance.

11