View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
Approximately 7 s00 p*m,, EDT,
Thursday, October 23, 1958*)

CONSUMER CREDIT; A ROSE OR A THORN?
Address of C, Canby Balderston,
Vice Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,




at the New York State Bankers Association
Management Conference on Installment Credit,
Hotel Commodore, New York City,
October 23, 1958.

CONSUMER CREDIT: A ROSE OR A THORN?

In his essay on Compensation, Emerson observed that "Every sweet
hath its sour; every evil its good, . . . . For every benefit which you
receive, a tax is levied. . . . . Every thing has two sides, a good and an
evil."
The age-old problem of how to have roses without thorns is well
illustrated by consumer credit.

Consumer credit may properly be referred to

as a rose because of the role that it has played in advancing the scale of
living of citizens generally.

Doubtless technical advance would have per­

mitted Americans to achieve eventually the v/ide ownership of homes, autos,
bathtubs and television that they have now achieved.

But consumer credit

enabled them to get these things sooner than otherwise.

The saving process

is so slow for a young family with children that they prefer to go into debt
to own a home of their choice and to equip it rather than to wait indefinitely.
Even those who are critical of the gadgets that surround us must admit that
an astounding proportion of Americans now have the physical basis for a
pleasanter life.

And those who were skeptical of the consumers' ability to

handle debt must recognize that the record of financial responsibility has
been remarkably good.
Like most roses, consumer credit also has its thorns.

The reces­

sion from which we are emerging, in part a consumer-durable-goods recession,
reminds us of the influence of consumer credit in the consumer boom of 1955»
In that year the outstanding volume of instalment credit increased $5-1/2
billion or almost 25 per cent.

This increase was accompanied by a signifi­

cant easing in the terms on which consumer credit was extended, particularly




- 2credit to purchase new automobiles.

By mid-1955j 30-month instalment con­

tracts on new automobiles were typical as against 24 months the year before,
and contracts with 36-month maturities were becoming common.

At that time,

the down-payments standard of one-third of the transaction price was still
being adhered to, but over-allowances on trade-ins were lowering the effec­
tive down payment and the buyer's equity.

With this impetus, 7.4 million

new cars were sold in the domestic market, an increase of more than one-third
over 1954»

The same liberalization of terms was evident in the use of credit

to expand residential construction at an accelerated rate.

You will remember

that in 1955 new housing starts reached 1 million 329 thousand.
In the second half of that year the thorns began to appear in the
shape of increases in the prices of industrial products amounting to almost
4 per cent.
persons to

The chain of events that followed has caused many thoughtful
question whether the obvious gains from the use of consumer credit

are bought at too high a social cost if it accelerates an already booming
market for consumer durables.

You will recall that the consumer boom of

1955 was followed by an expansion of inventories in every consumer-durables
industry during 1956 even though the sale of automobiles declined sharply.
This industry, a mighty force in the economy, appeared to have over-extended
itself and to have slowed down for a while.

Automobile executives and workers

must have regretted that the 1955 market was over-sold by at least a million
cars.
This consumer boom was no small factor in inducing subsequent
management decisions that were not altogether prudent.

In 1956 businessmen

expanded their outlays for plant and equipment at a rate 22 per cent faster




- 3 -

than in the year before.

Thus a plant-expansion boom, triggered in part by

the consumer boom of 1955> drove the cost of building materials and labor
higher and higher.

This upward movement led some manufacturers to believe

that if they were going to need expanded capacity, they had better get it
promptly before costs rose still higher. As a result, many of them discounted
the growth in demand for their product for years ahead.

When the awakening

came during the last half of 1957* many industries became aware of excess
capacity.
Most tragic of all was the unemployment that resulted.

Having

obtained the consumer durables that they needed most, having automobiles that
were still good for thousands of miles, and becoming disenchanted with the
increased prices, consumers went on a buyers' holiday.

There developed an

over-supply of stoves, refrigerators, washing machines, radios and television
sets.

Production schedules were cut back and men were laid off.

struction boom also languished and here again men were laid off.

The con­
And so,

in 1957 and 1958* society paid in unemployment, lost salaries and lost profits
the price of another bust that followed in the wake of a boom which we must,
in all honesty, recognize was helped on its way by the excessively rapid
growth of consumer credit.
This poses the question as to whether it is socially desirable to
have selective control over consumer credit, in addition to general fiscal
and monetary control.

The decision must represent a value judgment based

upon a balancing of gains against disadvantages.

To diminish the unstabi-

lizing effects of consumer credit has strong appeal to those who feel that,
despite its benefits, excessive fluctuations in its use should be prevented




- 4 -

in order to minimize economic instability.

But if selective control is to

be employed, the disadvantages of such control need to be faced up to and
removed if possible.

In the use of margin requirements to prevent excessive

flow of credit into the stock market, supervision and enforcement are not
too difficult.

In three previous efforts to regulate consumer credit, how­

ever, the administrative difficulties were so great that the Federal ReseI’
ve
System, which had the task of enforcement and the 200,000 retailers and
financial institutions to whom the regulation applied breathed a sigh of
relief when the ordeal was over.
To gain a proper perspective of the role of selective controls,
one must compare them with general fiscal and monetary policy,

Fiscal policy

acts through governmental surpluses or deficits, which reflect both govern­
mental spending and taxing.
and the Treasury.

The direct responsibility rests upon the Congress

General monetary control, entrusted by the Congress to

the Federal Reserve Sj^stem, has the particular role of regulating the re­
serves available to the commercial banks so that bank credit may contract
and expand flexibly in accordance with the fluctuating needs of the economyc
The Federal Reserve has the task of controlling the supply of money and
credit in total, leaving its allocation to the competitive forces of the free
market.

Credit is allocated in the marketplace to those credit-worthy bor­

rowers vího are willing to pay the going price.

The apportionment among

individual borrowers is left to competition between private borrowers and
private lenders, even though the responsibility for influencing the total
supply of credit rests with the central bank.




- 5In contrast to this relatively impersonal allocation of the money
supply are so-called selective or direct controls.

Broadly speaking, they

embrace rationing, and price and wage controls, as well as regulation of spe­
cific uses of credit.

If any of these is used, government intervenes in the

operation of the free market.

Of course it also intervenes when it uses sub­

sidies, price supports, and guarantees to shelter particular groups of citi­
zens,

It is clear that even if these supplementary controls are helpful in

meeting emergencies, they are no substitute for general fiscal and monetary
controls.

Without the general controls, inflationary pressures will break

loose eventually,
Through the use of general credit measures, supplemented by stockmarket margin regulations, economic fluctuations have been greatly moderated
in the period since 1950* despite a sharp increase in both public and private
debt.

Since 1950 we have added t?20 billion to consumer instalment credit

outstanding, #90 billion to mortgage debt, and $85 billion to corporate debt—
in considerable part to finance additions to plant and equipment.

We have

also added to the Federal debt, largely as a result of the need to reorganize
and reequip the defense establishment in view of the rapid technical advances
which have taken place in a world of continuing international tensions.

At

the same time State and local governments have borrowed $30 billion to fi­
nance schools and highways and for other purposes.
When one contemplates these magnitudes and the rates of increase
they imply, both in credit and in our stock of real wealth— homes, automobiles,
factories, and public facilities— it seems almost a miracle that we have been
able to accomplish so much growth and still maintain as much stability as we
have had in prices and employment,




I am convinced that we could not have

- 6done even this well if we had not citing tenaciously to a sound, flexible
monetary policy*
Reliance on general credit measures alone, of course, has limita­
tions,

Despite the manifest necessity for a sound general credit policy, and

despite the manifest advantages of permitting the market to carry out the
function of credit allocation, conditions may at times develop in specific
areas that to some people would justify selective credit controls.

Develop­

ments in a particular area may be unsound in themselves; or the area may be
absorbing too much of the total credit expansion that is appropriate to the
situation*

Under such circumstances, public opinion may come to insist upon

selective controls to supplement general ones.
The Federal Reserve System made a study of the consumer-credit field
almost two years ago and concluded that selective controls of consumer credit
were not called for at that time.

It is possible, however, that developments

in the future might call for a reconsideration of that view.

They might cre­

ate a widespread public demand for consumer-credit controls as an alternative
to enhanced cyclical fluctuations or to an increased degree of general credit
restraint.

Such feeling might be generated, for example, if terms were once

more eased radically at a time when credit demand and consumer spending were
on the increase.

In that case, society might decide that the benefits to be

gained by consumer-credit regulation would outweigh the difficulties.

If so,

we should benefit from the experience during prior periods of regulation so
as to minimize administrative difficulties.
And so I return to the question posed at the beginning of my remarks,
Thi.s question has been put into verse by the economist, Kenneth Boulding:
The Fruits of the Financial System
Are quite impressive, once you list ’
em,
Although the system has the power
To turn its fruits extremely sour,
1/
l7

"Principles of Economic Policy" by Kenneth E, Boulding, p, 210.