View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The Economic Outlook and
Long-Term Growth

New Jersey Economic Leadership Forum
New Jersey Bankers Association
Somerset, NJ
January 11, 2013

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

The Economic Outlook and Long-Term Growth
New Jersey Economic Leadership Forum
New Jersey Bankers Association
January 11, 2013
Somerset, NJ
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Introduction
Good morning and thank you for inviting me to address the New Jersey Economic
Leadership Forum. Last year, my colleague Bill Dudley, president of the New York Fed,
addressed your group. As you may know, the northern part of New Jersey lies within
the New York Fed’s District, and the southern part lies within the Philadelphia Fed’s
District. I am sometimes asked why it was set up this way, with District boundaries that
don’t always follow state boundaries. The answer is I don’t know. But if the political
nature of decision-making in 1914 was anything like it is today, I am not sure any of us
would find the rationales offered at the time particularly enlightening.
Nevertheless, President Dudley and I each lead one of 12 Federal Reserve Banks across
our nation. Together with the Board of Governors in Washington, this decentralized
structure of the Federal Reserve System helps ensure that monetary policy decisions are
based on the full breadth of economic conditions across our diverse country.
The goals of monetary policy are set by Congress in the Federal Reserve Act, which
states that the Fed should conduct monetary policy to “promote effectively the goals of
maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.” I have
long believed that the most effective way monetary policy can contribute to maximum

1

employment and moderate long-term interest rates is by ensuring price stability over
the longer term. Price stability is also critical in promoting financial stability.
The Fed seeks to promote these objectives by influencing the cost and availability of
credit through its decisions about interest rates and the supply of money. These
decisions are the primary responsibility of the FOMC – the Federal Open Market
Committee – the group within the Fed charged with setting monetary policy.
By design, policy is set by 12 voting members on the FOMC — the seven members of the
Board of Governors in Washington always have a vote, as does the president of the New
York Fed. The remaining four votes come from among the other 11 Reserve Bank
presidents, who serve one-year terms on a rotating basis.
Whether or not we vote, all Reserve Bank presidents contribute to the discussion.
Though we may, at times, disagree on how to promote the best outcome, we share the
same goals and objectives prescribed by the Federal Reserve Act. This process ensures
that the Committee considers a wide range of independent assessments of the economy
and of the policy options available to pursue.
Before I continue, I must note today that my views are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Board or my colleagues on the FOMC.
Economic Outlook
Let me begin with an overview of the economy as we enter 2013. We are now in the
fourth year of an economic expansion that officially began in mid-2009. Yet economic
growth has come in fits and starts, taking two steps forward, only to then stall or take
one step back. The general path has continued to be forward, but we’ve made far
slower progress than anyone would like. A year ago, many economists were forecasting
that economic growth would be closer to 3 percent for 2012. Instead, when the yearend data are released later this month, we are likely to see that growth in 2012 was
near 2 percent.
2

I anticipate that the pace of growth will pick up somewhat, to about 3 percent in 2013
and 2014 – a pace that is slightly above trend. In December’s projections by FOMC
participants, the central tendency showed real GDP growth of 2.3 to 3 percent in 2013
and 3 to 3.5 percent in 2014. So my outlook places me at the high end of the central
tendency for 2013 and at the low end for 2014.
This level of growth should allow for continued improvements in labor market
conditions, including a gradual decline in the unemployment rate, similar to the
improvements we have seen over the past two years.
In the fourth quarter of 2010, the unemployment rate averaged 9.5 percent. By the
fourth quarter of 2011, the average rate had fallen to 8.7 percent. We now know that
the unemployment rate for the fourth quarter of 2012 came in at 7.8 percent. Thus,
over the last two years, we have seen unemployment fall by 1.7 percentage points. I
believe we will see the rate continue this downward trend at a similar pace, falling to
near 7 percent by the end of 2013.
Part of the challenge with this recovery has been the modest number of net jobs added
to the economy. In 2012, employment growth averaged 153,000 jobs per month, on
par with the average monthly gain in 2011. We are simply not adding jobs at a pace that
will rapidly reduce the unemployment rate.
The economy lost 8.8 million jobs from the peak of employment in January 2008 to the
employment trough in February 2010. We have regained just over half of these jobs.
Progress has been particularly challenging here in New Jersey. As of the latest
employment numbers from November, New Jersey had regained under a quarter of the
260,000 jobs lost in the recession. The state’s unemployment rate stood at 9.6 percent,
compared to 7.8 percent in Pennsylvania and 6.7 percent in Delaware, and the rate is
higher than its level at the start of last year.
Many people are understandably frustrated by the modest pace of the recovery,
especially when it is compared with the recovery from the 1981-82 recession, which was
3

also a severe downturn. In 1982, the unemployment rate peaked at 10.8 percent –
notably above the 10 percent peak of this recession. Yet by the end of 1985, three years
after the peak, the rate had fallen 3.8 percentage points, to 7 percent. In contrast,
today, about three years after the unemployment rate peaked in October 2009, the rate
has fallen only about 2.2 percentage points. But recessions are not all alike, and to
understand the dynamics of recovery, including why this one has been relatively
sluggish, we must understand the size and nature of the shocks that sent the economy
into recession in the first place.
We entered this recession over-invested in the housing and financial sectors. The
adjustment in the housing market as a result of this boom and bust has been painful for
the housing sector and the financial markets. Those sectors have shrunk as a share of
the economy, and labor and capital must be reallocated to other uses. Indeed, it would
not be particularly wise to seek to return those sectors to their pre-crisis highs, which
we learned the hard way were not sustainable. Moreover, the labor force needs to be
at least partially retooled to match the skills employers demand. Even within sectors
such as manufacturing, the skills of workers now being hired are different from those
who were let go. Employers are seeking generally higher skilled workers who are more
technology savvy, and thus better able to deliver the increases in efficiency that firms
have sought to achieve. This adjustment takes time. It is painful to be sure, but it will
lead to a healthier economy in the long run.
The housing collapse also significantly reduced consumer spending, which accounts for
about 70 percent of the nation’s GDP. The sharp decline in housing values destroyed a
lot of the equity that families had built up in their homes. Thus, a huge chunk of their
savings vanished. Many households had been counting on that equity to help send their
children to college or to help fund their retirement. With that wealth gone, it is only
natural, and rational, for consumers to want to rebuild savings. Consequently, private
savings rates have risen substantially and consumption by households has been
restrained.
4

I believe these adjustments are unlikely to be significantly accelerated through
traditional government policies that seek to stimulate aggregate demand. This is
especially true in the case of ever more aggressive monetary policy accommodation.
The conventional view is that by lowering interest rates, monetary policy lowers the
price of consuming today relative to consuming in the future, thereby encouraging
households to reduce savings and bring consumption forward. However, as I’ve noted,
in the current circumstances, consumers have strong incentives to save. They are trying
to restore the health of their balance sheets so they will be able to retire or put their
children through college. They are behaving wisely and in a perfectly rational and
prudent way in the face of the reduction in wealth. In fact, low interest rates and large
budget deficits can frustrate those efforts to save. For example, low interest rates
encourage households to save even more because the return on their savings is very
small. And large budget deficits suggest that they are likely to face higher taxes in the
future, which also encourages more saving. Thus, efforts to drive real rates more
negative or promises to keep rates low for a long time may have frustrated households’
efforts to rebuild their balance sheets without stimulating aggregate demand or
consumption. In my view, until household balance sheets are restored to a level that
consumers and households find comfortable, consumption will remain sluggish. This is
likely to take some time, and attempts to increase economic “stimulus” may not help
speed up the process and may actually prolong it.
Manufacturing activity has also shown sluggish growth. The Philadelphia Fed’s monthly
Business Outlook Survey of regional manufacturers has been a useful barometer of
national trends in manufacturing over many years. The survey’s general activity index
posted negative numbers over the summer, recovered briefly in September and
October, and then posted declines in November in the wake of Hurricane Sandy. In
December, the index returned to positive territory. The good news is that the survey’s
future activity index suggests that firms expect growth to continue over the first six
months of 2013. Yet that growth may be restrained compared to other recoveries.
5

Even though the balance sheets of most corporations are in pretty good shape, we
continue to hear of weak demand and a great deal of uncertainty. Domestic demand
has slowed as U.S. consumers save more, as I have just described. Yet, global demand
has also slowed, due in large part to the economic turmoil in Europe, which is hovering
near recession. This slowdown has restrained world trade. U.S. exports have slackened
and, with it, so has our manufacturing sector.
Uncertainty is the other factor restraining hiring and investment by businesses. The
fiscal issues in Europe remain unresolved. While leaders in Europe have, at least so far,
avoided the financial implosion that some have feared, they are far from resolving the
underlying fiscal issues they confront.
Of course, uncertainty is not limited to Europe. Many U.S. firms have taken a wait-andsee attitude with respect to hiring and investing as businesses and consumers wait to
see how our own fiscal problems will be resolved. How much will tax rates rise? How
much will government spending be cut? U.S. fiscal policy is clearly on an unsustainable
path that must be corrected. Yet, there remains significant uncertainty about the
choices that will be made. And that uncertainty has been a drag on near-term growth.
Although recent efforts by Congress have reduced some of the near-term uncertainty
over personal tax rates, the long-term fiscal issues have not been fully addressed.
However, we will have to wait and see if the somewhat greater clarity on near-term tax
rates reduces some of the drag on business spending going forward.
Here, too, in my view, monetary policy accommodation that lowers interest rates is
unlikely to stimulate firms to hire and invest until a significant amount of the
uncertainty has been resolved. Firms have the resources to invest and hire, but they are
uncertain as to how to put those resources to their highest valued use.
So to sum up, there are good reasons to expect that the recovery will continue but at a
moderate pace over the next couple of years.

6

Turning to inflation, it has been running near our longer-term goal of 2 percent.
Although the drought in the Midwest and higher gasoline prices during the summer
pushed inflation up slightly, these effects are waning. Thus, I do not see a risk of higher
inflation, or deflation, in the near term. Indeed, over the medium to longer term, I
expect inflation to be near our 2 percent target. But this expectation is based on my
assessment that the appropriate monetary policy is likely to tighten more quickly than
the Committee anticipated in its latest statement. Thus, I do see some risks to inflation
in the medium to longer run, given the current stance and anticipated path of monetary
policy.
Long-Term Growth Prospects
The shocks we have experienced are large and likely to impact the economy for some
time. During this period, the economy’s level of output has been significantly reduced,
and it is unlikely we will ever fully recoup those losses. This is a painful and disruptive
consequence of the imbalances and shocks that have hit the economy. But what are
the longer-term consequences of the Great Recession? Has the economy’s longer-term
trend rate of growth been permanently impaired? This is much harder to determine,
and the answer will depend, in part, on the economic policy choices we make.
A simple way to assess the long-term trend rate of growth is to think of it as the sum of
labor productivity growth, which is typically measured as the growth of real output per
worker or real output per hours worked, and labor force growth. If an economy is
averaging 1.5 percent labor productivity growth and labor force growth of 1 percent,
you can anticipate that its trend growth will be about 2.5 percent per year. Over the
long term, labor force growth is mostly a demographic phenomenon, although
economic policy can affect it as well. Japan is an interesting example, as its labor force
is declining at a pace of about 1 percent per year. This is due in part to an aging
population, low birth rates, and fairly stringent immigration policies. Thus, if Japan were
experiencing 1.5 percent productivity growth, its long-term trend growth rate would
only be 0.5 percent per year.
7

Over the long run, productivity growth is the primary determinant of rising living
standards, or per capita income. Over the shorter run, variation in labor force
participation rates and the share of income going to labor vs. capital are also factors.
But over the longer run, these latter factors tend to be more stable, leaving productivity
growth as the main determinant of per capita income growth. Without productivity
growth, economies would stagnate and living standards would fall as the population
increased. Thus, productivity growth is the essential ingredient for continued
improvements in economic prosperity.
Most economists view productivity growth as being determined over the long run by
education and the quality of the labor force, innovation, and enterprise. Of course,
many factors can influence these drivers. Various government policies can support
productivity growth; others can dampen it. In this sense, societies face trade-offs and
make choices. One way that I like to describe these choices is in a risk-reward
framework. Investors, for example, can choose strategies that are risky, with asset
prices or returns that can be quite volatile. Yet, the expected rewards for tolerating that
volatility are higher over the longer term than those from adopting the safe or risk-free
strategy.
A society can do the same thing. It can choose policies that potentially increase
productivity over the longer run, but those choices may result in more volatility in
economic outcomes over time or across citizens. Alternatively, a society can choose
policies that are safe and that reduce economic volatility, but such choices could
dampen expected growth.
So what effects will the Great Recession have on long-term economic growth or
productivity? I think our policy choices and how they affect incentives will matter.
Establishing training programs, investing in education, and adopting immigration
reforms can increase the quality of our work force and enhance future productivity
growth. But policies that reduce labor and capital mobility could harm longer-run
growth. Attempting to eliminate volatility by creating an expanded safety net, if you
8

will, for both individuals and institutions could stifle innovation and distort risk-taking.
This would likely be costly in terms of longer-run productivity growth. On the other
hand, adopting policies that enhance the opportunity for all citizens to reap the rewards
of their efforts could enhance productivity growth.
Of course, tax policies and spending priorities, as well as financial regulation and trade
policy, will also play a role. For example, most economists see our tax code as almost
byzantine, with its inefficient complexity, loopholes, and special interest provisions that
distort incentives and the allocation of resources. Simplifying and enhancing the
efficiency of our tax system by lowering tax rates, closing loopholes, and broadening the
base could enhance productivity growth. Tax and government spending policies that
put our fiscal affairs back on a sustainable path and increase incentives for private
capital investment, R&D, and education and training would be very beneficial as well.
Financial regulations that work to ensure that markets are transparent can improve
efficiency and enhance productivity. For example, investors are attracted to our
financial markets when they know that the rules provide a level playing field rather than
favoring one set of participants over another. Similarly, regulatory reforms that penalize
excessive risk-taking and create incentives for the appropriate level of risk-taking in our
financial markets could also improve longer-run growth prospects. But regulations and
supervisory steps that dramatically reduce the risks of failure by financial or industrial
firms are likely to reduce long-term growth. In my view, government regulation should
seek to enhance the effectiveness and incentives of market participants to discipline the
firm’s risk-taking – not try to totally supplant it. That is, regulations should work to
enhance market discipline. I would add that excessive compliance costs in either the tax
system or the regulatory system can be sources of inefficiency and reduce productivity.
Thus, the choices that we make in response to the Great Recession can be a major
factor in determining whether long-term productivity growth and the potential growth
rate of the U.S. economy declines or not. This is not meant to be a pessimistic story.
Indeed, I am generally an optimist and a strong believer in the resiliency of our market
9

economy. But we must choose wisely. Crises sometimes can lead to an over-reaction
by policymakers and the public; we must seek to achieve an appropriate balance.
Conclusion
In summary, the U.S. economy is continuing to grow at a moderate pace. I expect
annual growth of around 3 percent in 2013 and 2014.
Prospects for labor markets will continue to improve only gradually, but I believe we
may see rates near 7 percent by the end of this year. I believe inflation expectations will
be relatively stable and inflation will remain at moderate levels in the near term.
However, with the very accommodative stance of monetary policy in place for more
than four years now, we must guard against the medium- and longer-term risks of
inflation. How the economy and the standard of living of our citizens ultimately fare
over the longer run will be determined by the policy choices we make in the aftermath
of the Great Recession. Some of these policies could increase the quality of the
country’s labor force and make us more competitive; others, while they may reduce
volatility, might also reduce our long-term growth prospects. It behooves us to choose
wisely.

10