View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

A Longer-Term View of the
U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy

Charlotte Economics Club
Charlotte, NC
December 3, 2014

Charles I. Plosser
President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

The views expressed today are my own and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve System or the FOMC.

A Longer-Term View of the U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy
Charlotte Economics Club
Charlotte, NC
December 3, 2014
Charles I. Plosser
President and Chief Executive Officer
Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia

Highlights
•

President Charles Plosser gives his views on the U.S. economy and discusses why it is
important to take a longer-term view of economic data.

•

President Plosser shares some thoughts about the stance of monetary policy and the
advantages of raising rates gradually and starting sooner rather than being forced to
raise them abruptly later.

•

President Plosser also discusses how policy rules can offer useful guideposts for
policymakers and the public in assessing and communicating the stance of monetary
policy.

Introduction
Thank you for the invitation to be here today. The Charlotte Economics Club has
welcomed many leading Federal Reserve voices to this podium over the years, including
a number of my fellow Fed presidents. You have heard from President Jeff Lacker of the
Richmond Fed, which has its Charlotte Branch over on East Trade Street, as well as
Presidents Richard Fisher of Dallas and Dennis Lockhart of Atlanta. So I am pleased to
have been included among your distinguished guests.
On November 16, the Federal Reserve observed the 100th anniversary of the opening of
all 12 Federal Reserve Banks around the country on the same day. These institutions
along with the Board of Governors in Washington, D.C., comprise our nation’s
decentralized central bank. This decentralized structure is one of the System’s great
1

strengths. Not only does it promote a diversity of views, but it also helps to build public
trust and preserve independence. However, it requires that I begin by reminding you
that the views I express today are my own and do not necessarily reflect those of the
Federal Reserve System or my colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC).
Your program chair, Professor Rob Roy McGregor, has spent a great deal of his academic
career studying the workings of the FOMC — including the use of power by the Chair
and the nature of consensus building and dissent within the Committee. Interestingly,
some of this work has been coauthored with a former colleague of mine at the
Philadelphia Fed, Todd Vermilyea, who now works at the Board of Governors.
Today, I plan to talk about the importance of taking a longer-term view in setting
monetary policy. We live in a 24-hour news cycle that focuses a lot of time and energy
on analyzing the tea leaves from the daily onslaught of new economic data at our
disposal. Yet, I believe it is a mistake for policymakers to focus too intently on the most
recent numbers to justify a policy decision. Our data are always noisy and often subject
to substantial revision, as we just witnessed with last week’s GDP revisions and as we
see regularly with the monthly employment report. Instead, we must focus our
attention on the underlying trends and the likely path of the economy over the
intermediate to longer-term horizon.
One reason why policymakers must think long term is that the effects of monetary
policy actions on inflation and employment may not be felt for many quarters and
maybe years in the future. Thus, the near term path of the economy is unlikely to be
altered in any significant way by today’s policy choices. We must look further ahead in
assessing the appropriate stance of monetary policy. Of course, there is a great deal of
uncertainty about the future and that too has implications for how we should approach
policy.
2

I will begin with a brief overview of the economy as one policymaker sees it as we near
the end of 2014.
Economic Conditions
Over the past year, we have seen encouraging signs in the economy. The most recent
estimate of annualized real GDP growth in the third quarter was 3.9 percent, which
followed strong growth in the second quarter of 4.6 percent. Taking a longer view,
growth from the third quarter of last year to this year was 2.4 percent. But this includes
a negative 2.1 percent growth rate in the first quarter of 2014 that was a consequence
of a severe winter and was largely transitory in nature. We are seeing continued
strength in personal consumption, especially in durable goods, as well as business fixed
investment, which marked the strongest two quarter growth in investment by
businesses in nearly three years.
GDP growth has averaged 2.3 percent over the 21 quarters of the recovery since mid2009. That is a half point below the 5-year growth rates measured during most of the
2000s before the recession, which is, in part, why this recovery is often seen as being
moderate or modest from an historical perspective.
Nonetheless, we have seen a sustained improvement in the manufacturing sector. The
November reading from the Philadelphia Fed’s Manufacturing Business Outlook Survey
indicated very strong growth in manufacturing activity. Even more encouraging are the
sustained increases we have witnessed in this sector. After a mediocre performance
from mid-2011 to mid-2013, the index has now been positive for nearly 18 consecutive
months, with the only aberration in February 2014 during the depths of our severe
winter weather. Our index is often viewed as a useful indicator of national
manufacturing activity, and indeed the national ISM manufacturing index has also
shown solid performance over the past 18 months.
3

The labor market has also strengthened over the year. Employers added jobs at an
average rate of 229,000 per month in the first 10 months of the year, which is 18
percent higher than the rate in 2013, and it’s the highest we have seen at any point in
the recovery. This acceleration in job growth has helped bring the unemployment rate
down to 5.8 percent as of October, compared with 7.2 percent a year ago.
Over the course of this recovery, the unemployment rate has fallen from a peak of 10
percent in October 2009 to 5.8 percent today. Other measures of unemployment have
also declined. For example, the measure called U6, which includes marginally attached
workers and those working part time for economic reasons, has fallen from its peak of
17.2 percent to 11.5 percent.
Inflation, for the moment, remains well contained. The personal consumption
expenditures, or PCE, price index, the measure of inflation preferred by the FOMC,
registered a 1.4 percent increase over the 12 months through October. It is running
somewhat below the FOMC’s stated longer-term target of 2 percent, but it remains
above the level that should stoke concerns of sustained deflation.
Falling energy prices are generally good news for consumers and a favorable
development for the economy going forward. In the short term, the decline in the
relative price of energy will show up in lower headline inflation, but as energy prices
stabilize, headline inflation will increase. Policymakers tend to look through such
volatile and transitory price changes to assess the underlying trend in inflation. The
core PCE index, which excludes food and energy, is a bit higher than the overall
measure, increasing 1.6 percent over the 12 months through October. Other measures
of inflation, including those that attempt to reduce the weight given to large outliers in
any given month, all tend to suggest that inflation is running between 1.5 percent and 2
percent. Given the precision with which we can measure such things, I find this
4

outcome satisfactory. Nevertheless, I anticipate that the FOMC will conduct policy over
time in such a manner that inflation will gradually move toward the Fed’s 2 percent
target. Private sector forecasters seem to share this view as the Philadelphia Fed’s most
recent Survey of Professional Forecasters shows that long-term inflation expectations
remain stable at 2 percent.
Monetary Policy
In my discussion of the economy, I have emphasized the longer-run path of the recovery
rather than the month-to-month fluctuations. Viewed in this context, it is clear that the
economy has come a long way since the recovery began in June 2009. To me, that
means we should no longer be conducting monetary policy as if we were still in the
midst of a financial crisis or in the depths of a recession.
The financial crisis was an extraordinary event, and much of the commentary on
monetary policy has focused on the actions of central banks in response to the financial
crisis. That is appropriate and understandable. Yet, there is another lesson to be
learned from the past six years that I think is important to recognize. And that is how
difficult it is for monetary policy to fine-tune real growth in the economy. Despite the
FOMC’s stated desire and aggressive actions to accelerate the pace of the recovery,
growth has proceeded at a moderate pace since the end of the crisis. Monetary policy
has simply not proved to be the panacea that many had hoped. As I have argued on a
number of occasions, I believe we have come to expect too much from monetary policy.
We would be better served by greater humility and lowered expectations of the
potential for monetary policy to manage real economic growth and employment.
Ten years ago, I suspect most commentators would have told you that six years of a
near-zero federal funds rate target and more than $3.5 trillion of long-term asset
purchases by the Fed would likely produce an economic boom in the near term and
would risk inflation in the longer term. Well, although we have experienced modest
5

growth, we have not experienced a boom, and the jury remains out as to whether
inflation will materialize as a consequence. Some argue that the absence of the boom is
because the Fed didn’t do enough — more was needed to offset the constraint of the
zero lower bound on nominal interest rates. Of course, there is an alternative
hypothesis: Monetary policy was not capable of offsetting or mitigating the sorts of real
challenges the economy was facing. Distinguishing between these two hypotheses will
undoubtedly be the subject of intense research in the coming decades. After all,
economists are still studying the policy choices and their effects during the Great
Depression eight decades ago.
But let me turn our attention to how monetary policy should evolve going forward. I
began my remarks by noting that monetary policy should focus on the intermediate to
longer term and be less sensitive or reactive to short-run and transitory movements in
the data. To that end, I see the economy continuing to improve with real growth
averaging about 3 percent in 2015 before coming back down to its long-term trend
growth rate of about 2.4 percent. Employment will continue to expand, and inflation
will move closer to our 2 percent target. While people can disagree about the extent to
which the labor market has healed, it is clear that the labor market is in much better
shape than it was in 2009 when unemployment reached its peak of 10 percent. The
economy has come a long way, and monetary policy should reflect such progress.
This progress suggests that monetary policy should begin to normalize. Keeping the
funds rate target near zero when inflation is close to our goal and the economy is near
full employment is both unprecedented and risky in my view. Waiting too long to begin
the process of raising the policy rate risks facing the possibility that the rate may have to
increase rapidly when the time comes and that could prove unnecessarily disruptive.
And waiting could also risk a more rapid pickup in inflation.
Of course, policymakers face many uncertainties, and so they must be prepared to
6

adjust policy as the underlying trends in inflation and the real economy evolve. So, how
should a central bank best inform the public about those uncertainties and the
prospective path of policy?
The appropriate way to communicate the future of policy is to describe in a general way
a reaction function. That is to describe what key economic variables influence the
setting of policy and to give a sense of how policy will change in response to changes in
those variables. Over the past several years, I have criticized policy messages that
suggest that calendar time is a relevant metric for determining a policy action. We must
avoid such date-based forward guidance, whether it uses specific calendar dates or
more vague references alluding to a “considerable period” of time. As policymakers, we
do not know what the future holds, so forward guidance in this form cannot be very
credible.
Unfortunately, it is unlikely that policymakers will adopt a specific reaction function in
the near term. Yet, there are numerous examples of such systematic approaches or
reaction functions that can help us to gauge the stance of policy. Some of these
reaction functions have been shown to be robust in a variety of circumstances and
useful in describing past monetary policy behaviors. They can, I believe, provide useful
guidelines for assessing the stance and the likely path of monetary policy. They can also
be useful in communicating policy to the public. I frequently consider such reaction
functions as I think about policy. These are typically Taylor-like rules named for the
Stanford University economist John Taylor who first proposed them in the early 1990s.
These policy rules typically call for the targeted funds rate to respond to deviations of
inflation from some desired target and to deviations of output from some measure of
potential — sometimes referred to as economic “slack” or the “gap.” Sometimes such
gaps are translated into deviations from full employment.
These policy rules can offer useful guideposts for policymakers and the public in
7

assessing the stance of monetary policy, and communicating more about such
guideposts would enhance transparency and help make policy more systematic. Thus,
there is no need to mechanically follow any particular rule, and judgment will always be
required. Yet, policymakers and the public should be very cautious when they call for
policy rates to deviate in important or significant ways from these guideposts. Making
such judgments should require careful analysis, and the justification for deviating from
such guidelines should be clearly communicated to the markets and to the public.
A monetary policy strategy such as I have just described could be communicated
through a regular Monetary Policy Report, perhaps published quarterly. The report
would offer an opportunity to reinforce the underlying policy framework of the
Committee and how it relates to current and expected economic conditions.
Publishing a Monetary Policy Report with an assessment of the likely near-term path of
policy rates, in conjunction with its economic forecast, would also provide added
discipline for policymakers to stick to a systematic, rule-like approach. Communication
about that path, in turn, gives the public a much deeper understanding of the analytical
approach that guides monetary policy, thus making policy more transparent and
predictable.
In the current environment, an assessment of a variety of these robust rules suggests
that the funds rate target is no longer constrained by the zero lower bound. These rules
indicate that liftoff of the funds rate target from zero should have already occurred or
should occur in the very near future. It is important to point out that all of these rules
recognize and take into account the fact that the inflation rate remains somewhat
below the FOMC’s target of 2 percent. Nevertheless, they do not call for maintaining
the funds rate target near zero.
These rules are helpful because they not only suggest when liftoff should occur, but they
8

offer guidance about the future path of rate changes, given the likely direction of the
economy — that is, forecasts of inflation and employment “gaps.” Even more important
is that if the forecasts of the future change, these guideposts can highlight how the
entire policy path is likely to evolve. As such, they are capable of better aligning the
public’s expectations of policy with those of the FOMC, making the conduct of monetary
policy more accountable and more efficient.
Conclusion
In conclusion, the U.S. economy continues to recover at a moderate pace. Although we
have not witnessed the strong bounce back from the depths of the recession that some
anticipated, the recovery has been somewhat remarkable in the steadiness with which it
has progressed. Labor markets continue to heal, and their stronger-than-expected
recovery should serve to underpin continued economic expansion. Consumer balance
sheets are much improved, and individuals have regained significant fractions of the
wealth they lost during the crisis. That gives me additional confidence that the economy
is now operating fairly normally and that policy should reflect that normalization.
Policy can also be made more transparent and effective by specifying more completely
the variables that guide policy and the general way that one can expect policymakers to
react to those variables. To this end, I believe the FOMC should move forward to
describe in a qualitative way its reaction function and then communicate our actions
and decisions in terms of this reaction function. A detailed Monetary Policy Report
could be a useful vehicle for such enhanced communication by discussing a range of
robust policy rules. Placing policy choices in such a context will lead to a more
systematic approach to policy and one that is more transparent and predictable.

9