View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Monetary Rules: Theory and Practice

Frameworks for Central Banking in the Next Century Policy Conference
Hoover Institution
Stanford, CA
May 30, 2014

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

Monetary Rules: Theory and Practice
Frameworks for Central Banking in the Next Century Policy Conference
Hoover Institution
Stanford, CA
May 30, 2014
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Highlights
•

President Charles Plosser discusses his views on the benefits of a systematic and rule-like
approach to monetary policy.

•

President Plosser outlines his proposals to indicate the likely behavior of the policy rate based
on a few different Taylor-like rules that have been consistent with past conduct of monetary
policy and are robust to our uncertainties regarding the true economic model.

•

President Plosser believes that the model created by the Federal Reserve Board staff, called
FRB/US, seems to be a reasonable starting point for providing economic forecasts based on
those rule-based policies; however, other models would be useful to consider.

Note: President Plosser presented related remarks on May 28, 2014, at the 2014 Bank of Japan–
Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies Conference.

Introduction
I would like to thank John Taylor for inviting me to participate in this panel discussion about a
subject that I feel is very important. Rules-based policy is a topic that I have discussed
numerous times in the past few years, urging policymakers to seek a more systematic approach
to policymaking. I am particularly honored to be on a panel with my colleague John Williams,
whose research in this area has been an important influence on my views, as well as Tom
Sargent. In Tom’s case, there probably isn’t an economist in this room who hasn’t been
1

influenced by his work and his contributions to economics. But before I go any further, I should
begin with the usual disclaimer that my views are my own and do not necessarily reflect those
of the Federal Reserve System or my colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC).
The Theoretical Justification for Rules
The theory part of this session’s title is well established. In their Nobel Prize-winning work, Finn
Kydland and Ed Prescott demonstrated that a credible commitment by policymakers to behave
in a systematic, rule-like manner over time leads to better outcomes than discretion. 1 Since
then, numerous papers using a variety of models have investigated the benefits of rule-like
behavior in monetary policy and found that there are indeed significant benefits. 2 Policies
characterized by commitment have been shown to lead to more economic stability — lower
and less volatile inflation and less volatile output. In fact, the mainstream theoretical models
that we use for monetary and macroeconomic analysis are built on the notion that monetary
policy is conducted in a rule-like manner.
The Practice
The practice part of the session title has proven to be a bit more elusive. The science of
monetary policy has not progressed to the point where we can specify the optimal rule for
setting monetary policy. The reason is that optimal rules, that is, those that maximize
economic welfare, are highly dependent on the particular model from which they are derived,
and there is no broad-based consensus for the right model. More relevant is the finding that
the optimal rule for one model can produce very bad outcomes in another model. In addition,
optimal rules can often be quite complex, thus making them difficult to implement and to
communicate to the public. In other words, they may not be very transparent.

1

Finn E. Kydland and Edward C. Prescott, “Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans,”
Journal of Political Economy, 85 (June 1977), pp. 473–91.

2

For an excellent overview, see Richard Clarida, Jordi Gali, and Mark Gertler, “The Science of Monetary Policy,”
Journal of Economic Literature (December 1999), pp. 1661–1707.

2

However, these limitations to implementing optimal policy rules should not deter us from
efforts to adopt a more systematic rule-like approach to the conduct of policy. There has been
a great deal of progress made in identifying simple rules that appear to perform well in a
variety of models and environments. Such robust rules can form a basis for developing more
systematic, rule-like policymaking.
One important and desirable characteristic of a systematic and rule-like approach to policy
relates to communication. In particular, it is an approach that is easily communicated to the
public and thus greatly improves the transparency and predictability of monetary policy, which
reduces surprises. The public and markets are more informed about the course of monetary
policy because they understand how policymakers are likely to react to changing economic
circumstances. Equally important in my view is that greater clarity about the policymakers’
reaction function strengthens accountability and thus can serve to preserve the central bank’s
independence.
The most well-known simple rule, of course, is the one proposed by John Taylor in 1993.3 The
Taylor rule and the family of rules it has inspired call for setting the nominal fed funds rate
based on three factors: the economy’s long-run real interest rate plus the Fed’s target rate of
inflation, the deviation of inflation from the central bank’s target, and the departure of real
GDP from some measure of “potential” GDP. The rule implies, for example, that when inflation
is above target, the funds rate should increase by more than one-for-one with the deviation,
and when GDP is below “potential,” the funds rate should be reduced.
The attractiveness of Taylor-like rules for monetary policy goes beyond their intuitive appeal or
the fact that they seem to describe the actual behavior of monetary policy reasonably well.
Taylor-like rules tend to fall in the class of those rules that are robust. That is, they yield good
3

John B. Taylor, “Discretion Versus Policy Rules in Practice,” Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, NorthHolland, 39, 1993, pp. 195–214.

3

results in a variety of theoretical settings. This feature is of enormous practical importance.
Given our uncertainty about the true model of the economy, knowing that systematic policy in
the form of a Taylor-like rule delivers good outcomes in a variety of models means that simple,
robust rules can provide useful guidance for policy.
Given model uncertainty and data measurement problems, there are, of course, limitations to
the use of a simple rule. The rule is basically intended to work well on average, but central
banks look at many variables in determining policy. There inevitably will be times when
economic developments fall outside the scope of our models and warrant unusual monetary
policy action. Events such as 9/11, the Asian financial crisis, the collapse of Lehman Brothers,
and the 1987 stock market crash may require departures from a simple rule. Having articulated
a rule guiding policymaking in normal times, however, policymakers will be expected to explain
the departures from the rule in these unusual circumstances. With a rule as a baseline,
departures can be quantified and inform us how excessively tight or easy policy might be
relative to normal. If the events are temporary, policymakers will have to explain how and
when policy is likely to return to normal. Thus, a simple rule provides a valuable benchmark for
assessing the appropriate stance of policy. That makes it a useful tool to enhance effective
communication and transparency.
Rules and Forward Guidance
In addition to providing important guidance for current policy decisions, Taylor-like rules can
also be extremely useful in providing guidance for the expected future path of policy. Such
forward guidance has received a good deal of attention recently. One reason for this increased
attention is that short-term rates have been constrained by the zero lower bound. Thus,
forward guidance and communication regarding future policy decisions take on greater
significance.
However, forward guidance is not a separate or independent policy tool. Its effectiveness is
intimately related to other features of monetary policy. Monetary policy should be thought of
4

more holistically, if you will. How effective we are with forward guidance, for example, can only
be assessed or thought of in the context of a central bank’s overall approach to policy, including
its approach to communication and transparency.
In particular, I see a credible, rule-like approach to policy and the general openness and
transparency of the policy process as essential elements in shaping expectations. Indeed, a
commitment to a policy framework that is systematic and rule-like provides the foundation for
establishing expectations concerning the future path of policy and thus forward guidance.
Rules as Benchmarks: A Step Forward
So from my perspective, using Taylor-like rules to shape current and expected future policy is
an important and useful part of any monetary policy framework. The operational question is
how might one go about such an effort? This is not a trivial assignment. As I mentioned at the
outset, it has proved to be quite elusive.
In a stylized world, where there is a single monetary policymaker who has considerable
confidence in a model of the economy, communication would include a forecast derived from
this model. This forecast would incorporate a policy path that yields the best economic
outcomes based on that single policymaker’s views.
Unfortunately, we don’t live in such a world. Monetary policymaking is often conducted by
committee, and divergent views can and often do exist. While this can be clumsy at times, such
governance mechanisms ensure that various views are heard in an environment that promotes
better decisions and better outcomes.
Nevertheless, I believe that given the nature of U.S. institutional arrangements, Taylor-like rules
can serve a very useful purpose. Specifically, they could underpin the construction of a periodic
detailed monetary policy report, a feature of communication that has been adopted by many

5

central banks around the world. However, while these reports have many similarities, there are
some key differences.
Many central banks include detailed forecasts in their published reports and highlight risks
along with the outlook. This communication about the evolution of key economic variables
that shape policy is important, but there is still debate about the nature of the forecasts and
the assumptions that underlie them.
A critical piece of a forecast emanating from the central bank is the nature of the future path of
the policy rate. Should a central bank’s published forecast be based on its assessment of what
the policy rate path is likely to be, perhaps based on its reaction function, or should the forecast
be based on an interest rate path that is more arbitrary, such as a constant interest rate path or
one that is related to market expectations?
An alternative approach that could easily be adopted would be to indicate the likely behavior of
interest rates based on a few different Taylor-like rules that have been consistent with the
conduct of monetary policy in the past or ones that are considered robust across various
models of the economy. Doing so would require agreement on a particular model in order to
produce the resulting rule-based behavior. For the Fed, the economic model developed by the
Board’s staff, called FRB/US, seems like a reasonable place to start. Such an exercise could also
be enhanced, I believe, by using some of the dynamic stochastic general equilibrium, or DSGE,
models that have been developed within the Federal Reserve System.
The FOMC could then use its biannual monetary policy reports to communicate the results and
whether and why it anticipates policy to be somewhat more restrained or more
accommodative relative to the projections given by the various rules. The monetary policy
report could also include various views that may differ from the baseline summaries. Policy
statements between reports can refer back to the reports to provide consistency in the
Committee’s communications with the public.
6

Performing this exercise would illustrate the various dimensions of uncertainty that
policymakers face. For example, there is model uncertainty, forecast uncertainty, and the
variations implied by different rules. Many central banks use fan charts and other devices to
highlight such bands of uncertainty about the forecast, and the Fed should do the same. It
would provide a better sense of the likely direction of policy and the variables most related
systematically to that policy. Further, this type of communication would push the FOMC to
conduct policy in a more systematic manner, which I believe will lead to better economic
outcomes over the longer run.
Conclusions
I am fully aware that we need to take great care in providing more specific forms of forward
guidance so that we avoid a false sense of certainty and a mistaken sense of commitment. Yet,
I believe systematic rule-like monetary policymaking can enhance economic performance, and
therefore, I favor clearer communication concerning the formulation of policy.
Providing information about how the policy path is likely to evolve forces policymakers to think
more deeply and more systematically about policy. Communication about that path, in turn,
gives the public a much deeper understanding of the analytical approach that guides monetary
policy.

7