View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Monetary Policy and a Brightening
Economy
2014 Economic Forecast
Lyons Companies, the University of Delaware’s Center for Economic Education and
Entrepreneurship, and Alfred Lerner College of Business and Economics

February 11, 2014

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

Monetary Policy and a Brightening Economy
2014 Economic Forecast
Lyons Companies, the University of Delaware’s Center for Economic Education and
Entrepreneurship, and Alfred Lerner College of Business and Economics
Newark, DE
February 11, 2014
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Note: President Plosser presented similar remarks at the Simon Business School in
Rochester, NY, on February 5, 2014.

Highlights
• President Charles Plosser provides his economic outlook for 2014 and reports that the
decision of the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) to reduce the pace of asset
purchases was a step in the right direction.
• President Plosser expects growth of about 3 percent in 2014. He also expects the
unemployment rate to continue its steady decline and to reach about 6.2 percent by the
end of 2014. Inflation expectations will be relatively stable, and inflation will move up
toward the FOMC target of 2 percent over the next year.
•

Based on the economic progress that has been made and his economic outlook, President
Plosser believes it is appropriate to end asset purchases, and he supported the FOMC’s
decision in January to continue to reduce the pace of purchases.

•

A case can be made for ending the current asset purchase program sooner to reflect the
improvement in the economic outlook and to lessen some of the communications problems
the FOMC will face with its forward guidance.

Introduction
I am delighted to return once again to the University of Delaware to speak at this annual
event. This is a great event for the region and I am pleased to see it grow year after
year.
1

I would like to begin my remarks this morning with a bit of history. We are observing
the 100th anniversary of the Federal Reserve and that gives me the opportunity, or the
excuse, to offer a perspective on this important, but sometimes misunderstood,
institution. I should note that my views are my own and do not necessarily reflect those
of the Federal Reserve System or my colleagues on the Federal Open Market
Committee.
On December 23, 1913, President Woodrow Wilson signed the act that created the
Federal Reserve System, and the 12 Federal Reserve Banks opened their doors on
November 16, 1914. I have often described the Federal Reserve as a uniquely American
form of a central bank – a decentralized central bank. To understand why, we need to
consider two earlier attempts at central banking in the United States. Just a few blocks
from the Philadelphia Fed’s present building on Independence Mall, you will find the
vestiges of both institutions, dating back to the early years when Philadelphia was the
major financial and political center of the country.
Alexander Hamilton, our first secretary of the Treasury, championed the First Bank of
the United States to help our young nation manage its financial affairs. The First Bank
received a 20-year charter from Congress and operated from 1791 to 1811. Although
this charter was not renewed, the War of 1812 and the ensuing inflation and economic
turmoil convinced Congress to establish the Second Bank of the United States, which
operated from 1816 to 1836. However, Congress could not override the veto of
President Andrew Jackson, and the Second Bank’s charter also lapsed. Both institutions
failed to overcome the public’s mistrust of centralized power and special interests.
Nearly 80 years later, Congress tried again. To balance political, economic, and
geographic interests, Congress created a Federal Reserve System of 12 regional Reserve
Banks with oversight provided by a Board of Governors in Washington, D.C. This
decentralized central bank was structured to overcome concerns that its actions would
be dominated either by political interests in Washington or by financial interests on Wall
Street.
2

These 12 Reserve Banks perform several roles. They distribute currency, act as a
bankers’ bank, and generally perform the functions of a central bank, which includes
serving as the bank for the U.S. Treasury. They also play a critical role in supervising
many banks and bank holding companies across the country.
Each Reserve Bank has a nine-member board of directors selected in a nonpartisan way
to represent a cross-section of banking, commercial, and community interests. Pat
Harker, president of the University of Delaware, serves on our board. These directors
fulfill the traditional governance role, but they also provide valuable insights into
economic and financial conditions, which contribute to our assessment of the economy.
The Reserve Banks seek to stay in touch with Main Street in other ways. Some have
Branch boards, and all have advisory councils. Reserve Banks also collect and analyze
data and conduct surveys of economic activity. This rich array of information and the
diverse views from across the country help policymakers paint a mosaic of the economy
that is essential as we formulate national monetary policy.
Within the Federal Reserve, the body that makes monetary policy decisions is the
Federal Open Market Committee, or the FOMC. Here again, Congress has designed the
system with a number of checks and balances. Since 1935, the composition of the
FOMC has included the seven Governors in Washington, who are appointed by the
President of the United States and confirmed by the Senate, as well as the president of
the New York Fed, and four other Reserve Bank presidents who serve one-year terms as
members on a rotating basis.
Whether we vote or not, all Reserve Bank presidents attend the FOMC meetings,
participate in the discussions, and contribute to the Committee’s assessment of the
economy and policy options. The FOMC has eight regularly scheduled meetings each
year to set monetary policy. The first one in 2014 was held just two weeks ago. In
normal times, the Committee votes to adjust short-term interest rates to achieve the
goals of monetary policy that Congress has set for us.
3

Congress spelled out the current set of monetary policy goals in 1978. The amended
Federal Reserve Act specifies that the FOMC “shall maintain long run growth of the
monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with the economy’s long run potential
to increase production, so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment,
stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.” Since moderate long-term
interest rates generally result when prices are stable and the economy is operating at
full employment, many have interpreted these instructions as being a dual mandate to
manage fluctuations in employment in the short run while preserving price stability in
the long run.
Economic Conditions
In order to determine the appropriate monetary policy to promote these goals, the
FOMC must monitor and assess economic developments. So, let me turn to an
assessment of our economy as we enter 2014.
In a nutshell, my view is that the economy is on firmer footing than it has been for the
past several years. So let’s look at some of the details of how last year ended and the
implications for the coming year.
Real output grew at a 3.2 percent annual pace in the fourth quarter of last year,
following a 4.1 percent growth rate in the third quarter. That means economic growth
doubled in the second half of 2013 compared with the first half. Consumer spending
and business investment in equipment ended the year with strong increases. Inventory
investment and net exports also contributed to growth. On the other side of the ledger,
a decline in residential investment and a sharp decrease in federal government spending
subtracted from growth in the fourth quarter of the year. Going forward, I expect that
there will be less fiscal drag in 2014 than we saw in 2013 and that housing will continue
its recovery.
Personal consumption, which accounts for more than two-thirds of GDP, advanced at an
annual rate of 3.3 percent in the fourth quarter, the highest personal consumption
4

growth rate since fourth quarter 2010. Rising house prices and stock prices have helped
improve consumer balance sheets, and steady job growth has added to wage and salary
growth, all of which have supported spending.
On the job front, the January employment report showed payroll gains of 113,000 jobs,
following an increase of 75,000 jobs in December, which was below many analysts’
expectations. Yet, these numbers were affected by the unseasonably cold and snowy
weather. Indeed, winter weather has continued to be unusually disruptive, and that is
making it difficult to assess underlying economic trends. I suspect it may be another
couple of months before we have a better read on the economy – hopefully the
weather will turn better before that!
We have to remember that these employment numbers are subject to revisions, and
such revisions can be significant. For instance, in the latest report the November jobs
number was revised up by 33,000, from 241,000 to 274,000, while the December
number was also revised up by 1,000 to 75,000.
Because of month-to-month volatility and data revisions, I prefer not to read too much
into the most recent numbers but, instead, look at averages over several months. Here
the news remains positive. Based on the latest revision, firms added an average of
194,000 jobs per month in 2013, somewhat better than the pace in 2012. This
consistent pace of job growth was enough to drop the unemployment rate 1.2
percentage points last year. In January, it fell a bit further to 6.6 percent. This is
noticeably lower than the FOMC anticipated in its Summary of Economic Projections in
September 2012, when we started the current asset purchase program. That is, the
labor market has performed better than expected, according to the unemployment rate
measure.
Should we be skeptical of the unemployment rate as an indicator of labor market
conditions? Some people are because the decline in the unemployment rate reflects
not only increases in employment but declines in labor force participation as well.
5

Declines in participation can include discouraged workers who have stopped looking for
work because it is difficult to find a job. There is concern in some quarters that the
unemployment rate will move back up significantly when these discouraged workers
reenter the labor force. Based on research by my staff, I am less concerned about this
possibility. 1
First, it is important to realize that labor force participation rates can decline for reasons
other than a rise in discouraged workers. Indeed, we have seen steadily declining
participation rates since 2000 that reflect demographic changes, most notably the aging
of the baby boomers. This trend is continuing and has long been expected to
accelerate.
Second, detailed analysis of the Current Population Survey’s micro data indicates that
about three-quarters of the decline in participation since the start of the recession in
December 2007 can be accounted for by increased retirements and movements into
disability. Some of these increases might have been driven by the state of the economy.
For example, some baby boomers may have moved their retirement decision forward
after losing a job. Nevertheless, few of these individuals are likely to reenter the labor
force. So, while I do expect some discouraged workers to reenter the labor force as the
economy improves, I still believe the overall unemployment rate remains a good
summary statistic of labor market conditions.
The business sector is also entering the year on a positive note. At the national level,
manufacturing activity accelerated over the final three months of 2013. The
Philadelphia Fed’s Business Outlook Survey of regional manufacturing, which is a
reliable indicator of national manufacturing trends, also showed that manufacturing
activity picked up in the second half of 2013. In January, the survey’s general activity
index posted its eighth consecutive positive number. Expectations for manufacturing
1

Shigeru Fujita, “On the Causes of Declines in the Labor Force Participation Rate,” Research Rap Special
Report, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, February 6, 2014.

6

activity six months ahead also remained positive. This gives me some hope that
business fixed investment, which has been generally lackluster during the course of the
recovery, will pick up somewhat this year. Indeed, we saw a nice rebound in equipment
spending in the fourth quarter.
Inflation has been running below the FOMC’s long-run goal of 2 percent. The Fed’s
preferred measure of inflation is the year-over-year change in the price index for
personal consumption expenditures, or PCE inflation. It came in at 1.1 percent last year.
It is important to defend our 2 percent inflation target from both below and above. But
I believe inflation is likely to move up. Economic growth is firming, and some of the
factors that have held inflation down, such as the one-time cut in payments to Medicare
providers, are likely to abate over time.
An additional and important determinant of actual inflation is consumer and business
expectations of inflation. I am encouraged that inflation expectations remain near their
longer-term averages and consistent with our 2 percent target. Thus, I anticipate, as the
FOMC indicated in its most recent statement, that inflation will move back toward our
target over time. Indeed, given the large amount of monetary accommodation we have
added and continue to add to the economy, I think there is some upside risk to inflation
in the longer term.
Although growth in the first quarter is likely to be somewhat slower than the rapid pace
we saw in the second half of last year, overall, I anticipate economic growth of around 3
percent this year, a pace that is slightly above trend. Everyone would like to see robust
growth of 5 to 6 percent, but I don’t see that happening. Nevertheless, I do see steady
progress and an improving economy. This growth is sufficient to result in a continued
decline in the unemployment rate, which should reach about 6.2 percent by the end of
2014.
Of course, with any forecast, there are risks. The current volatility in emerging market
currencies could pose a risk if it were to spill over more broadly into other financial
7

markets. But at this point, I do not consider it a significant risk to the U.S. economy.
While there continues to be some downside risks, for the first time in a few years, I see
a potential for some upside risks to the economic outlook. We need to consider this
possibility as we calibrate monetary policy.
Monetary Policy
The Federal Reserve has taken extraordinary policy actions to support the economic
recovery. The Fed has lowered its policy rate — the federal funds rate — to essentially
zero, where it has been for more than five years. Since the policy rate cannot go any
lower, the Fed has attempted to provide additional accommodation through large-scale
asset purchases. We are now in our third round of this quantitative easing, or, as it is
commonly called, QE3. These purchases have greatly expanded the size and lengthened
the maturity of the assets on the Fed’s balance sheet.
The Fed is also using forward guidance as a policy tool, which is intended to inform the
public about the way monetary policy is likely to evolve in the future. In this dimension,
the FOMC has indicated that it intends to leave the policy rate near zero well past the
time that the unemployment rate falls below the 6.5 percent threshold. The FOMC had
previously indicated this was the earliest point at which it would consider raising
interest rates, especially if projected inflation continues to run below the Committee’s
2 percent target. On asset purchases, the FOMC has indicated that it will continue the
purchases until the outlook for the labor market has improved substantially in the
context of price stability.
Yet, with the economy having improved substantially over the last year and the outlook
brightening, the time has come for the FOMC to slow the pace at which it is adding
monetary accommodation, which is to say, ease our foot off the accelerator. 2 My
2

For more on the subject, see Charles I. Plosser, “The Outlook and the Hazards of Accelerationist Policy,”
remarks before The University of Delaware Center for Economic Education and Entrepreneurship,
Newark, DE, February 14, 2012.

8

personal view is that the process should have started sooner and proceeded more
expeditiously. Nevertheless, the FOMC did decide in December to take a very modest
step by reducing asset purchases from $85 billion to $75 billion per month, and then
reduced this by another $10 billion to $65 billion a month in January.
The FOMC indicated that if incoming information broadly supports the expectation of
ongoing improvement in labor market conditions and inflation moving back toward its
longer-run objective, then we’ll likely reduce the pace of purchases further in measured
steps at future meetings. Former Chairman Ben Bernanke indicated in his December
press conference that if we are making progress in terms of inflation and continued job
gains, then the program would be concluded late in 2014.
Notice that even though we are reducing the pace at which we are purchasing longerterm assets, we are still adding monetary policy accommodation. So, the foot is still on
the accelerator. My preference would be that we conclude the purchases sooner rather
than later.
I believe a good case can be made for speeding up the pace of our taper if the economic
outlook plays out as I expect. As I noted earlier, the unemployment rate fell 1.2
percentage points last year, and again in January to 6.6 percent. This is a much sharper
decline than anticipated when we started the purchase program in September 2012.
We are now only one-tenth of a point from the 6.5 percent threshold in our forward
guidance for interest rates.
The FOMC has indicated that it doesn’t anticipate raising rates when the economy
crosses that threshold. However, I do believe that we have a communications
challenge. We have not described how policy will be conducted after the
unemployment rate passes 6.5 percent. Last summer, it was thought that we would
stop asset purchases by the time unemployment reached 7 percent. Well, that didn’t
happen. What is the argument for continuing to increase monetary policy
accommodation when labor market conditions are improving more quickly than
9

anticipated and inflation has stabilized and is projected to move back to goal? The
longer we continue purchases in such an environment, the more likely we will fall
behind the curve in reducing the extraordinary degree of monetary policy
accommodation. With the economy awash in reserves, the costs of such a misfire could
be considerably higher than usual, fomenting higher inflation and perhaps financial
instability.
My preference was, and remains, to scale back our purchase program at a faster pace to
reflect the strengthening economy. Given the falling unemployment rate, our
communications should be focused on how economic conditions will determine the
interest rate path. Continuing to buy assets is neither helpful nor essential.
Conclusion
In summary, I believe that the economy is continuing to improve at a moderate pace.
We are likely to see growth of around 3 percent in 2014. Prospects for labor markets
will continue to improve, and I expect the unemployment rate will continue its decline,
reaching 6.2 percent by the end of 2014. I also believe that inflation expectations will
be relatively stable and that inflation will move up toward our goal of 2 percent over the
next year.
On monetary policy, we must back away from increasing the degree of policy
accommodation in a manner commensurate with an improving economy. Reducing the
pace of asset purchases to $65 billion a month is moving in the right direction, but that
may prove to be insufficient if the economy continues to play out according to the
FOMC forecasts. I believe the economy has met the criteria for ending the asset
purchases as there has been significant improvement in labor market conditions. I also
believe that further increases in the balance sheet are unlikely to provide appreciable
benefits for the recovery and may have unintended consequences. A case can be made
for ending the current asset purchase program sooner to reflect the improvement in the
economic outlook and to lessen some of the communications problems we will face
10

with our forward guidance.
Even after the asset purchase program has ended, monetary policy will still be highly
accommodative. As the expansion gains traction, the challenge will be to reduce
accommodation and to normalize policy in a way that ensures that inflation remains
close to our target, that the economy continues to grow, and that we avoid sowing the
seeds of another financial crisis. This means the Fed still has considerable work to do.

11