View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE FED AND THE DUAL-BANKING SYSTEM

Remarks by
BRUCE K. MacLAURY
President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

at the
Northern Regional Convention
Bank Administration Institute

Duluth Arena
Duluth, Minnesota
May 20, 197^




THE FED AND THE DUAL-BANKING SYSTEM

Remarks by
BRUCE K. MacLAURY
President
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

at the

Montana Bankers Convention

Banff
Alberta, Canada

June 27, 1974

THE FED AND THE DUAL-BANKING SYSTEM

A year ago, the chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, Arthur
Burns, called for legislation which would impose uniform reserve re­
quirements on demand deposits at all financial institutions.

That

legislation has now been drafted, and was submitted to Congress with the
Administration's endorsement last January.
The reaction to Chairman Burns' proposal was swift, hostile,
and in my opinion not very well reasoned.

Of course, some of the

opposition to uniform reserve requirements is understandable, because
such a law, if passed, would diminish the economic advantages now en­
joyed by non-member banks.

In effect, the current reserve discrepancies

are like a discriminatory tax — paid by some and not by others in the
same line of business.
Let me summarize the nature of the inequality that now exists.
As you know, banks that are members of the Federal Reserve System are re­
quired to hold reserves in the form of vault cash or collected balances
in Federal Reserve Banks equal to specified proportions of their deposit
liabilities.

These reserves earn no interest.

In contrast, in a number

of states, the percentage of deposits that must be held as reserves is
smaller for non-member banks than for members.

But more important, in

many states non-member banks may hold reserves in the form of securities
that earn interest, correspondent bank balances that can claim services,
and even uncollected checks.

Since member banks also need liquid secu­

rities and correspondent balances in addition to the reserves they main­
tain with the Federal Reserve, it's not hard to see why bank earnings
can frequently be increased by withdrawal from the Federal Reserve
System.




- 2 -

Reflecting this financial penalty attached to membership is
the large number of withdrawals from membership in recent years.
I960, about 700 banks have left the Federal Reserve System.

Since

Of 1,600

newly chartered state banks in that period, only 100 elected to join.
During roughly the same period, the proportion of deposits in member
banks declined from 83 percent to 78 percent of the total.

And over

the past ten years, 40 percent of the increase In checking account
balances at commercial banks took place at non-member banks.
To some degree the accelerating withdrawals from the System
may result from the upward trend of interest rates in recent years.
When interest rates were low, the financial reward to a bank that with­
drew from the Federal Reserve was less than it is today when interest
rates are high.

With Federal funds yielding 11 percent, all banks, both

member and non-member, are obviously anxious to minimize the amount of
assets that do not earn interest.
It is understandable, therefore, that non-member banks resist
the extension of the Fed's reserve requirements to them.

And it's

reasonable that they should inquire whether the benefits said to result
from uniform reserve requirements justify the financial penalty (or more
accurately, loss of advantage) they feel they would incur.

So I'd like

to take a look at what benefits could be expected from uniform reserve
requirements.
As you know, the academic community, the financial community
and the Federal Reserve in recent years have all attached more signifi­
cance to the behavior of the money supply than was true previously, when
interest rates were given a great deal more attention.




In fact, I think

- 3 -

it is fair to say that today most students of money and banking agree
that the effectiveness of monetary policy depends to a considerable extent
on how well the Federal Reserve can control the growth of deposits.
Now it's no secret that money growth has frequently strayed
from the rate that we in the Federal Reserve have intended.
the departures have been sizable.

At times

One reason for this lack of precision

is the fact that a growing proportion of the money supply is accounted for
by non-member bank deposits, deposits over which the Fed has much looser
control.

For example, $1.00 of reserves at the Fed on average supports

about $7.00 of demand deposits at member banks, but as much as $50.00 of
such deposits at non-member banks.

Obviously, it's difficult to tell how

much money we're creating with this kind of range of variation.
Moreover, under present circumstances, with inequitable
impact on different banks, we are very reluctant to use changes — and
particularly increases — in reserve requirements as a means of imple­
menting monetary policy.

Thus, one tool that could be of help at times

is largely immobilized.
Let me underline that the lack of uniformity in reserve re­
quirements is only one of the factors causing difficulties for credit
policy.

But the problem is getting more serious.

Why, then, the strong

reaction against this proposal?
Larry Kreider, executive vice president and economist for the
Conference of State Bank Supervisors, has described the uniform reserve
proposal as a "frontal attack" on the basic freedoms of the entire banking
industry.
He said that "there is no convincing evidence that compulsory
affiliation (with the Federal Reserve) would lead to more effective




-

monetary policy.

k

-

Certainly freedom from compulsory affiliation cannot be

blamed for the poor batting average (of the Fed) from 1965 to date ..."
To this I would reply that we do not claim uniform reserve requirements
will save us from inappropriate monetary policy.

What we do claim is

that when monetary policy is appropriate, and we hope that it will be
most of the time, then uniform reserves will help us to be more effective
and more precise.
Kreider also argues that "compulsory affiliations for reserve
purposes cannot be expected to yield greater equality among banks ...
Banks over which the Fed has reserve-setting powers have greater inequal­
ity among them ... than exists between member and non-member banks of a
comparable size grouping."
say about this:

There are three things that I would like to

1) We recognize that reserve requirements for members are

graduated by size of deposits, with smaller banks required to maintain lower
ratios.

This can be described as "inequality", of course, but more realisti­

cally discrimination by size In a rough way only offsets some of the advan­
tages of large-size banks, and thus Is economically, as well as politically,
justifiable.

In any case, it's not the same as having unequal rules for

otherwise equal competitors.

2) The degree of inequality between members

and non-members is greater than the crude figures indicate, because non­
members In fact get substantially more services for their correspondent
balances than the Fed can offer against reserves.

3) Withdrawals from mem­

bership In the Federal Reserve System, clearly reflect the Inequality
between members and non-members, not differences in reserve requirements
among member banks.
It has also been suggested, erroneously in my view, that uniform
reserves would somehow involve a great deal more Federal Reserve intervention




in the management of banks.

For example, Dr. Kreider said, "First, in

operating our banks, we want to have the flexibility needed to serve our
trade area.

Generally, if we want to make a sound loan and have lendable

funds to do so, we should not have to get the approval of anyone outside
the bank or bank board.

If we need to ask our correspondent bank for

participation on a loan, we should be free to do so ...

We should be

free to determine within a competitive environment where we go for our
participation loans.

To have someone from the government, whether state

or federal, tell us we should not make a specific type of loan at a cer­
tain point in time, should not compete to increase loans consistent with
total funds ... should increase certain types of loans as determined by a
governmental employee some distance from our trade area, or where we should
go for any correspondent type of service, violates what most of us believe
to be basic freedoms.
"For a bureaucrat, irrespective of the trappings of his position,
to tell a banker how and for what he should allocate funds assumes that he
knows the banker's milieu better than the banker, that he is more honest
than the banker, and that he has a greater interest in the particular trade
area than does the banker, his board, stockholders and customers.

These are

assumptions that most of us would reject out of hand."
If any of this malarky were true, then bankers should be alarmed.
So would I be.

But this sort of argument is strictly a red herring:

the

uniform reserves proposal does absolutely nothing to change the supervisory
relationships that now exist, and thus in no way invites more or different
public intervention in the private sector.
Another charge which Dr. Kreider and other critics of the uni­
form reserve proposal have made is that correspondent bank relationships




- 6 -

would be greatly altered.

He states, "You see, greater Fed control ...

would dilute the vitality of correspondent services which are provided
primarily by member banks, correspondent services, along with correspond­
ent balances, would gradually be translocated from the private, competitive
sector of the economy to a highly centralized government agency.

I don't

think that this would contribute to the type of democratic economy most
people want."
I don't deny that uniform reserve requirements might alter
existing correspondent bank relationships, simply because the proposal,
if enacted, would remove an important disincentive to Fed membership.
But there are a number of services provided by correspondent banks that
the Federal Reserve has no intention of providing.
overlines:

One example would be

if a bank receives a loan application which exceeds its legal

lending limit, the Federal Reserve cannot share in that loan as a corre­
spondent bank can.

Investment advice would be another area where the Fed

is not prepared to provide service.

Bank stock loans are another.

Some

correspondent banks furnish consulting services on all phases of commercial
bank operations.

The Federal Reserve does not supply this kind of service.

Thus the need for correspondent banks would not disappear if banks were
required to observe uniform reserve requirements.
Finally, spokesmen for the Conference of State Bank Supervisors
frequently express the view that compulsory membership in the Fed — which
we are not talking about — or even uniform reserve requirements for all
banks, constitutes a threat to the very survival of the dual-banking system.
This also, I submit, is pure myth.
If I understand the term properly, the dual-banking system refers
to the dual-sources of bank charters in the United States -- the state




" 7 -

governments on the one hand, or the federal government on the other.
Uniform reserve requirements would in no way restrict the freedom of a
bank to operate under a state charter, and thus choose among different
supervisory and examining authorities.
Concerning the dual-banking system, the Hunt Commission said:
"The Commission believes that the widest feasible options among chartering
and supervisory agencies should be created and maintained.

When a particu­

lar type of financial institution can be chartered by only one agency —
whether state or federal — a two-fold danger emerges.

First, the

agency may become over-zealous in protecting existing firms, with the
result that entry by new firms is effectively foreclosed.

Second, the

agency may not be as innovative and imaginative as it should be in
exercising its authority.

Opportunities for dual-chartering and super­

vision mitigate these dangers and improve service to the public."
I personally support these arguments for dual banking.

But it

is misrepresentation to say that uniform reserve requirements or even
mandatory membership constitute a "frontal attack" on the dual-banking
system.

The only logical interpretation I can put on this kind of

emotional appeal is that the supervisors believe that the only reason
banks apply for, and retain, state charters is because of the unfair
competitive advantage that less onerous state reserve requirements pro­
vide.

My own belief is that the dual-banking system has a legitimate

basis.




Getting by on the cheap is not it.