View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

STATE LIMITS TO GROWTH
A Discussion Paper
for the
August 16, 1974
Meeting of the
National Legislative Conference
Albuquerque Conference Center
Albuquerque, New Mexico

by
B. K. MacLaury
President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

It's indeed an honor to be invited to participate in this National
Legislative Conference.

Coming as I do from a background with the Federal

Reserve System, I have frankly had little occasion to become acquainted with
the processes of state government except in the abstract, nor, more importantly,
with state legislators.
For the past year, however, I have had the privilege of serving with
the Commission on Minnesota's Future, and have come to know at first hand the
dedication and concern of the twelve legislative members of that Commission.
As in every walk of life, I'm sure there are both saints and scoundrels among
elected representatives.

Unfortunately, the legacy of Watergate has given the

public at large the impression that the scoundrels predominate.
tainly not my experience.

That is cer­

Indeed, I believe that conferences such as this one

are witness to the continuing efforts to find better ways of serving the con­
stituencies you represent.
One brief word of local pride, if I may.

I'm naturally delighted

that the Conference has seen fit to select Marty Sabo, Speaker of the Minnesota
House, as its chairman this year,

lie's clearly one of the bright young leaders

of our future, and deserves this fine recognition.

The subject of this particular session is "State Limits to Growth."
In thinking about the topic, I couldn't help noticing how differently we are
inclined to approach the subject today than we did even twenty years ago.
Growth in output, as measured by the Gross National Product, used to be the
uncontested standard for judging success.




1

More "things" automatically implied

a rising standard of living.

Since it took people to produce "things," more

things also implied more jobs, and more jobs meant full employment.
Though we still have a deeply-felt commitment to full employment,
we have changed our notions about growth as traditionally defined.

First, we

have become increasingly aware of the adverse side effects of untrammeled
growth in terms of pollution and environmental degradation.

Second, we have

come face to face with the spectre of dwindling natural resources, both in the
abstract in such concepts as "The Closing Circle," "Planet Earth," "Limits to
Growth," etc., and in concrete terms with sudden energy shortages.
Partly as a result, growth has come to be seen not as an unrnixed
blessing, but as a question of balance.

Emphasis has shifted from standard of

living to quality of life, and from economic indicators to social indicators
in a broader sense.

In fact, in thinking about the topic "State Limits to

Growth," I wondered whether the planners of the Conference were interested in
finding ways to overcome limits to state growth, or whether, on the contrary,
they were seeking guidance on how one could limit state growth!

In some sense,

they probably meant both.
Limits to growth is not a new concept, although it has recently taken
on new overtones in the process of becoming a popular slogan.

In a fundamental

sense, of course, economic questions since the beginning of time have tried to
deal with the issues raised by unsatisfied wants on the one hand, and limited
resources on the other.

Whether it's the family budget or the national product,

we are continually faced with choices involving more now versus more later,
more of this and less of that, etc.

And when these choices are made consciously

rather than unconsciously, we almost inevitably find ourselves in the business




2

of making lists, assigning priorities, and in general trying to cope with the
problems of limited resources.
What, then, can be said about state limits to growth?

I'd like to

consider briefly four types of "limits" with which policy-makers must contend
in working through a philosophy and practical approach to questions of growth:
1) natural resources; 2) people; 3) outside influences; and 4) tir.ie.
I suppose the most obvious kind of limit, or constraint, or deter­
minant, if you will, of state growth is resource endowment.

Certainly, if

one looks at the history of Minnesota, it's hard to escape the fact that much
of that state's present pattern of life is a legacy of its position at the
headwaters of the Mississippi River, hence a transportation hub; a grain grow­
ing area and hence a flour milling center; a source of first lumber and now of
paper products; and of course the nation's provider of first iron ore and now
taconite.

The state's resouce endowment, in other words, was both a stimulus

to growth in certain areas, and a limit on growth in other ways.

Minnesota

doesn't grow bananas, for instance.
Yet resource endowment is perhaps less of a constraint on state
growth today than it was in the past.

It doesn't explain, for example, why

Minnesota should have become a major center for the computer industry.

But

somehow this very break with a resource-oriented past symbolizes the fact
that technological change is a widely recognized means for freeing us from
resource limitations.

Indeed, as the nation as a whole becomes more oriented

toward the service industries — away from primary activities such as mining
and agriculture, and into the so-called post-industrial society — one would
assume that the links between a state's income and wealth and its traditional




3

natural resource base would become increasingly tenuous.

It's also true that

with changing values and relative scarcities, we now consider as natural re­
sources such things as clean air, clean water, open spaces, and wilderness
areas that were previously thought of as free goods, when they were thought
of at all.
In a different sense, state governments have become much bolder in
limiting growth despite resource endowments.

Again to take an example from

Minnesota, you have probably read about the famous case of the Reserve Mining
Company and the state's efforts to halt the dumping of 67,000 tons a day of
taconite tailings into Lake Superior, even at the possible cost of several
thousand jobs in an area of the state where jobs are far from plentiful.
Similarly, one of the most important and difficult decisions facing Minnesota
legislators is whether, and on what terms, to permit exploration and develop­
ment of apparently large copper-nickle ore deposits across the northern tier
of the state.

Many other states face similar choices on natural resource

developments, petroleum refineries, deep-water ports, power plant sitings, and
on and on.

We have reached a time, in other words, when natural resources are

no longer a necessary condition for growth within a state, nor indeed a suf­
ficient condition if the residents decide to forego growth by leaving resources
unexploited.

A different sort of limit on state growth grows out of population
patterns and trends.

In a crude sense, of course, one can think of growth

simply as an increasing headcount.

Again, however, our yardsticks are changing.

More is no longer necessarily better.




At the least, income per capita is taken

4

as the measure of well-being and growth, not total income.

And if we knew how

to measure it, I suppose we'd prefer a quality of life index.
There's no point in listing here all the characteristics of demographic
patterns, but it is relevant, I think, to point out their potential influence
on state growth.

Migration rates, population distribution patterns, age char­

acteristics and dependency ratios, education levels and other attributes of a
state's population determine to some extent its potential — and its limits -for growth.

Some of these characteristics can be influenced by public policies,

others much less so.

For example, for all the talk of discouraging immigration

into certain states, I'm not aware of specific policies designed to accomplish
this purpose, nor any evidence of the effectiveness of propaganda in this regard.
In other instances, states provide high quality education for their residents
only to find the best trained students leaving for jobs in other parts of the
country.

Similarly, there's much talk and some public effort to counter the

migration from the countryside to the cities, or from the inner cities to the
suburbs.

But again I'm not aware of any substantial reversal of trends brought

about by such policies, despite isolated cases of factories in the countryside.
One other characteristic of a state's population that's much harder
to get a handle on, and yet may be as important as any other in determining
growth and its quality, and that's leadership.

Every one of you, I'm sure,

could cite examples of towns or districts in your states that stand out from
the rest, or are different from their neighbors, simply because a few individuals
got together and made something happen.
a larger scale at the state level.

The same thing is true, I believe, on

There've been many studies that have tried

to identify the characteristics of leadership and how one goes about developing




5

it, but no one, to my knowledge, has yet hit upon a workable formula.

At the

same time, its axiomatic that without good leadership, in either the public or
the private sectors -- and of course preferably both -- growth can be stifled.

A third kind of limit on growth within a state relates to what's going
on outside its borders.
world around it.

No geographical unit is an island, insulated from the

This is obvious in so many ways.

The Russian crop failure in

1972, for example, certainly had a pervasive impact on growth of incomes in our
agricultural region.

Likewise, in a different sense, the decision of oil export­

ing Middle Eastern countries first to embargo petroleum shipments to the U.S.,
and then to raise prices manyfold has had a profound effect on all developed
countries.

Even within this country, it has had substantially differing impacts

on different states, depending on whether they were net oil producers or oil
consumers.
State legislators hardly need to be reminded that what goes on in
Washington can affect the growth of their states profoundly.

Where defense

contracts are placed, or other public works projects are awarded are cases
in point.

The shape and size of housing programs, rural development programs,

urban renewal programs, and the long string of other federally funded programs
will either promote or limit state growth, sometimes quite unexpectedly.

And

quite apart from government program levels, the overall state of the nation's
economy will determine in large measure the pace of growth in the constituent
parts.
It’
s also clear that the options open to any given state are deter­
mined to some extent by what its neighbors amd competitors are doing.




6

I have

in mind, for example, that differing tax levels and structures among various
states do have some influence -- through it's not clear how much -- on locational
choices by business.

Similarly, if one state chooses to step out ahead of

national norms on air and water pollution standards, it has to expect that some
industries that might otherwise have expanded within its borders may choose to
move next door.

The same may be true for power plant sitings, and other invest­

ments usually thought of as spurring economic growth.
In sum, there are limits on state growth imposed by the outside
economic environment, and by the competition of other states with differing
philosophies of development.

Finally, there's a different sort of limit on state growth that has to
do with time spans.

When any of us gets a good idea, we usually want to imple­

ment it right away.

Moreover, we've been taught that we live in a society of

instant gratification, that the pace of change, in technology at least, is so
rapid that we are suffering from future shock, that if we only had the will, we
could bring the fruits of advanced ideas to all rnen, and moreover, that unless
we hurry up and make changes soon, we'll drown in our own filth or run out of
resources.

Both the positive and negative inducements to rapid change, in

other words, push us hard to find answers and implement programs.
Yet all of you share, I'm sure, the sense of frustration that cornes
from seeing some things change only slowly, and sometimes not at all.

Despite

our cult of quick solutions, we find that the course of human events is largely
predetermined at any given point in time.

This is true, of course, in an economic

sense in that our capital structures -- our investments in plant and equipment,
in cities and transportation systems, in housing and cultivated land — are the




7

legacy of decades, if not generations.
overnight.

One does not replace or transform these

Similarly, there is a great momentum — or inertia, as the case may

be — in what might be called our institutional arrangements:

the way we order

our lives, the incentives to which we respond, our attitudes toward life and
how we want to live it.

These investments, then, in things and in ideas, limit

the scope and pace of growth and change within the state at any point in time.
To recapitulate, the limits to state growth as I see them can be
divided into four categories:
1.

natural resource endowment;

2.

population characteristics;

3.

what's going on outside the state; and

4.

the inertia that efforts toward change must overcome.

I'm sure that any one of you might analyze the issues differently, and equally
validly.

The important question, though is why you as state legislators are

concerned about limits to growth in your state.
twofold.

The answer, I think, is probably

First, many of you are being called upon to set limits to certain kinds

of growth in your states, growth that your constituents no longer find acceptable
for environmental or other reasons.
point.

Efforts at land use planning are a case in

At the same time, you are expected to assure full employment, rising

standards of living, better public services, and much, much more.

Like they say,

nobody ever promised you a rose garden, nor that the demands of the electorate
would be reasonable, compatible or consistent!
The political arena has always been the place where conflicting demands
have come head to head, to be reconciled or compromised.

In this sense, the limits

to growth questions are no different from those you and your predecessors have
wrestled with in the past.




But I do sense a new urgency in trying to deal with

8

the questions in a broader framework than heretofore.

Previously, our frontier

heritage permitted us the luxury of making decisions piecemeal, in isolation,
without worrying too much about the side effects on other places, other people,
or the next generation.

We learn daily, however, that everything seems to be

connected to everything else, that there are feedbacks in the system, whether
biological, ecological, economic, or social that have to be taken into account,
and that the margin for error seems to be diminishing.

So we are being forced

to take a broader look at the consequences of our decisions -- broader in two
dimensions:

first, integrating the whole spectrum of interacting issues that

determine the quality of life today; and second, a conscious weighing of the
tradeoffs between quality of life today, and quality of life tomorrow.
This perceived need to expand the framework within which intelligent
decision-making can take place has been the genesis, I believe, of increasing
efforts in various states in the last few years to plan more systematically for
the future.

Different states have responded in different ways.

I don't think

that any of the efforts to date can claim great results — certainly we in
Minnesota are at too early a stage to predict with confidence that we're on the
right track.

Yet I somehow think the efforts must continue, because the need is

so evident.
Against that background, let me describe what the Commission on
Minnesota's Future is, how it's going about its task, and what kind of results
it hopes to achieve.

Rather than discuss in detail the establishment of the

Commission, its membership, duties, etc., let me refer those of you who are
interested to a booklet called Minnesota's Future that provides this information.
The key characteristics, it seems to me are these:




9

1) the forty citizen-members

appointed by the governor represent a broad cross-section of the state's resi­
dents, geographically, ethnically, age-wise and so on; 2) the twelve legislators —
six from each house selected on a bipartisan basis — are playing an active role
in the Commission's deliberations; 3) the Commission is funded by the legislature
for two years and has an expected life of four years; 4) staffing is provided by
the State Planning Agency; 5) the mandate is broad enough to permit an allencompassing look at the factors that are likely to be important to the state's
future; and 6) the ex-officio membership of the state's economic development
region chairmen provides important input from across the state, and a channel
of communication about the Commission's work to key local officials.
Following organizational meetings in October 1973 and January of this
year, the Commission divided itself into four working committees, somewhat along
the lines of the California Tomorrow plan:

a committee looking at natural

resources; a committee looking at man-made structures, such as housing, urban
centers, transportation systems etc.; a committee looking at human needs, such
as health care, education, employment opportunities, etc.; and finally, a
committee looking at structures of governance, how decisions affecting the public
are made, in both the public and private sectors.

In each case, the intent is

to learn about the way the system is operating at present, determine what major
trends or changes seem to be occurring, assess the desirability of the probable
future as it seems to be unfolding, identify alternative futures and the public
policy measures required to bring them about.

Our structure, in other words,

is designed to cover the waterfront of issues affecting the quality of life
today, and to take a bearing on the future.
Quite frankly, the task at times seems almost overwhelming.

While we

have been doing a good deal of thinking about how we might best communicate with




10

broad groups of citizens about our work, we have consciously deferred going to
the public at large for their ideas until we had better defined in our own minds
the key issue areas and key questions that ought to be asked, and how we might
best set out the trade-offs that almost always are involved.
We are just now in the process of putting together our first interim
report to the Governor and the legislature.

We intend to use that document to

give focus to our own thoughts, as well as to try to justify, to ourselves as
much as to the legislature, that our efforts to wrestle the future into manageable
bite-sized, prioritized alternatives are likely to bear fruit.

We intend the

report, likewise, to serve as the basis for cornmunieating key questions to the
public.

This is a tall order, and we'll all feel a sense of relief and accom­

plishment if we can pull it off.
In a very real sense, one could think of our task on the Commission
as one of searching for critical limits — on the one hand identifying those
negative limits that stand in the way of our growth toward the lifestyle we
desire;

on the other hand, recommending positive limits to growth of a kind

we're no longer prepared to permit.

Even assuming we can agree on such limits,

and find acceptable public policy options that may help us to deal with them,
we recognize that movement in the desired directions by the state will, in turn,
be limited by the outside environment in which we're operating, and the inertia
of our past.

Growth, as I said at the outset, is a question of balance.

The

only way to achieve balance is to put all the evidence on the scales — that's
what the Commission on Minnesota's Future is trying to do.
I must say I'm greatly encouraged by the strong support of our legis­
lative members.
concrete results.




They are our best assurance that the Commission can lead to
At the same time, they have urged us not to be bound by

11

traditional ways of thinking.

And with great practical foresight, they have

warned that despite our best efforts, we will not be able to identify all the
major trends of the future, and have therefore urged that we consider recom­
mendations for an ongoing process that will continuously update the type of
broad look at the future — and desired futures — in which we are now engaged.




12