View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
Approximately 12:00 noon CDT,
Friday, October 14* I960)




INVESTMENT OPPORTUNITY
Remarks of C, Canby Balderston,
Vice Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Before the Finance Section,

merican Life Convention,

Chicago, Illinois,
Friday, October 14, I960,

INVESTMENT OPPORTUNITY

In the fifteen years since the Second World War, the American
economy, despite minor setbacks and some speculative excesses, has per­
formed at high levels and has grown markedly.

The record gives us reason

to take satisfaction in our economic performance.

In contrast, fifteen

years after the conclusion of the First World War this country was in the
midst of a major economic upheaval that had gotten under way some time
before.
Many factors have contributed to the relatively well-sustained
growth in our economy during this decade and a half,
establishment has been created:
curement expenditureso

A large military

it entails high developmental and pro­

The so-called "built-in stabilizers" provided

by variation in income tax levies, unemployment compensation, and other
devices have been adopted.

In addition, the economy has been supported

by a high level of business investment in plant and equipment.
Saving continues to be necessary to support the world-wide
craving for capital investment.

And so at the 1957 meeting of the Na­

tional Association of Life Underwriters, I took occasion to pay tribute
to the skills of the insurance industry in merchandising saving and of
its success as a savings vehicle.

My suggestion then was that savings

programs must be fitted to new requirements by the use of creative imagi­
nation.
This paper is foe

in the other side of the coin:

Business

analysis of postwar trends




the

l i b r a r y

_ 2investment is related to our economic growth in two ways, The distinction
between them is one which is of central importance in understanding what
has happened to investment in recent years.

It is a distinction between

the process of investing on the one hand, and the results of investing on
the other.
The process of investing involves streams of orders and contracts,
production, borrowing, and spending; as a process, investing contributes to
the current demand for the nation's goods and services.

When investment

expenditures drop, the drop in demand has a depressing influence on the
economy.

When expenditures are high, as they have been on the whole during

the postwar years, the economy is stimulated.

It was this aspect of in­

vestment which preoccupied many students of the economy in the 1930's, when
the level of capital spending was very low.

At that time many of them viewed

investment solely as a short-run stimulus to total demand.
In doing so, they tended to overlook the fact that business in­
vestment adds to the nation’
s stock of structures and equipment.

Business

investment has increased the capital stock needed to maintain and expand
our industrial economy, and to make that capital stock responsive to im­
provements in technology and to shifts in the nature of final demands.
An expanding economy requires not only a widening stream of spending, but
also sufficient capital and other resources to translate spending into
goods and services rather than into bottlenecks and price increases.

This

aspect of investment has received much attention in the current discussion
of economic growth— so much, in fact, that there may be some danger of the
pendulum swinging too far away from attention to the maintenance of a smooth




-

investment process*

3

-

It is difficult, but necessary, to keep both aspects

of investment in mind— the capital needed for expansion, and the process
by which it is obtained,
We shall return to this distinction presently after an excursion
to present an observation of my colleague, Frank deLeeuw of the Board's
staff*

He has noted that the postwar course of fixed investment spending

and overall economic activity has had the relation depicted in Chart 1,
The solid line in the upper portion of the chart represents the total gross
national product and the dashed line represents business fixed investment.
The two lines are plotted on different scales, c?.rranged so that when they
coincide,fixed investment is equal to 10 per cent of gross national product.
The lines have in fact approximately coincided many times during the post­
war period, and so the chart makes it apparent that business fixed invest­
ment has fluctuated around 10 per cent of gross national product.
Cyclically, as the chart shows, fixed business investment he°
followed roughly the same alternations of boom and recession as total GNP,
but the amplitude of its swings has been greater.

When GNP has risen,

business investment has typically risen faster; when the former has fallen,
the latter has dropped off still more sharply.

Furthermore, business in­

vestment has tended to lag at the start of the postwar upswings, but once
turned upward, it has advanced rapidly.

In the last two years, although

the advance has not quite sufficed to bring business investment up to the
10 per cent level, the gap has narrowed.
One of the forces producing these magnified fluctuations in fixed
investment has been swings in the pressure of output against capacity.




We

- 4 do not have data to illustrate these swings for the economy as a whole,

we

do, however, have the information pictured in Chart 2 for seventeen industrial
materials.

The chart is based on physical output and capacity data available

for such materials as steel, cement, and petroleum.
The capacity line in Chart 2 appears to be quite smooth, and to
rise at an average rate of a little more th?n 4 per cent per year.

However,

the drop in output beginning in late 1953 was followed by a slowcown in the
capacity line in 1954 and 1955»

After the 1954-55 rise in output came a

pickup in the capacity line in 1956 that continued in 1957 and 1958.

And

the 1957-58 drop in output was followed by a perceptible slowdown in the
e:qpansion of capacity in 1959.

These fluctuations in the rate of increase of

capacity are shown more clearly in the bottom panel of the chart, inhere they
are depicted as year-to-year per cent changes.

The larger changes are more

than twice as great as the smaller ones.
Now it is these changes in capacity rather than the levels of
capacity that are related to net capital spending, or at least to a portion
of such spending.

Even though shifting pressures of output on capacity have

apparently tilted the capacity line up or down only slightly, these slight
alterations in slope represent quite large changes in the absolute amount of
capital spending.

Thus the postwar cycles in total output have been magnified

in capital spending.
If providing new capacity were the only function of investment,
however, investment would probably fluctuate even more than it actually does.

A relatively stabilizing influence is provided by one of its other functions:
the replacing and modernizing of the stock of capital.




As Chart 3 shows—

~ 5 -

though I should warn you that the underlying data are very rough— the replace­
ment of worn-out or obsolete plant and equipment and the intinduction of new
production processes are believed to have reflected changes in business condi­
tions, but generally their fluctuations have been less than those related to
the expansion of productive capacity.
In Chart 3 as well as in Chart 2, it is apparent that each of the
postwar cycles has had its own characteristics and that each has been distinc­
tive.

Chart 3 shows that during both the Korean expansion of 1950-53 and the

post-Korean expansion of 1955-57, outlays for expansion were for a time above
outlays for replacement and modernization.

During the expansion of 1959 and

I960, in contrast, outlays for expansion have remained well below those for
replacement and modernization.

The preceding chart, No. 2, also shows a

difference between the current expansion and those in 1951 and 1955-56.
Capacity has been more ample during the current cycle than during the two
earlier ones,

While the chart refers only to selected industrial materials,

other evidence indicates that similar, though less marked, widening of capacity
margins has characterized much of the rest of the economy.
It seems likely, therefore, that the trends in the two charts are
related.

More ample capacity currently than in the early 1950's has meant

devoting a smaller share of total outlays to expansion.

This decline in

expansion illustrates the two sides of investment referred to earlier.

Rapid

growth in output following the outbreak of the Korean War exerted pressure to
increase a capital stock that had proven insufficient.
ing the stock contributed to the general expansion.
stock

rose*

The process of increas­

Meanwhile, the capital

defense spending leveled off, and eventually the results of

the earlier investment relieved the pressure to increase capital outlays.




- 6The growth in replacement and modernization is not simply a result
of more ample capacity.

It also reflects the real increase in depreciation

and obsolescence, particularly the latter, which has accompanied the expansion
of our stock of capital*

One small but interesting example is afforded by

changes in truck registrations as portrayed in the fourth chart.

The number

in the five-year-and-under group reached its peak in 1952; since then there
has been a steady rise in the number in the older group until it now comprises
two-thirds of the total.
The present age distribution of trucks, it will be observed,
resembles the early postwar one.

In this respect, however, the chart is

probably not quite representative; on the whole, the emphasis on replacement
and the ease in capacity margins appear to be even greater now than in the
pre-Korean period.
At the same time, what information we have available as to output
and capacity during the 1920's suggests that capacity margins during that
period were not far from current margins.

In a classic 25-year-old study of

America1s Capacity to Produce, the Brookings Institution put manufacturing
cvutput at an average of about 80 per cent of full capacity in the prosperous
years 1925 to 1929.

The margin during the current year is generally put

slightly above this figure.
Turning now to the funds available for investment,

Chart 5 shows

that the flow of profits and depreciation allowances— that is, "internal”
funds— have provided no obstacle to spending during the early stages of our
cyclical expansions.

It is typically in the later stages of capital spending

booms that spending has overtaken internal funds, long-term corporate borrow­
ing demand has been high and— as the bottom panel of the chr rt shows— interest
rates on long-term bonds have tended to rise.




This chart also reveals the distinctive character of investment
during the Korean and early post-Korean years; it was during these years
that capital spending rose above internal funds for extended periods«

In

the first postwar expansion, capital spending and internal funds were
similar in amount, but since 1958, internal funds have been somewhat the
larger.
The term "internal funds" covers two broad sources of receipts:
depreciation allowances, and profits after taxes and dividends.

Between

these two sources there has been a dramatic shift during the postwar years,
which is depicted in Chart 6.

Depreciation allowances were smaller than

retained profits in each year from 1946 through 1951; by 1959? however,
they were more than twice as great.

This shift reflects changes in the

treatment of depreciation in our tax lav/s, as well as the great postwar
growth in the stock of capital that has been already mentioned.
Whether growth in depreciation contributes to stability is open
to question, since such growth might simply transfer to profits the un­
stable portion of corporate receipts»

The evidence of the chart, however,

is that the drop in internal funds in the 1958 recession was no more
steep than in earlier periods and was unusually brief.
There are other interesting and illuminating aspects to the
postwar investment boom presented in the last two of the charts, Nos. 7
and 8,

The first aspect relates to interest rates.

Over the last few

years bond rates have tended upward, although currently below the peak levels
reached at the beginning of I960»




Generally speaking, the stream of spending

~ 8 -

has been catching up with the high liquidity levels which existed at the end
of the Second world War and which have continued to grow since then«
sequently, interest rates have risen.

Con­

This deterrent to capital spending has

been somewhat offset by a decline, slightly reversed currently, in the average
dividends-price ratio on couimon stocks <> But of the two, bond issues have been
the more important as a source of corporate funds, and so the offset has
probably not been complete.
On the whole the average dividends-price ratio has not departed too
much from the average of the 1920's; but the bond rate in most of the postwar
period has been lower.
low point in 1928*

In fact, its early i960 peak just about touched the

Here, then, is another respect in which the present situa­

tion represents a change from the early 1950’
s and greater kinship with the
1920's.

Of course, the higher rates of taxation in recent years distort such

a long-term comparison.
Finally, consider the most imponderable of all the influences—
research and development activity.

Of the new products that have come of

age during the postwar years— electronic computers, television and other
communication equipment, new drugs and medicines, synthetic rubber, many
synthetic fibers and plastics, jet engines and other military equipment of
all kinds— it is astonishing how many of them sprouted during the Second
World War, It would seem that much postwar productivity growth has capital­
ized on war researchs
On the other hand, the eighth chart showing research and development
expenditures reflects how the amount of resources devoted to research has
increased every year.




The late Kenneth Mees, research director of Eastman

- 9 -

Kodak, concluded that technology has been accelerating at a rate that has
itself been accelerating.

Has this trend ceased for the moment, and are the

returns from product and process research diminishing?

Or in view of the lag

between initial breakthrough and mass production, is the stream of new products:
and methods likely to grow in the years ahead?
Inferences
Despite the gaps in our knowledge of the long-term influences on
business investment, we can nevertheless summarize our observations and
draw certain inferences that may help to give us our bearings.

During much

of the postwar period, especially the Korean and early post-Korean years,
the need for additional plant and equipment has been very high.

Compared to

the 1920's, margins of excess capacity have been smaller and interest rates
on long-term bonds lower.

I.'ith new processes and products adding to this

need for new capacity, there has been steady growth in fixed capital outlays.
In the last few years, capacity has become more ample in relation to output,
business demand

for external financing has receded, and at the same time

growing needs of other borrowers have caused bond rates to rise.

As a result,

there has been a decline in the growth of investment— either when compared
with its own earlier growth or with total gross national product (see Chart l).
In addition to these depressants, however, the present situation
is marked by certain positive features,.

A growing volume of investment

apparently is needed to offset the retirement of worn out and of obsolete
equipment.

Business depreciation allowances have reached high levels, and

they might possibly have a stablizing effect on investment expenditures.
Finally, national spending for research and development is at record levels,




- 10 -

and may be expected to promote new products and processes reouiring new types
of plant and equipment,
¡hat may one infer as to recent trends?

!.e are not, of course,

able to predict the future of investment vdth precision.

But some insight

into the over-all business investment situation may be gained from the dis­
tinction drawn at the beginning of this discussion— that between the process
of investing and its results,
l.ith respect to the process of investment in plant and equipment—
the flows of orders, production and shipments— we have seen in recent years
a leveling off.

Dampening influences that have slowed down investment have

lessened this stimulant to the growth of the economy.
On the other hand, with respect to the results of investment— the
adequacy of the nation's capital stock,— we are in a much better position
than we have been in any of the earlier postwar years.

The present position

bears some similarity to that of the 1920's, and we can achieve considerable
expansion without running into bottlenecks and price pressures related to
plant and equipment.
This combination of an ample stock of capital and a less buoyant
flow of new investment is the reverse of the situation typical of the post­
war period as a whole and especially of the early 1950's.

These trends may

again be reversed, as replacement and modernization outlays grow or as
expansion in other streams of spending gradually push output close to capacity
again.

As long as they last, however, current trends represent a change in

the character of investment that bears upon the economic outlook, inflation,
and economic growth.




- 11 -

Cne should not conclude from the foregoing observations that the
need for saving has in any way diminished.

Indeed, we will be unable to

achieve the economic growth to which we aspire unless we provide through
savings for enlarged productive facilities in the future.

To this end, care­

ful and alert guidance is needed to allocate the savings stream to the most
urgently needed capital developments.
There are many evidences of obsolete and worn out physical plant
all around us in this country.

Moreover, the pace of technological change has

never in all history been so rapid and this is providing fresh openings for
industrial capacity adapted to new processes and products.

Besides this, we

face the need to invest aggressively to keep competitive with the rest of the
world.

In underdeveloped countries, lastly, there is a desperate desire for

the fruits of industrialization to raise the standards of living by furnishing
water, schools^ and houses with better than earth flooring.
And so the struggle to save enough to undergird technological
advance goes on in all countries able to produce more than they consume.
But changes in the most effective use of saving must be taken into account
by all those responsible for investment policy.

These changes are sufficiently

acute to merit close analysis and the active search for promising opportu­
nities ,




B □ AR D

□ F

GOVERNORS

DF

THE

FEDERAL

R ES L k VE

SYSTEM

Chart 1

Chart 2

BUSINESS FIXED INVESTMENT

MAJOR MATERIALS

1946 1948 1950 1952 1954 1956 1958 1960

1950

1955

Chart 3

Chart 4

CAPITAL OUTLAYS - m a n u fa c t u r in g

TRUCK REGISTRATIONS




1950

1955

1960

1960

BOARD

OF

GOVERNORS

OF

Chart 5

FEDERAL

RESERVE

SYSTEM

Chart 6

CORPORATE
FINANCE
1

CORPORATE INTERNAL FUNDS

Billions of dollars, annual rates
Ratio scale
p,ant ani [quip|lie||j
1
Outlays / i
#

32
24

v->./ V

~f f ^ \

THE

16

Internal Funds

1

Ml
/i/1i
ii
f

r..

i i _i i

....

i l

1 1 i 1

i i

Chart 8

Chart 7

CORPORATE SECURITY YIELDS

RESEARCH and DEVELOPMENT
10

8

1000

400

200

1946

1948

1950




1952

1954

1956

1958

1960