View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

EXIT

Shadow Open Market Committee
March 25, 2011
New York, New York

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

EXIT
Shadow Open Market Committee
March 25, 2011
New York, New York
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Introduction
It is a pleasure to be here today with my old colleagues and friends. I spent the better
part of 15 years as a member of the Shadow Open Market Committee and served as its
co-chair with Anna Schwartz for part of that time. It was a valuable experience and I
learned a great deal from our discussions and debates concerning policy.
When I accepted the position with the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia in 2006,
some of my colleagues thought that I had gone over to the dark side. I preferred to
think of it as trying to help put the lessons of modern macroeconomics and monetary
theory to work in the making of policy. That has turned out to be easier said than done
for a number of reasons, not the least of which is the onset of the greatest financial
crisis since the Great Depression. Some might think, based on temporal ordering or a
test of Granger causality, that it was my arrival at the Fed that actually caused the crisis.
Yet, we should be cautious in drawing conclusions about causation from such evidence.
Personally, I prefer to think the crisis occurred despite my arrival at the Fed. But that is
a story for another day.
The financial crisis was, indeed, an extraordinary event, and the Federal Reserve’s
decisions to adopt nontraditional policies in an attempt to stabilize financial markets
and the real economy have taken it far from the traditional and well-understood
operating framework for conducting monetary policy. Our traditional instrument of
monetary policy – the federal funds rate – has been near zero for more than two years
and is controlled within a range but not precisely. The Fed’s balance sheet is nearly
three times as large as it was before the crisis, and it is heavily weighted toward longterm Treasuries and mortgage-related assets.

1

Although recent global events have created some uncertainties, the apparent
strengthening of the U.S. economy suggests it is prudent for policymakers to develop a
strategy for the normalization of monetary policy. Today I want to suggest such a
strategy. As always, and perhaps particularly so today, the views I express are my own
and do not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve System or my colleagues
on the Federal Open Market Committee.
Economic Outlook
Let me begin by noting that the economy has gained significant strength and
momentum since late last summer and seems to be on a much firmer foundation going
forward. Consumer spending continues to expand at a reasonably robust pace, and
business investment, particularly on equipment and software, continues to support
overall growth. Labor market conditions are improving. Firms are adding to their
payrolls, which will result in continued modest declines in the unemployment rate. The
residential and commercial real estate sectors remain weak but appear to have
stabilized. Nevertheless, I do not believe that weakness in these sectors will prevent a
broader economic recovery. Indeed, the nonresidential real estate sector is likely to
improve as the overall economy gains ground.
The tragic events in Japan and the potential for sharply higher oil prices given the
turmoil in the Middle East and North Africa pose some risk to our recovery. Yet, I
believe this risk is small and short term, assuming Japan is able to stabilize its nuclear
reactors and political unrest in the Middle East does not dramatically disrupt Saudi
Arabia, the region’s largest oil producer.
If this forecast is broadly accurate, then monetary policy will have to reverse course in
the not-too-distant future and begin to remove the massive amount of accommodation
it has supplied to the economy. Failure to do so in a timely manner could have serious
consequences for inflation and economic stability in the future. To avoid this outcome,
the Fed must confront at least two challenges. The first is selecting the appropriate
time to begin unwinding the accommodation. The second is how to use the available
tools to move monetary policy toward a more neutral stance over time. Policymakers
will have to consider other important and broader issues as well, including the scope of
central bank responsibilities, the appropriate demarcation between monetary and fiscal
policies, and the moral hazard implications of our nontraditional actions. But these are

2

not my topic for today, as I have spoken on these issues elsewhere. 1 Nor will I be
focusing on the choice of when to begin reversing course. That, too, is a difficult issue,
but not an unusual one.
My focus today will be on the design of an exit strategy. How do we execute an exit
from extraordinary accommodation and nontraditional policies and move toward a
more traditional operating framework for monetary policy?
The Monetary Policy Operating Framework After Exit
In designing an effective exit strategy, we must start by deciding what the operating
framework should look like at the end of the process. We must then articulate a
systematic approach that will get us to that framework in a reasonable time frame. The
approach must be easily communicated and thus transparent to the public and the
markets, so that they understand not just where we are headed but how we plan to get
there.
Of course, monetary policy actions should be dependent on economic conditions, that
is, state contingent, and the exit strategy should be as well. While there is very little
economic theory to guide systematic policymaking using nontraditional tools, we
nonetheless should not act with complete discretion. I have frequently advocated a
systematic approach to policy and our exit strategy should be no different.2 Such a
systematic approach reduces uncertainty by offering a degree of commitment by
policymakers to the exit strategy.
So where do we want to go? My preferred operating framework for conducting
monetary policy in the future has four elements.
First, monetary policy should operate using the federal funds rate as its policy
instrument. Because the Fed can now pay interest on reserves, monetary policy could
use the interest rate on reserves (IOR) as its instrument, establishing a floor for rates
and allow reserves to be supplied in an elastic manner.3 However, targeting the federal
funds rate is more familiar to both the markets and policymakers than is an
administered rate paid on reserves. To make the funds rate the primary policy
1

See Plosser (2011), (2010), (2009a), (2009b).
See Plosser (2008), (2009a), (2010).
3
It is possible to distinguish the interest rate paid on required reserves from the rate paid on excess
reserves, but we can ignore that complication for my purposes here.
2

3

instrument, the target federal funds rate would be set above the rate paid on reserves
and below the discount or primary credit rate that banks pay when they borrow from
the Fed. This operating framework is sometimes referred to as a corridor or channel
system and is used by a number of other central banks around the world.4 I have
argued elsewhere that our goal should be to operate with a corridor system instead of a
floor system, in part because it constrains the size of the balance sheet while the floor
system does not.5
The second element of the environment follows from the first. To ensure that the funds
rate constitutes a viable policy instrument and thus is above the interest rate on
reserves, the volume of reserves in the banking system must shrink to the point where
the demand for reserves is consistent with the targeted funds rate. This will require a
significant reduction in the size of the Fed’s balance sheet, with reserve balances falling
by $1.4 trillion to $1.5 trillion to about $50 billion.
The third characteristic of my preferred operating environment has to do with the
composition of the Fed’s assets and in particular the System Open Market Account, or
SOMA, portfolio. I believe this portfolio should consist predominantly of U.S. Treasury
securities concentrated in short-term issues, similar to its composition prior to the crisis.
At that time, about 90 percent of the SOMA assets were Treasuries, of which about 35
percent were Treasury bills. Currently, only about 60 percent of the portfolio is in
Treasuries, while around 40 percent is housing-related assets, such as mortgage-backed
securities (MBS). Moreover, Treasury bills are less than 2 percent of the Treasury
securities in the portfolio. Thus, the exit plan must contemplate a significant
restructuring of the balance sheet in terms of its composition and average maturity.
Fourth, my preferred operating environment would make explicit the Fed’s commitment
to a numerical inflation objective, a proposal I have made many times. 6 Numerical
inflation objectives are fairly common among major central banks around the world and
many academics and students of central banking regard adopting such an objective as

4

Other central banks implementing a corridor or channel system include the Bank of Canada, Bank of
England, Bank of Japan, European Central Bank, Norges Bank, Reserve Bank of Australia, Reserve Bank of
New Zealand, and the Swedish Riksbank. In the recent financial crisis, the ECB, Bank of Japan, Bank of
England, Bank of Canada, and Norges Bank have moved to floor systems due to the expansion of their
balance sheets. See Berentsen and Monnet (2008), Kahn (2010), and Antoine and Monnet (2011).
5
See Plosser (2010a).
6
See Plosser (2009a), (2009b), (2008).

4

best practice.7 I believe it is time for the Federal Reserve to adopt this best practice and
clearly announce a numerical inflation objective in support of our dual mandate. This
would be particularly valuable as we exit our accommodative stance. Since our large
balance sheet poses significant risks for inflation down the road, an explicit commitment
to a low and stable inflation rate would help reassure the public that we will exit in a
way that is consistent with that goal. This would also help keep expectations of inflation
well anchored.
To summarize, my preferred operating environment would re-establish the federal
funds rate as the primary instrument of monetary policy; shrink the balance sheet and
reserves to levels that make the federal funds rate an effective policy tool; and
restructure the balance sheet in terms of its composition and maturity structure.
Adopting an explicit inflation objective would contribute to the effectiveness of policy
and the policy framework and any plan for normalization.
A Proposed Exit Plan
Now that I have described where I think our policy framework should be, the next step
is to lay out an exit plan that takes us there. As I argued at the outset, it is important to
have a plan. The plan must be communicated to the public and markets in a way that
reduces uncertainty, and it should explain how decisions will depend on economic
conditions, just like other monetary policy decisions.
Economists have recognized that any exit plan will use several policy tools, including
raising interest rates and shrinking the balance sheet. Some would start with raising
interest rates; some would begin by shrinking the balance sheet; others would do both.
My proposed strategy involves raising rates and shrinking the balance sheet
concurrently and tying the pace of asset sales to the pace and size of interest rate
increases. 8
The first element of the plan to exit and normalize policy would be to move away from
the zero bound and stop the reinvesting program and allow securities to run off as they
mature. Thus, we would raise the interest paid on reserves from 25 basis points to 50
7

Inflation targets have been adopted by numerous economic regimes, including Australia, England, Brazil,
Canada, Chile, the Czech Republic, the European Central Bank, Hungary, Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Mexico,
New Zealand, Norway, the Philippines, Poland, South Africa, Sweden, and Thailand. See Dotsey (2006).
8
Taylor (2010) also suggests linking sales to interest rate decisions.

5

basis points and seek to achieve a funds rate of 50 basis points rather than the current
range of 0 to 25 basis points. 9 We would also announce that between each FOMC
meeting, in addition to allowing assets to run off as they mature or are prepaid, we
would sell an additional specified amount of assets. These “continuous sales,” plus the
natural run-off, imply that the balance sheet, and thus reserves, would gradually shrink
between each FOMC meeting on an ongoing basis.
The second element of the plan would be to announce that at each subsequent meeting
the FOMC will, as usual, evaluate incoming data to determine if the interest rate on
reserves and the funds rate should rise or not. Monetary policy should be conditional
on the state of the economy and the outlook. If the funds rate and interest on excess
reserves do not change, the balance sheet would continue to shrink slowly due to runoff and the continuous sales. On the other hand, if the FOMC decides to raise rates by
25 basis points, it would automatically trigger additional asset sales of a specified
amount during the intermeeting period. This approach makes the pace of asset sales
conditional on the state of the economy, just as the Fed’s interest rate decisions are. If
it were necessary to raise the interest rate target more, say, by 50 basis points, because
the economy was improving faster and inflation expectations were rising, then the pace
of conditional sales would also be doubled during the intermeeting period.10
The third element of the exit plan must address the composition of the Fed’s portfolio.
If we are to return to an all-Treasuries portfolio, then asset sales, particularly in the early
part of the program, must be concentrated in MBS.
Examples of the Exit Strategy
What are the consequences of this strategy? In order to make the proposal concrete,
first, let’s assume that excess reserves need to shrink by about $1.4 to $1.5 trillion in
order to permit the federal funds rate to be reliably above the interest rate paid on
reserves. Second, let’s assume that once asset purchases end and the practice of
reinvesting proceeds from maturing or prepaid assets stops, the balance sheet will begin
to contract by about $20 billion a month, or by about $30 billion between FOMC
meetings, which occur about every six weeks. This will vary somewhat over time and
This may be difficult to achieve in the short term due to technical challenges, but we would learn about
the challenges of hitting a target under a floor system.
10
This assumes a linear relationship between the size of the policy rate increase and the volume of sales.
We could consider a nonlinear relationship, whereby doubling the size of the rate increase would entail
less than a doubling in the volume of sales, but a drawback would be that we would not regain control
over the funds rate target as an independent policy instrument until interest rates were at a higher level.
9

6

with the level of interest rates, but that will make little difference in the overall thrust of
the plan. Third, let’s consider continuous sales of $20 billion in assets between each
FOMC meeting. This pace of continuous sales plus the natural run-off imply that the
balance sheet, and thus reserves, would shrink by about $50 billion between each FOMC
meeting on an ongoing basis.
To illustrate my proposed exit strategy, I want to consider two examples.11 In the first
example, assume after the initial rise to 50 basis points, the path of policy involved
raising the interest rate by 25 basis points at each of the next eight meetings over the
following year, and suppose the pace of conditional sales was $125 billion. That is, for
each 25 basis point increase in the funds rate, we would sell an additional $125 billion of
assets. I note that this pace of conditional sales, combined with the continuous sales
and run-off, is similar to the pace at which the Fed bought securities as the balance
sheet expanded.
Then the funds rate and the interest rate on reserves would rise to 2.5 percent and the
balance sheet would shrink by $1.45 trillion by the end of a year, or eight FOMC
meetings. Monetary policy would still be accommodative, but the operating framework
would be normalized. We would have shrunk the amount of excess reserves in the
banking system so that the funds rate could once again be the policy instrument and the
balance sheet would no longer be an issue for policy.
In the second example, let’s suppose we wanted to normalize policy in 18 months rather
than a year. That would mean normalizing over twelve FOMC meetings rather than
eight. This would require conditional sales of only $67 billion between meetings, but it
would also mean that the funds rate would become a viable instrument at 3.5 percent
rather than 2.5 percent.12 These two examples illustrate how the pace of sales and the
time it takes to normalize policy involve trade-offs that must be faced.
Discussion
I recognize that any strategy has its disadvantages and this one, no doubt, will attract its
share of critics. Some will say that we cannot shrink the balance sheet this rapidly
without disrupting markets. Yet the pace of sales in the first example is likely to be no
more rapid than the pace of asset purchases during the crisis, and in a growing

11
12

See the Table.
See the Table.

7

economy, the demand for duration and risk is likely to be increasing and this will
mitigate any potential for disruption.
Moreover, many advocates of the asset purchase programs have argued that these
programs mainly influenced long-term rates by changing the amount of these assets in
the hands of the public – the so-called stock effect – and not through the flow or pace of
purchases. This is why announcing the total amount of purchases up-front was an
important part of the asset purchase programs.
According to this stock view, once the markets understand that the FOMC has begun to
normalize policy and that the Fed is shrinking its portfolio and the volume of excess
reserves, then the stock effect will largely be incorporated into long rates and the pace
of sales will have only marginal effects. Thus, whether it is through expected higher
short-term rates or through the sale of longer-term securities, long rates will and should
rise during the tightening cycle.
My own view is that except for the period when markets were severely impaired, early
in the crisis, the asset purchase programs had, at best, marginal effects on asset returns
and economic activity. Given that market functioning has returned to normal, I believe
asset sales are unlikely to have a significant impact as market participants’ demand for
risk and duration rise.
Others have suggested that we simply rely on raising interest rates and allowing the
balance sheet to decline only slowly over time through the natural run-off of maturing
securities. In my view, this alternative has several drawbacks. No one knows how fast
the Fed might have to raise rates to restrain the huge volume of excess reserves from
flowing out of the banking system. Rates might have to rise very quickly and in larger
increments than otherwise to offset the accommodative impact of the large balance
sheet. This could prove quite disruptive, yet failing to do so could risk much higher
inflation levels. It also means that it would take about five years before the funds rate
would become a feasible operating instrument. This approach also fails to address the
problem of the composition of the balance sheet, since, at the end of the process, the
SOMA portfolio would still remain heavily invested in mortgage-backed securities.
Another drawback of this alternative is that while the Fed’s interest rate decisions
would be contingent on the state of the economy, decisions regarding the size and
composition of the balance sheet would not be.

8

Another, perhaps somewhat more appealing approach is to shrink the balance sheet
first through the sale of assets. This might be thought of as the LIFO model – last in first
out. The asset purchases came after the policy rate reached the effective zero bound,
so some argue that assets should be sold first before raising the policy rates from the
zero bound. I think this is a somewhat risky strategy, because if the pace of sales is not
sufficiently aggressive, the policy rate may fall far behind the curve to stave off higher
inflation.
For these reasons, the approach that I have outlined involves concurrent policy rate
increases and asset sales whose pace depends on the state of the economy. Of course,
as my examples illustrate, this approach can be modified by changing the numbers. You
could make the balance sheet shrink faster or slower and affect the timing of when
normalization is achieved, or you could increase the pace of continuous sales and make
the conditional sales smaller. But whatever pace we decide on, I believe it is important
that we articulate a systematic approach to normalizing monetary policy. We must have
a plan that we can communicate to the markets that indicates where we are headed
and how we anticipate getting there.
Closing Thoughts
In summary, I believe that my proposed exit strategy has several advantages. It can get
us back to a “normal” operating environment in a timely manner. It shrinks excess
reserves sufficiently in a timely manner after the process begins so that the federal
funds rate can once again be the primary policy instrument. It is a plan that can be
easily communicated in a way that the markets and the public can understand. By tying
sales to interest rate decisions, it allows the process for selling assets to be conditional
on economic outcomes in ways that are familiar to market participants. This should
provide a degree of comfort to the markets and reduce uncertainty about the path of
sales.
I believe that the challenges the FOMC faces as it exits from the period of extraordinary
accommodation and nontraditional policies can be reduced if we communicate a
systematic plan that describes where we are headed and how we will get there. Such a
plan would be strengthened if the FOMC adopted an explicit numerical objective for
inflation. Doing so will help ensure that inflation expectations remain well anchored,
thereby reducing the risks of undesirable inflation outcomes as we choreograph a
graceful exit.

9

References
Berentsen, Aleksander, and Cyril Monnet. “Monetary Policy in a Channel System,”
Journal of Monetary Economics (2008), 55(6), pp 1067-1080.
Dotsey, Michael. “A Review of Inflation Targeting in Developed Countries,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review (Third Quarter 2006).
Kahn, George A. “Monetary Policy Under a Corridor Operating Framework,” Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review (Fourth Quarter 2010).
Martin, Antoine, and Cyril Monnet. “Monetary Policy Implementation Frameworks: A
Comparative Analysis," Macroeconomic Dynamics, 15:S1 (forthcoming).
Plosser, Charles. “The Scope and Responsibilities of Monetary Policy,” speech at the GIC
2011 Global Conference Series: Monetary Policy and Central Banking in the Post-Crisis
Environment, The Central Bank of Chile, January 17, 2011.
Plosser, Charles. “Credible Commitments and Monetary Policy After the Crisis,” speech
to the Swiss National Bank Monetary Policy Conference, September 24, 2010.
Plosser, Charles. “Sound Monetary Policy for Good Times and Bad,” speech to Merk
Investments/Stanford SIEPR Panel, Stanford University, October 20, 2009b.
Plosser, Charles. “Ensuring Sound Monetary Policy in the Aftermath of Crisis,” speech to
the U.S. Monetary Policy Forum, University of Chicago Booth School of Business,
February 27, 2009c.
Plosser, Charles. “The Benefits of Systematic Monetary Policy,” speech to
The National Association for Business Economics, Washington Economic Policy
Conference, March 3, 2008.
Taylor, John. “An Exit Rule for Monetary Policy,” a paper originally prepared for the
House Committee on Financial Services hearings on “Unwinding Emergency Federal
Reserve Liquidity Programs and Implications for Economic Recovery,” February 10,
2010. (Also published as Discussion Paper 09-009 by the Stanford Institute for Economic
Policy Research and available at http://www-siepr.stanford.edu/repec/sip/09-009.pdf).

10

Table 1
Exit Strategy Example 1: Normalization in 12 Months
FOMC MEETING

Funds Rate/IOR
Change in
Funds Rate/IOR
Beginning of Period
Total Reserves ($ bil.)
Asset Run-off ($ bil.)
Continuing Asset
Sales ($ bil.)
Conditional Asset
Sales ($ bil.)

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

0.50

0.75

1.00

1.25

1.50

1.75

2.00

2.25

2.50

2.50

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0

$1,500

$1,450

$1,275

$1,100

$925

$750

$575

$400

$225

$50

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$0

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$0

$0

$125

$125

$125

$125

$125

$125

$125

$125

$0

Exit Strategy Example 2: Normalization in 18 Months
FOMC MEETING

Funds Rate/IOR
Change in
Funds Rate/IOR
Beginning of Period
Total Reserves ($ bil.)
Asset Run-off ($ bil.)
Continuing Asset Sales
($ bil.)
Conditional Asset Sales
($ bil.)

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

0.50

0.75

1.00

1.25

1.50

1.75

2.00

2.25

2.50

2.50

2.75

3.00

3.25

3.50

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0.25

0

$1,500

$1,450

$1,333

$1,216

$1,099

$982

$865

$748

$631

$514

$397

$280

$163

$46

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$30

$0

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$20

$0

$0

$67

$67

$67

$67

$67

$67

$67

$67

$67

$67

$67

$67

$0

11