View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Convertible Securities and
Bankruptcy Reforms:
Addressing Too Big to Fail and Reducing
the Fragility of the Financial System
Conference on the Squam Lake Report: Fixing the Financial System
New York, NY
June 16, 2010

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

Convertible Securities and Bankruptcy Reforms:
Addressing Too Big to Fail and Reducing the Fragility of the Financial System
Conference on the Squam Lake Report:
Fixing the Financial System
New York, NY
June 16, 2010
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

If it is possible to find any positives to take away from the recent financial crisis, an
active dialogue between academics and policymakers about regulatory reform is one.
The Squam Lake Group includes some of the most distinguished financial economists,
and their thoughtful proposals have already had a significant and positive influence on
the course of the debate over regulatory reform.
I’d like to start with a quote from the Squam Lake Report.
“During the World Financial Crisis, several governments bailed out ailing
financial firms through fiscal transfers and other mechanisms because
they feared that these firms were too large or too systemic to fail without
catastrophic costs. Many of our recommendations are intended to
create a robust financial system in which any troubled financial company
is allowed to fail.” 1
I agree wholeheartedly. In my view, the most important element in fixing our financial
system is that we must end the notion that some financial firms are too big or too
interconnected to fail. If a firm’s creditors believe that the government will rescue them
in times of trouble, they will have little incentive to exert market discipline and
discourage a firm from taking excessive risk.

Squam Lake Group, The Squam Lake Report: Fixing the Financial System (Princeton: Princeton University
Press, 2010), p. 137.

1

1

Eliminating too big to fail should be the first priority of any regulatory reform. This is
easier said than done. As the crisis has taught us, when the systemic risks are perceived
to be large — and regulators are prone to see systemic risks under every rock — they
will be very reluctant to close down insolvent firms or impose losses on creditors. So
how do we reduce these risks so that regulators can credibly commit to a policy of
allowing financial companies to fail and not resort to rescues or bailouts?
Broadly, I want to discuss two complementary approaches to this problem. First, we
must seek ways to ensure that a financial firm that is susceptible to creditor runs has a
capital structure that reduces the likelihood of insolvency. The second is to ensure that
if such firms do become insolvent, there is a credible way to allow them to fail without
disrupting the entire financial system.
The first approach is to design capital structures with corrective mechanisms that kick in
when a financial firm displays signs of trouble, but when it still has positive economic
capital. This is the general philosophy behind prompt corrective action — the driving
principle behind the FDIC Improvement Act of 1991. Yet, prompt action need not come
only from regulators. The mechanisms could exploit market forces to address
developing problems without requiring regulatory interventions. In general, I interpret
“prompt corrective action” to include both regulatory-based and market-based actions.
While these mechanisms can help keep firms from slipping into insolvency, there will be
times when failure is the only option. Thus, the second approach is to design a
resolution mechanism that will close failing financial firms when early intervention has
not led to the firm’s recovery. I believe the best model for this mechanism should be
bankruptcy, which imposes an orderly resolution of counterparty claims according to
predetermined rules. In addition, certain forms of early intervention can help to lower
the costs of permitting firms to fail. For example, a regulatory requirement that
financial institutions develop living wills will help make it easier to unwind these firms in
an orderly fashion, consistent with their complex corporate structures, and at lower
costs. Furthermore, living wills can provide insight into the degree of systemic risk that
these firms impose.
I’ll go into more detail as I discuss the Squam Lake proposals. While I may focus
somewhat more on our disagreements ― nobody wants to hear how much we all agree
with each other ― I actually find much to agree with in this impressive document.

2

Indeed, my own views have evolved as I have discussed regulatory reform with various
members of the group.
Before I go on, I want to apologize to the NBA and the city of Los Angeles, and taking no
sides in this week’s championships, I will refer to the Squam Lake Group as the Lakers
for short.
Market-based Prompt Corrective Action and Hybrid Securities
Let me first talk about market-based mechanisms as a form of prompt corrective action.
I think that we have to acknowledge that heavy-handed regulation that focuses on what
activities institutions can and cannot do runs the risk of firms devising ways of getting
around the rules, forcing activities into the unregulated sector and creating risks
elsewhere. Regulators can also find themselves behind the curve as financial markets
evolve and innovation changes the way firms function. Discretionary supervision and
regulation alone are not sufficient to prevent excessive risk-taking or prevent future
crises. Thus, I think reform must seek ways to strengthen market discipline rather than
seeking to override or replace markets in controlling risk-taking.
One idea is for a firm to use reverse convertible securities that would function as debt in
normal times but would convert to equity in times of stress. We can place the various
proposals for these mandatory convertibles along a continuum. At one end, typified by
the work of Mark Flannery, reverse convertible securities are a mechanism for
addressing problems early on. 2 Conversions could be triggered by financial troubles at a
single firm and, thus, could occur relatively often. 3 At the other end, typified by the
Lakers’ proposal, reverse convertibles are a type of prepackaged recapitalization for a
banking system already in a crisis. Thus, from the Lakers’ perspective, convertibles are
not intended for prompt corrective action but as a way to avoid government bailouts
during a crisis, when firms might otherwise have trouble raising capital.
The Lakers propose that convertible debt convert to equity only if both the firm’s
financial condition deteriorates and the regulators declare that the whole banking
system is in crisis. The idea is to ensure that a single bank’s managers do not get a
reprieve from defaulting on the firm’s debt due to a financial setback. The Lakers worry
that managers will act inefficiently if they expect this reprieve, and so they want to
See Mark Flannery, “Market Value Triggers Will Work for Contingent Capital Instruments,” Working
Paper, November 2009.
3
In Flannery’s proposal, the trigger is the market price of equity.
2

3

retain a firm debt claim to enforce managerial discipline, except when regulators pull
this second trigger to declare systemic crisis. 4
I have three main concerns with this view.
First, as the Lakers understand, regulators will find it very hard to pull this second trigger
until very late in the game. The double trigger is designed to work only when financial
conditions have seriously deteriorated and regulators’ commitment to enforce
conversion is probably not much of an issue. Therefore, these securities would not help
provide any type of prompt corrective action to prevent problems. They function only
after the fact. I see this as limiting the potential usefulness of these securities.
I prefer reverse convertibles that can be triggered at an earlier stage, when market
participants may not agree that the system is in crisis. In fact, waiting for regulators to
declare a crisis before debt could convert would be a mistake, since regulators may be
too concerned that the announcement itself will worsen the crisis. Moreover, having
the securities convert earlier and imposing the cost of dilution increases incentives for
managers to avoid risky actions that might precipitate or encourage a market run or
systemic event. And while earlier conversion may lead to cases in which this event
occurs when the firm is healthy, this may not be such a big problem. The firm can
simply buy back the equity, if the market turns out to have taken an excessively
pessimistic view of the firm’s prospects.
My second concern with structuring reverse convertibles with a double trigger is that
anecdotal evidence from market participants suggests that doing so may limit the
demand for these securities. Securities analysts and investors will need to consider not
only the health of each bank, but also the health of the banking system as a whole, and
the prospects for regulators to intervene. This conditioning on discretionary behavior
by a regulator makes the security much harder to evaluate than a convertible security
with a single trigger based on the firm’s observable financial condition.
Finally, as a practical matter, I am not completely persuaded by the Lakers’ view that
convertible debt is not a hard enough claim to impose discipline on managers. All debt
disciplines managers to varying degrees. I doubt that managers will shirk their
responsibilities. After all, a forced recapitalization is not likely to be a happy event for
the firm’s managers or its shareholders.
See the article by Douglas Diamond and Raghuram Rajan, “Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation, and
Financial Fragility: A Theory of Banking,” Journal of Political Economy, 109:2 (April 2001), pp. 287-327.

4

4

Even if there is no second regulatory trigger, one needs to carefully consider the nature
of the first trigger, which is based on the financial condition of the firm. The Lakers
present a number of alternatives, without taking a final stand. It appears, however, that
their preferred choice of the trigger is based on the book value of the firm’s equity, in
particular, Tier 1 capital over risk-adjusted assets.
For two reasons, I tend to prefer something more along the lines of Flannery’s proposal
to trigger conversion when the market value of a firm’s equity falls below some
specified value. First, book values tend to lag economic realities, yet as I just argued,
there are benefits in having conversion occur at an early stage when the economic value
of capital is still significantly positive, as this will keep the firm bounded away from
insolvency. Second, relying on an equity price means that recapitalization becomes a
market-driven event that does not depend on the regulators’ evaluation of the firm’s
books. Book-value accounting is always a slippery matter; ultimately, a decision that the
firm is undercapitalized on a book-value basis depends on regulatory accounting
standards. Such a decision involves some discretion, since these standards are subject
to change by the regulators. This can undermine the regulators’ ability to commit to
intervening when troubles arise at a financial firm.
There may also be potential problems with the use of market triggers. Theoretical
research has shown that conversion schemes based on market prices of equity may
yield multiple equilibria or no equilibrium, unless the trigger is designed very carefully. 5
In practical terms, this theoretical work suggests that a firm’s stock price may behave in
perverse and unpredictable ways as we near the trigger. In addition, we need to worry
about incentives for investors ― for example, short sellers of the firms’ stock ― who
may seek to trigger conversion to profit from the discontinuous decline in the value of
the firm’s stock.
We can’t ignore these concerns. But the regulators’ ability to commit to their own form
of prompt corrective action is also a major concern and is likely to have consequences
for asset prices. I propose we give more thought to designing market-based schemes
that address the theoretical objections. For example, Flannery has recently proposed
that layered convertible instruments may help address the problem of discontinuous
changes in equity values at the trigger point. If the convertible securities have different
5

See Suresh Sunderesan and Zhenyu Wang, “Design of Contingent Capital with a Stock Price Trigger for
Mandatory Conversion,” Staff Report 448, Federal Reserve Bank of New York (May 2010), and Philip Bond,
Itay Goldstein, and Edward Prescott, “Market-Based Corrective Actions,” Review of Financial Studies, 23
(2010), pp. 781-820.

5

price triggers and, thus, convert at different points, equity capital could be gradually
increased.
Resolution and Bankruptcy
Of course, there will be times when all the efforts at prompt corrective action do not
succeed in preventing a failure. And if we are to deal effectively with the too-big-to-fail
problem, we must have a credible mechanism to deal with such failures.
I strongly agree with the Lakers’ two underlying principles for an expanded resolution
authority: First, an insolvent financial institution should be dismantled and its parts sold
off. Second, the resolution process should be as predictable as possible; regulatory
authorities should not be able to use discretion to alter contractual claims in the
resolution process. Notice, these principles sound a lot like a Chapter 7 bankruptcy.
While we agree on broad principles, the Lakers have not come to agreement about who
should implement the resolution process. I believe a bankruptcy court with special
procedures for financial institutions would be better equipped than a bank regulator to
credibly dismantle large financial institutions without bailouts. I do not view an initial
vetting by a panel of judges, as outlined in the Senate bill, as a substitute for a real
bankruptcy court proceeding.
Many details need to be worked out. In particular, the precise role of regulators in the
bankruptcy process is a matter that requires careful thought. In addition, international
coordination among nations with different bankruptcy regimes is an obstacle. One
possible solution is for global financial firms to declare a single jurisdiction under which
bankruptcy would be administered, but even this solution will require coordination.6
Contrary to some claims, however, we don’t really require a full harmonization of
bankruptcy regimes across nations. It is enough to seek agreement about the creation
of a special regime for financial firms. International firms do go through bankruptcy
now, so I don’t see this as an insurmountable task.
One of the greatest attractions of a bankruptcy court is the systematic and predictable
treatment of claims in bankruptcy — GM and Chrysler notwithstanding. We might still
worry that the failure of a large financial firm can lead to panicky behavior by claimants
that would simply overwhelm the bankruptcy process. However, I think prompt
6

See Peter J. Wallison, “Debtor Selection: Resolving Insolvent, Globally Active Financial Firms,” AEI
Outlook Series (March 2010).

6

corrective action and market responses should help mitigate this problem. A number of
suggestions by the Lakers are designed to enhance the predictability of the bankruptcy
process and, in turn, the credibility of closing down financial firms without a bailout.
The Lakers make a sensible proposal to reduce systemic risks in broker-dealer markets.
They propose placing higher capital requirements on brokerage accounts that permit
collateral to be reused by the broker-dealer and lower capital requirements on accounts
that fully segregate the customers’ collateral. If a customer’s collateral cannot be
reused, the customer will have less incentive to run and grab his or her collateral at the
first sign of financial troubles. The lower capital requirement could induce a substantial
portion of the market to migrate toward these fully segregated accounts, thereby
reducing systemic risks.
The Lakers also call for further study of the special treatment accorded to qualified
financial contracts, which include repos and derivatives contracts. Under current law,
these contracts are exempt from the automatic stay in a bankruptcy proceeding; that is,
counterparties can take immediate possession of their collateral when a financial firm
enters bankruptcy. Other claimants without this special treatment must wait until the
court has worked out a plan.
Arguably, this special treatment actually increased systemic risks during the recent
crisis. Sophisticated counterparties were encouraged to provide short-term repo
funding, collateralized by securities that turned out to be very illiquid, such as various
asset-backed securities. These creditors clearly perceived that they did not need to
carefully monitor their borrowers’ condition, in part, because they expected that they
could seize collateral before other claimants. In turn, this created incentives for the
borrowing firms to increase leverage, and increase their reliance on short-term funding,
which increased fragility in the financial system.
I am increasingly persuaded by the arguments of bankruptcy scholars like Tom Jackson
that we should limit the special treatment in bankruptcy to a much smaller group of
contracts, such as those repos secured by highly liquid collateral (cash or Treasuries). 7
For short-term funding secured by collateral with more uncertain value, sophisticated
counterparties should have the incentive to look more carefully at the borrower’s risk of
default. The consequence may be that short-term funding collateralized by securities
7

See Thomas H. Jackson, “Chapter 11F: A Proposal for the Use of Bankruptcy to Resolve Financial
Institutions,” Chapter 11 in Ending Government Bailouts as We Know Them, Kenneth E. Scott, George P.
Shultz, and John B. Taylor, eds. (Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, 2009).

7

other than cash or Treasuries might become more expensive and less pervasive. In turn,
our financial system might become a little less fragile. Not such a bad outcome.
The Lakers’ main proposal for lowering the costs of permitting financial firms to fail is
the living will. In their proposal, all systemically important firms would be required to
have a plan for their own bankruptcy as well as an estimate of how long this bankruptcy
would take. Higher capital requirements would be assessed for firms whose
bankruptcies would take longer.
It is difficult to argue with the idea of a living will. But, as the Lakers note, firms will not
have a strong incentive to cooperate without pressure from regulators. Planning for
bankruptcy is likely to be a highly adversarial process and very intrusive to bank
managers.
A better use of regulatory resources might be to view the living will as one of the tools
of prompt corrective action for firms that become undercapitalized but are still solvent.
For example, we might use the conversion of a firm’s convertible debt as the occasion
for requiring firms to begin serious planning for their ultimate bankruptcy. Once a firm
has been declared undercapitalized, the regulators’ bargaining power to insist on a
serious plan for bankruptcy will be greater. For these firms, I would argue that
regulators should also consider a more aggressive approach to press systemically
important organizations to simplify their internal structure. In this context, a joint
exercise in which the regulator and the financial firm prepare for bankruptcy would
certainly be a useful tool.
Conclusion
I have enjoyed this opportunity to think at some length about the work of the Squam
Lake Group. And I look forward to more discussion about these issues in the coming
months. While Congress is likely to pass a regulatory reform bill in the coming weeks,
this is certainly not the end of the process of regulatory reform. Regulators will need to
work out many details left open by the legislation. And taking the longer view, I don’t
think that Congress’s approach is necessarily the final word on designing a resolution
mechanism that will end the problem of firms that are too big to fail.

8