View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

F o f Release o n D e l i v e r y

(Approximately 6:00 p.m.
Central Daylight Time,
Thursday, September 20, 1962)

TWIN GOALS OF MONETARY POLICY
Remarks of C. Canby Balderston,
Vice Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,




Before the Twenty-Third Annual Conference
of the Public Expenditure Survey cf Wisconsin,
Milwaukee, Wisconsin.

x xN GOALS OF MONETARY POLICY
The Nation*s economic goals are to maximize employment opportunities
and living standards at home without sacrifice of the dollar's exchange value
abroad.

In human terms, our breadwinners of all ages and young folks who have

finished school need job opportunities; our family shoppers, widows and retired
folks need stable prices.

But these domestic objectives must be harmonized

with the international position of the dollar.

Otherwise our ability to com­

pete in the markets of the world and to sustain our position of world leadership
will be injured.

These national goals are also the broad goals of the Federal

Reserve System.
Much of the responsibility for achieving the national economic ob­
jectives rests with Congress.

Although it has ultimate responsibility to main­

tain the quality of our money, Congress has delegated the direct responsibility
to the Federal Reserve.

The fact that money, as a medium of exchange and a

standard of value, pervades all parts of the economy means that the quality of
the service it renders links the goals of Federal Reserve policy to those of
the Nation as a whole.
In particular the System keeps watch over the integrity of the
monetary unit to the end that it will be the servant of the people and not
their master.

It does this by regulating the volume of legal reserves made

available to the commercial banks, thus influencing the cost and availability
of bank credit and the amount of bank-deposit money in the hands of the public.
Thus monetary policy takes into account not only the level and trend of economic
activity, but also related questions, such as the degree of inflationary or
deflationary pressure, the presence or absence of speculative ebullience, and




- 2 -

through which the Fed operates, accounts for only a small proportion of the
Nation’
s total credit volume.

In 1959» for example, the total expansion in

credit amounted to $61 billion, but the banking system provided only $5.6
billion of this amount.
restrictive.

This was a year when monetary policy needed to be

In 1961, when monetary policy was easier, the banking system

provided $17.5 billion of a total $53 billion credit expansion.

These figures

serve not only to indicate the rough proportions of bank to total credit, but
also the changes that may occur in this proportion in response to changes in
monetary policy.
To recapitulate, the Nation has twin economic goals:
and international ones, but these are interrelated.

domestic ones

The Fed's job is to

influence bank credit, which is four-fifths of the money supply.

It does not

control the allocation of the money supply to particular industries, govern­
mental units and individuals.

That allocation is left to competitive bargain­

ing between lenders and borrowers and thus reflects the market forces of supply
and demand.
So much for the goals.

What of the performance? Without belittling

the magnificent physical basis for a good life that our economy provides for
a majority of our families, what with an auto for every 3 persons and abundant
telephones and televisions, the Nation's recent economic performance has been
sufficiently unsatisfactory as to prevent complacency.
Domestically, the economic growth rate has slackened; recoveries
from each of the last two recessions were less vigorous than from past ones.
As a result, unemployment has remained distressingly high— over 5 per cent of
the labor force— productive facilities have not been utilized fully, real
output has been lost forever, and the investment in new and better facilities
so important to future economic growth has been disappointing.




We are in the

- 3 difficult years between the restocking boom following the war and the maturing
of the bumper post-war baby crop.
Abroad, we are faced with increasingly vigorous competition from
industrial plants rebuilt after widespread, war-time destruction.

In many

lines, the new modern industrial facilities of such nations as Germany, France,
Italy and Japan are hard to beat.

Meanwhile, the cold war continues to call

for heavy expenditures to protect our national interests.

Although our country

exports substantially more goods and services than it imports, this favorable
balance of trade, though large, has fallen short of what is needed to pay for
our private investments, military expenditures and Government loans and grants
abroad.

The result has been a persistent deficit of $2-1/2 to over $3-1/2 bil­

lion annually in our international balance of payments.
The failure to earn enough foreign exchange to cover our foreign
investing, lending and spending has piled up short-term dollar claims in the
hands of foreigners.

These claims tend to come to rest in the central banks

of other industrialized countries as their nationals convert the dollarsthey
have obtained into their own currencies.

And when a given central bank has

all the dollars it wishes to hold, it uses the rest to buy gold from us.

The

resulting exodus has been at a rate fast enough to cause us to seek measures,
without resorting to restrictions upon the flow of trade and capital, that
will stop this pyramiding of liquid dollar claims against us.
This is not to say that as a nation we have fallen completely short
of our economic objectives.

Our GNP stands at an all-time high even though

the rate of economic growth has been less rapid than our productive and tech­
nological resources would permit.

Integrity of the dollar has been maintained

with commodity prices constant for about four years, and progress is being made
in redressing our balance of payments.




- 4These are fundamental explanations for the economic situation in
which we find ourselves.

The range of needed remedies seems wide and varied,

and involves a combination of wise and forward-looking public and private
planning.

But one central requirement for the solution of our economic prob­

lems— both domestic and international— is the restoration of greater vigor in the
conduct of our economic affairs.

And one important stimulant, in my opinion,

would be better profit potentials.

It is not enough to savej entrepreneurs

must be willing to venture as a result of their profit expectations.
Have such incentives really suffered in the post-war years?

This

is a difficult question, but I think that the affirmative can be argued.
Higher taxes, rising wage and operating costs, and the loss of buoyancy in
many markets certainly have made it more difficult to carry a satisfactory
margin down to profit.

Despite the many billions spent on new and improved

facilities and equipment, profits after taxes per dollar of sales of manufac­
turing companies have dwindled from 5.8 per cent in 1948 to 4.8 per cent in
1957 and 4.3 per cent in 1961— all years of mixed prosperity and recession.
This calculation excludes funds retained through depreciation charges, which
have been rising in relation to sales but which are needed in the long-run to
maintain our productive facilities.
What has happened is that in the post-war years, we have built a high
cost structure into our economy.

Wages and salaries, fringe benefits, taxes,

overhead— all have risen regularly from year to year, and in most cases have
exceeded the substantial gains in productivity that have been achieved.

In

the earlier post-war years, when markets were strong and competition moderate,
these higher costs could be passed on through higher prices.

But as the most

urgent market demands have been satisfied, and as competition has become more
severe at home and abroad, more and more cost advances have had to be absorbed.




- 5Cost-price controversy often centers upon the upward trend in wage
and related costs.
payrolls.

But certain other costs have risen even more rapidly than

Thus, according to a First National City Bank study, the proportion

of the sales dollar that the 100 largest manufacturing corporations paid out
for materials, payrolls and fringe benefits fell slightly between 1949 and
1961, from 82 to 80 per cent.

Surprisingly, the proportion of sales taken

by Federal income taxes also dropped a bit, from 4.2 to 3.8 per cent.

But

other tax payments, including State and local, rose from 2.2 to 4*6 per cent
while depreciation charges rose from 3»6 to 4*7 per cent of sales over the 12
year period.

It was these cost elements that cut after-tax earnings of the

100 firms from 7*6 to 6.0 per cent of sales between the roughly comparable
years of 1949 and 1961.
The rise in State and local taxes is reflected in the accompanying
charts that my colleagues at the Federal Reserve Board, J. Charles Partee and
Richard C. Pickering, have prepared.

Their analysis shows that State-local

activities, however measured, have grown more rapidly than the economy and
faster even than Federal programs.

On the first page of charts, the first

panel illustrates the steady growth in State-local purchases of goods and
services, both in absolute amount and in relation to the GNP.

The second

panel indicates the similar movement in tax and other receipts in comparison
with the national income.

Employment in State-local activities has mounted

with especial speed, as the third panel shows, so that in recent years the
number of State-local jobs has exceeded total Federal employment, including
the armed forces.

Indebtedness of the State and local governments also has

increased steadily, by $4-$5 billion annually in recent years, reflecting
mainly the heavy construction programs undertaken.

As a result, the fourth

panel shows that State-local debt has risen faster over the post-war period




- 6 than has total public and private debt, while Federal indebtedness in relation
to the total has declined markedly.
This expansion in State-local activity has been in response to very
real and urgent needs— the requirements of a rapidly growing population, a
rising standard of living, the post-war housing boom and the manifold demands
for government services that have followed.

Who would argue that there is no

need for the schools, roads, public buildings and other facilities represented
by these outlays?

It is true that operating costs and salaries have risen,

and debt servicing costs have ballooned, as shown by the charts on page 2»
These developments, however, reflect the rising standards of performance
demanded, the heavy needs for borrowed funds, and the inflation suffered by
the economy as a whole.
The point I wish to make is simply that increased services entail
increased costs, and that these costs must be borne by the public either
currently in the form of higher taxes, or over the longer-term, in the form
of a debt-servicing burden.

We are a wealthy economy, and can afford the

services that are really needed and useful, but we should be very sure to
get our money's worth.

Taxation, like direct wage and other production costs,

adds to the already high cost-structure of our productive machine.

And in

our present environment where increasing competition prevents upward price
adjustments, even marginal increases in costs, from whatever source, tend to
squeeze profit margins and injure investment incentives.

In our public affairs,

as in private industry, unnecessary frills and expenditures add to an already
inflated structure of costs and prices.

These must be held in check, and

opportunities for the profitable employment of men, money and machines enhanced
if we are to be successful in the competitive struggle for world markets.




-

7

-

The Vicious Spiral and the Job Killers
So far I have made the point that the goals of monetary policy are
interrelated and that the domestic ones cannot be separated from the inter­
national.

Even a small community ’
will not prosper if its people just take

in each other's washing*

it must have cash crops.

Fast moving trade is

therefore a prerequisite to main mum employment. What destroys trade among
ourselves and with others kills jobs.

There is no mystery to unemployment

that realistic thinking will not uncover.
Of what does the vicious spiral consist?

At the risk of over­

simplification, I shall list some considerations from which it springs.
(1)

Goods will not sell well at home or abroad unless they are

attractively designed and priced.
(2)

They will not be priced attractively if the costs of producing

and selling them are inflated by waste and inefficiency.
(3)

One source of waste is the misapplication of resources— human

and other— that happens when bad investments are made in the private sector
or useless expenditures in the public one.

The productive efficiency neces­

sary to keep costs competitive requires continued investment in improved plant
and equipment, but such investment calls for the willingness to venture funds
as well as their availability.

The willingness to venture is weak if profit

expectations in general have been diminished by a cost squeeze.

A cost squeeze

and -a drop in profit expectations is the classic way in which competition
eliminates weak finns and forces contraction in industries where product demand
is on the decline.

But when all business suffers a cost squeeze, there is no

place for savings to go, except perhaps to finance a Government-deficit or into
foreign investment.




- 8(4)

Taxes are rising more rapidly than the national income, par­

ticularly at the State and local levels.
cost structure.

This is one facet of our inflating

Taxes per se are not to be condemned but only that part of taxes

that results from unneeded projects, featherbedding and other wasteful expendi­
tures.

For instance, better schools make for a labor force that is more viable,

just as necessary roads help move materials and people to the places where
needed.

But featherbedding, whether in the public or private sector, makes

jobs for some people only by destroying job opportunities for others.

If

American products are priced out of world markets, or if consumption at home
is diminished by adverse consumer reaction, job opportunities are killed and
people go unemployed.

Trade is indeed a magic circle that has within it the

means of attaining our economic goals, including maximum employment.

But un­

controlled costs, whether governmental or private, are job killers.
The foregoing discussion of our economic goals— domestic and inter­
national— suggests that neither class can be isolated and dealt with separately
from the other.

In the framing of monetary policy, it is the optimum combina­

tion of the two sets of goals that should guide.

Success in their attainment

will depend upon appraising our strengths and weaknesses with realism and
courage, and then making those hard decisions that are needed for the long-run
health of the economy.







Charts to Accompany Remarks
on
TWIN GOALS OF MONETARY POLICY
by

C. Canby Balderston
Vice Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the Twenty-Third Annual Conference
of the
Public Expenditure Survey of Wisconsin
Milwaukee, Wisconsin
September 20, 1962

GOVERNMENT PURCHASES OF GOODS AND SERVICES
ANNUAL AMOUNTS
Bi l l i on s of d o l l a r s

PER C EN T OF
G RO SS N A TIO N A L

PRODUCT

20
15

10

Chart 3

GOVERNMENT EMPLOYMENT
NUMBER OF

EM PLOYEES




PER C EN T O F T O T A L

GOVERNMENT RECEIPTS
ANNUAL AMOUNTS

PER C E N T O F
N A T IO N A L INCO M E

Bi l l i o n s of d o l l a r s

Chart 4

GOVERNMENT DEBT
NET CH A N G E

PER C EN T OF T O T A L
PU BLIC A N D PRIVA TE
DEBT O U T S T A N D IN G

- ANNUAL

B i l l i o n s of d o l l a r s

STATE AND
LOCAL

15

4

10

LJ 1<\
17

ST ATE iAND LOCA

1

t

+
0

r#--- ■ /

\

\
\
\ »f
f

30

/
V
/
FEDE R AL

20
10

10

15

50
40

1
11
”#

" \\

1
1
1
1i

5

#
L i
1 \_ 1
L"""*
1
—
.
1

□

FEDERAL

60

1

_ _ L... .

1948 ’50

1
’52

’54




’56

1...

1

’58

’60

0
1946 1953 1961

Chart 5

STATE AND LOCAL EXPENDITURE, BY FUNCTION
ANNUAL AMOUNTS
B i l l i ons of d o l l a r s

1946

’50

’55

PERCENTAGE
D ISTR IBU TIO N S

’61

1946

'50

’55

'61

Chart 7

STATE AND LOCAL COSTS
Q u a r t e r l y i n d e x e s , 1 9 5 0 = 100

180

160

140

120

100
1950




1952

1954

1956

1958

1960

1962

Chart 6

STATE AND LOCAL EXPENDITURES FOR DEBT SERVICE
ANNUAL AMOUNTS
B i l l i o n s of d o l l a r s

PER C EN T O F R E V E N U E S
« O M OWN SOURCES

RE TIREM EN Ty
( )F DEIB T /

— S

/
^

I

IN TERES T

__ *
1

1952

i

'54

....

’56

i.

’58

i

’60

1952

Chart 8

BOND YIELDS
M ont hl y a v e r a g e s , per cent per annum




’54

’56

’58

’60

NOTES TO CHARTS
Government Purchases of Goods and Services
Calendar year data from
chases consist of compensation of
other purchases from business for
Gross National Product accounts.

U. S. Department of Commerce. Government pur­
employees, new construction expenditures and
general governmental purposes included in the
Excluded are purchases of government enterprises.

Grovernment Receipts
Calendar year data from U. S. Department of Commerce. Government receipts
consist of tax revenues, charges and fees for government products and services
(except those accounted for under government enterprises) and contributions for
social insurance. Federal grants to State and local governments are excluded from
State and local receipts to avoid duplication. Government receipts are shown as a
per cent of National Income, as customarily defined, plus indirect business tax and
nontax accruals.
Government Employment
Calendar year data from U. S. Department of Commerce. Number of employees,
both total and government, is in terms of full-time equivalent employment, which
measures man-years of full-time employment of wage and salary earners and its equiv­
alent in work performed by part-time workers. Total Federal employment includes
military as well as civilian employees; both Federal and State and local data
include employees of Government enterprises as well as general Government employees.
Government Debt
Data are from U. S. Department of Commerce and represent changes during,
or debt outstanding at the end of, calendar years except for State and local govern­
ments which are for fiscal years ending June 30. Total debt includes long- and
short-term corporate, noncorporate business and individual indebtedness as well as
government debt; both total and government debt is net of certain types of dupli­
cating debt.
State and Local Expenditures, by Function
Data are for fiscal years from U. S. Bureau of the Census. Expenditures
include general government expenditures for current operation, capital outlay,
assistance and subsidies, and interest; they exclude utility, liquor store and
insurance-trust expenditures and debt redemption. "Other”includes expenditures
for health, hospitals, natural resources, housing and community development, local
recreation, general control, interest on general debt and miscellaneous unallocable
expenditures.
State and Local Expenditures for Debt Service
Data are for fiscal years from U. S. Bureau of the Census. Expenditures
for interest and retirement of debt include those for utility debt as well as for
general government debt. Revenues from own sources include utility revenue as well
as that from general government taxesj charges and fees, but exclude revenue from
Federal grants and proceeds from new debt issued. Retirement of debt includes
long-term debt only.




- 2 -

State and Local Costs
Data are quarterly indexes; 1950 average equals 100. Average salary is
based on Department of Commerce monthly estimates of State and local government pay­
rolls and Bureau of Labor Statistics estimates of employment. Commercial and
manufacturing building costs are compiled monthly by E. H. Boeckh Associates, are
averages of indexes for 20 major pricing areas, and are used to represent probable
costs of constructing public buildings. Highway construction costs are based on
quarterly indexes compiled by the Bureau of Public Roads on the basis of average
unit prices for common excavation, portland cement concrete pavement, bituminous
concrete pavement, reinforcing steel, structural steel and structural concrete
with quantity weights.
Bond Yields
Data are monthly averages. For State and local bonds, yields are averages
of Thursday figures for five general obligations bonds of the highest quality with
average maturity of about 20 years. For corporate bonds, yields are average of
daily figures for about 30 industrial, railroad and utility bonds of the highest
quality with average maturity of 23-26 years. U. S. Government bonds yields are
averages of daily figures for all fully-taxable bonds maturing or first callable in
10 years or more. Corporate and State and local yields are compiled by Moody’
s
Investors Service.