View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The Economic Outlook and Challenges for Policymakers
Birmingham Rotary Club
Birmingham, Alabama
February 6, 2008
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia
Introduction
It is indeed a pleasure to be back in Birmingham, my hometown. Not only have I had the
opportunity to visit with family and friends, but this trip has also given me the
opportunity to enjoy some warmer temperatures than I have been experiencing in
Philadelphia. From Philip Jackson’s introduction, you will note that my latest career
move has been in a southerly direction — moving away from the deep snows of
Rochester, New York, and into the more moderate coastal climate of Philadelphia. If that
doesn’t sound like much progress climate-wise, you don’t know Rochester.
Of course, friends and colleagues, not to mention family members, have questioned my
judgment regarding what represents a desirable climate since I moved to Chicago as a
graduate student nearly 40 years ago. And they developed even more serious doubts
when my wife and I moved from Palo Alto, California, to Rochester. But regardless of
where life and opportunities have taken me, Birmingham will always be my hometown
and I am delighted to be back.
I especially want to thank Philip Jackson for giving me the opportunity to be here with
you today. Those of you who know Philip understand he is no stranger to the Federal
Reserve, having served on the Board of Governors from 1975-78 under Chairman Arthur
Burns. And he is certainly no stranger to some of what I’ll be discussing with you today.
Thank you, Philip, for the invitation to return to Birmingham and for the opportunity to
speak to the Rotary Club.
Birmingham and the surrounding region have changed quite a bit since I left to go to
college over four decades ago. The UAB Medical Center was only a vision of what
might be. The industrial base was weak and in decline, and many of us were envious of
the more rapidly growing metro areas in other parts of the country. Since then
Birmingham has undergone a resurgence. Its economic base has broadened and
diversified. As a result, it has grown and prospered. I have little doubt there are many
people throughout the country who now envy the quality of life Birmingham has to offer.
My own sojourns over the last four decades have taken me from Birmingham, to
Chicago, to New York City, Palo Alto, Rochester, and now Philadelphia. Most of my

career has been spent as an academic economist, doing research and teaching in the areas
of macroeconomics, monetary theory, and finance.
After studying and conducting research on the macroeconomy and monetary policy for
about 30 years, I am indeed fortunate to have the privilege of serving as the president and
CEO of one of the 12 Reserve Banks in the Federal Reserve System. It is a great
experience. The Philadelphia Reserve Bank has about 1100 employees, and like our
sister Bank in Atlanta, it has three major responsibilities. One of those is the supervision
and regulation of banks and bank holding companies. Another is helping to ensure the
smooth operation of the nation’s payment systems — basically by providing financial
services to banks and the U.S. Treasury.
The Reserve Banks’ third major responsibility is monetary policy. This responsibility
has two dimensions. First, each Reserve Bank’s board of directors regularly makes
recommendations about its discount rate — that is, the interest rate at which the Reserve
Bank lends to banks and other depository institutions. Such recommendations are
ultimately approved or denied by the System’s Board of Governors in Washington, D.C.,
but each Reserve Bank has an opportunity to provide its region’s input on those decisions
as part of the process.
The second way in which a Reserve Bank contributes to monetary policy is through its
president’s role as a member of the System’s Federal Open Market Committee — or
FOMC, as it is usually called. It is the body within the Fed that makes monetary policy
for the nation. Congress established the Federal Reserve as a decentralized central bank.
Giving each Reserve Bank a seat at the FOMC table is another way for the Reserve Bank
to convey its region’s perspective on both local and national economic and financial
developments. The Bank presidents also bring an important diversity of views to the
table. The Committee’s ability to make thoughtful and sound policy choices is greatly
strengthened by the interaction of members with different perspectives. I am fond of
recounting the words of that famous writer and journalist Walter Lippman, who once
said, “Where all men think alike, no one thinks very much.” I believe the give and take at
FOMC meetings reflects the fact that a lot of thinking goes into the decisions the
Committee makes. If we all agreed all the time, there would be little reason for the
Committee to meet.
For someone who has been a student of monetary policy for many years, serving on the
FOMC is simply a great opportunity. Sometimes I am asked if my views regarding
policy have changed now that I am an insider, so to speak, rather than the outsider
looking in. The answer is that sound economic analysis is independent of where you sit,
so that my fundamental views have not changed. That does not mean that applying or
implementing sound policy is necessarily easy. Indeed, when I took the position in
August 2006, little did I know how challenging the FOMC’s job would be during 2007
and 2008.

The FOMC and Monetary Policy Objectives
In conducting monetary policy, the FOMC seeks to foster financial conditions, including
growth of money and credit and a level of short-term interest rates, consistent with
achieving two goals: price stability and maximum sustainable economic growth. I
believe that the most important contribution the Fed can make to sustained economic
growth and employment rests on credibly committing to and achieving long-run price
stability. In fact, without a credible commitment to maintaining price stability, the Fed’s
ability to promote sustainable growth would be seriously undermined. Moreover, price
stability is not only an important element in achieving sustained economic growth, it is
also critical in promoting financial stability.
The primary tool for implementing monetary policy is the federal funds rate, which is the
interest rate at which banks trade overnight funds. The FOMC controls the funds rate by
buying and selling government securities in what is known as open market operations.
The FOMC meets approximately every six weeks, but, of course, can meet more often as
necessitated by economic developments, as we did in January. The Committee’s
objective at each meeting is to set an appropriate target level for the fed funds rate that
supports its longer-term goals.
It is important to recognize that the influence of changes in the FOMC’s targeted funds
rate on inflation and economic growth occurs with a lag, so by necessity the FOMC must
be forward-looking in setting an appropriate funds rate target. It must forecast future
economic growth and inflation based on available economic data and financial
conditions, including a particular path for the fed funds rate.
But paraphrasing physicist Nils Bohr, forecasting is a tricky exercise — especially if it’s
about the future. Thus we must recognize that circumstances change and sometimes they
can change very quickly. As new economic data become available, the Committee must
consider the data carefully and assess how they impact our forecast of future economic
outcomes. When the outlook for output and inflation does change appreciably, the
Committee may choose to adjust its fed funds rate target to achieve its longer-term goals.
Since last August, economic data have been particularly volatile, making the assessment
of the outlook unusually difficult and subject to revision. A change in the economic
outlook is what was at work in the last two weeks when the FOMC decided to reduce its
target fed funds rate in two steps to its current level of 3 percent.
Let me elaborate on recent economic and financial conditions and my current outlook for
the economy and inflation.

The Outlook
Since last August, financial and economic conditions have deteriorated. As that
occurred, policymakers revised downward their forecasts for 2008 economic growth.

This took place in several steps as new data were released and, in turn, led the FOMC to
lower the federal funds rate in a series of steps.
By last September, we had already seen a cumulative deterioration in the housing sector
during the earlier part of 2007. In addition, the disruptions in financial markets in August
caused by the problems in the subprime mortgage market raised the risk of potential
adverse effects on the broader economy from a further tightening of credit conditions. As
a result, I lowered my projection of economic growth for the fourth quarter of 2007 and
the first half of 2008. In particular, the adjustment to my forecast involved pushing back
the turnaround in residential construction, as low demand for homes meant it would take
longer than expected for the economy to work off the inventories of new and existing
homes for sale. The continuing high prices of oil and other commodities also suggested
the potential for some slowing in the pace of economic activity, as well as hinting at
increasing inflationary pressures — a point I will return to later. As the outlook changed,
the FOMC lowered the fed funds rate target by 50 basis points in September, and then by
another 25 basis points in both October and early December.
Since the Committee’s meeting in early December, the economic data have indicated that
the deterioration in the housing market has continued unabated. Although that by itself
was discouraging, other economic indicators also showed signs of an economy that was
weakening. The renewed widening of some credit spreads in financial markets, along
with weaker figures for retail sales, manufacturing activity, and job growth in December,
led many forecasters in early January to further mark down their forecasts for 2008. The
sharp rise in December’s unemployment rate, which was released in early January, also
heightened many economists’ concerns about the economy’s health. What’s more, the
Philadelphia Reserve Bank’s closely watched manufacturing survey recorded a
surprisingly steep decline in industrial activity in January, to a level not seen since the
last recession.
Although the economy’s resilience to past shocks makes me cautious about making
changes to my outlook based on just one or two pieces of economic news, the string of
weaker than anticipated numbers released in late December and in January had a
cumulative effect on my own assessment of the 2008 outlook. While I would not be very
surprised if the economy bounces back more quickly than many forecasters are now
projecting, I am now, nevertheless, anticipating a weaker first half of 2008 than I did in
October. This downward revision to the economic outlook is what led me to conclude
that a substantially lower level of interest rates was needed to support the process of
returning the economy to its trend rate of growth. Consequently, I believe the recent
reductions in the federal funds rate were a necessary and appropriate recognition of this
changed outlook.
The ongoing housing correction and the volatility and uncertainty in the credit markets
are significant near-term drags on the economy and I expect growth in the first half of the
year to be quite weak, around 1 percent. As conditions in the housing and financial
markets begin to stabilize, I expect growth to improve in the second half of the year and

to move back to trend, which I estimate is around 2.7 percent, in 2009. Overall, I am
now anticipating economic growth in 2008 of near 2 percent.
Given the slowdown in economic growth this year, payroll employment will rise more
slowly than last year and will remain below trend for much of the year before picking up
in 2009. Slower job growth will also lead to an unemployment rate near 5-1/4 percent in
2008, after fluctuating between 4-1/2 and 5 percent in 2007.
Two adjustments will continue to be needed to help work down the large number of
unsold homes: further cuts in construction and declines in housing prices. I expect the
decline in housing starts will bottom out in the middle of this year, but starts are likely to
then be quite flat through the end of 2009 as the inventory of unsold homes is reduced
gradually.
Of course, as was the case in 2007, how quickly housing bottoms out remains one of the
main uncertainties surrounding any forecast in today’s environment. It seems that ever
since last spring, the turnaround in housing was always six months away. Well, nine
months later, it is still six months away. Simply having housing stop contracting will
help economic growth. In 2007 the decline in residential construction took 1 percentage
point off real GDP growth, which turned out to be 2.5 percent for the year (4th quarter to
4th quarter). Once residential construction stops declining, it will cease subtracting from
overall growth. But housing is unlikely to make a positive contribution to economic
growth until 2009.
Business investment should continue to increase this year, but at a slower pace than in
2007. Outside of autos and housing, there isn’t a large inventory overhang in the
economy to be worked off. This is actually good news. Recessions are often preceded
by periods of large inventory accumulation and much of the decline in production during
recessions reflects a working off of an inventory imbalance. The absence of such an
inventory overhang is encouraging.
The biggest component of GDP is consumer spending. With slower growth of
employment and personal income in the first half of 2008, and as the decline in the value
of homes and equities diminishes households’ net worth, consumer spending is likely to
grow more slowly before picking up again in 2009.
One piece of good news has been the growth in exports. The trade sector supported
economic growth last year as domestic demand weakened in the U.S. while foreign
growth remained strong. The declining dollar also helped fuel a rebound in our exports.
The net export component of GDP should continue to improve this year, although more
slowly than it did in 2007 because we are likely to see somewhat slower growth among
our major trading partners this year.

Inflation

Let me now turn to the outlook for inflation. Unfortunately, I expect little progress to be
made in reducing core inflation this year or next, and I am skeptical that slower economic
growth will help. All you have to do is recall the 1970s when we experienced both high
unemployment and high inflation to appreciate that slow economic growth and lower
inflation do not necessarily go hand in hand. I anticipate that core inflation (which
excludes the prices of food and energy) is likely to remain in the 2 to 2-1/2 percent range
in 2008, which is above the range I consider to be consistent with price stability. If oil
prices stabilize near their current levels, I expect headline, or total, inflation to decrease
to around the 2 to 2-1/2 percent range in 2008.
While the Fed’s goal is to achieve stable prices for all goods and services, economists and
policymakers sometimes focus on core inflation, as it has been thought to give a better
indication of underlying inflation pressures since it excludes food and energy prices,
which can be quite volatile. The idea is that over time, core and headline inflation rates
should, on average, be similar, as increases in the volatile components are offset by later
decreases and vice versa. I am concerned, however, that over the past 10 years headline
inflation has exceeded core inflation by about 40 to 50 basis points. This has been true of
both the consumer price index (CPI) and the broader personal consumption expenditure
(PCE) price index. Indeed, headline inflation rates have exceeded core inflation rates in 8
of the last 10 years for both the CPI and the PCE price measures on an annual average
basis. While I would like to believe that, over time, these two rates should be converging
on average, I am concerned that the data are suggesting that core inflation rates may not
be as indicative of underlying or trend inflation as we might have thought. My
conclusion is that we need to look at both measures of inflation — headline and core —
since it is not clear which one is telling us the most about underlying inflationary
pressures. As a consequence, I was very much in favor of the FOMC’s beginning to
include forecasts of both core and headline inflation in our quarterly forecasts.
As the FOMC’s January 30 statement said, it will be necessary to continue to monitor
inflation developments carefully. Most measures of inflation, including the core CPI and
core PCE price measures, accelerated in the second half of 2007 compared to the first
half. With inflation creeping up, we have to be particularly alert for rising inflation
expectations. It is important that inflation expectations remain stable. If those
expectations become unhinged, they could rapidly fuel inflation. Moreover, as we
learned from the experience of the 1970s, once the public loses confidence in the Fed’s
commitment to price stability, it is very costly to the economy for the Fed to regain that
confidence. The painful period of the early 1980s was the price the economy paid to
restore the credibility of the Fed’s commitment — we certainly do not wish to go through
that process again.
Fortunately, so far inflation expectations have not changed very much. But they bear
watching because there are some signs that they, too, are edging higher. These may be
early warning signs of a weakening of our credibility, and we must be very careful to
avoid that.

Monetary Policy Going Forward
How do I think about monetary policy going forward? Recall that monetary policy works
with a lag. The full impact of changes in monetary policy on output and employment
may not materialize for several quarters at the earliest. Thus, actions taken today depend
in a critical way on how one sees the economy evolving over the next year or two. Put
another way, actions taken today will have little appreciable impact on the real economy
over the next couple of quarters.
As I have already emphasized, this lagged response means that monetary policy decisions
depend critically on the outlook for the economy over the intermediate term.
Forecasting, however, is a difficult task. Data are noisy and are often revised, which
means it is difficult, in real time, to extract clear signals about the economy from these
noisy data. In times of economic turbulence and uncertainty, the problem of extracting a
signal becomes especially acute. That does not mean that you can stop forecasting, but it
does mean that the uncertainty surrounding any forecast will be unusually large and may
be very sensitive to incoming data.
Over the course of the last five months, as forecasts for economic growth have been
revised downward, the FOMC has lowered the fed funds rate by 225 basis points — from
5.25 percent to 3 percent. Taking expected inflation into account, the level of the federal
funds rate in real terms — what economists call the real rate of interest — is now
approaching zero. That is clearly an accommodative level of real interest rates. The last
time the level of real interest rates was this low was in 2003-2004. But that was a
different time with a different concern — deflation — and we were intentionally seeking
to prevent prices from falling. Recently we have had reason to be worried about rising
inflation, not declining prices.
The FOMC’s reductions in the federal funds rate have been proactive in responding to
evolving economic conditions that led to the deterioration in the outlook for economic
growth. My inclination to alter monetary policy depends on whether the accumulation of
evidence based on the data between now and our next meeting causes me to revise my
forecast further. Weaker than expected data might lead to a downward revision, while
stronger than expected data may lead to an upward revision to the forecast.
To make this point concrete, last Friday the Bureau of Labor Statistics reported that the
economy lost 17,000 jobs in January. This was not an encouraging number. However, it
was consistent with my forecast of weak employment growth in the first quarter of this
year. Thus, by itself, it does not lead to a substantive revision to my forecast. We must
look at the accumulation of data from a variety of sources to assess how the outlook may
have changed relative to what was expected.
I also want to note that in early January there was much concern when the BLS reported
only 18,000 jobs were created in December. Yet in the employment report last Friday
that preliminary number was revised up to 82,000. Thus, we have to realize that

economic data are subject to revision, and we have to be very careful not to rely on any
one statistic or data series in assessing current economic conditions or our outlook.
There are those who have expressed the view that in times of economic weakness, the
Fed must not worry about inflation and should focus its entire effort on restoring
economic growth by dramatically driving interest rates down as far and as rapidly as
possible. To borrow a line attributed to that famous, or perhaps infamous, Union
Admiral David Farragut at the Battle of Mobile Bay, it is sort of a “damn the torpedoes,
full speed ahead” approach to policy. But the Fed has a dual mandate for a reason. Price
stability is a necessary component for achieving sustained economic growth. Ignoring
price stability during times of economic weakness risks undermining our ability to
achieve economic growth over the long run. It fuels higher inflation down the road and
risks inappropriate risk taking and recurring boom/bust cycles. This would be
counterproductive.
Although it might be tempting to think that monetary policy is the solution to most, if not
all, economic ills, this is not the case. I think it is particularly important, for example, to
recognize that monetary policy cannot solve all the problems the economy and financial
system now face. It cannot solve the bad debt problems in the mortgage market. It
cannot re-price the risks of securities backed by subprime loans. It cannot solve the
problems faced by those financial firms at risk of being given lower ratings by rating
agencies because some of their assets are now worth much less than previously thought.
The markets will have to solve these problems, as indeed they will. But it will take some
time. However, the Fed can and should help by offsetting some of the restraint created
by tightening credit conditions and the sharp reduction in housing investment. The Fed
can and should also promote the orderly functioning of financial markets.
Going forward, then, my approach to making monetary policy decisions will be to look at
incoming information and ask whether it is consistent with my outlook and the
achievement of the Fed’s dual mandate. My outlook for 2008 already incorporates the
fact that we will be receiving quite a few weak economic numbers in the first half of the
year. However, to the extent that economic conditions evolve differently than expected,
we will need to be prepared to incorporate those changing conditions into our policy
decisions in a manner that is consistent with our dual mandate.

Conclusion
In conclusion, my own forecast for economic activity has been revised downward since
last October as economic conditions have evolved. I believe the recent reductions in the
level of the federal funds rate target will be supportive of the economic adjustment
process and a return to trend growth near the end of this year and on into 2009. The Fed
has been aggressive in making this adjustment in rates, which will mitigate some, but not
all, of the problems the economy and financial markets are facing. Some problems will
simply take time for the financial markets to work out.

In taking aggressive action in supporting the economy’s eventual return to its trend
growth rate, I continue to believe we must not lose sight of the other part of the Fed’s
dual mandate – which is price stability. We cannot be confident that a slow-growing
economy in early 2008 will by itself reduce inflation. I am also convinced that we need
to keep our eye on both headline as well as core inflation in assessing how well we are
doing in achieving our goal of price stability.
Going forward, monetary policy decisions will depend on how the economy unfolds and
whether further changes in the economic outlook are necessary.
Again, let me thank Philip Jackson and the Rotary Club for inviting me to return to speak
here in Birmingham.