View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

BRETTON WOODS MACH II -- THE SHAPE OF THINGS TO COME




Remarks by
BRUCE K. MacLAURY
Presi dent
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

at
The Money Marketeers Dinner
New York

May 17, 1972

BRETTON WOODS MACH II -- THE SHAPE OF THINGS TO COME

There's a certain irony in the fact that President Nixon's
announcement last August 15 that the dollar was no longer convertible
into gold came as a shock to a world that had long since become
accustomed to the idea that the dollar was no longer convertible
into gold.

Were it not for the obviously serious consequences of

that announcement, one would be tempted to compare it to that of the
boy who finally called attention to the fact that the Emperor had no
c loth es.
But the consequences were - and are - serious.

Indeed,

during the four month interval between August and the Smithsonian
Agreement in December, there were times when 1t seemed questionable
whether a new order would in fact emerge to take the place of the
old.
This turbulence should not have been particularly surprising,
since it had been pretty clear that when the chips were down, and the
gold window finally had to be formally closed, the reaction was not
likely to be the neat one postulated by the benign neglect "dollar
standard" advocates -- of foreign countries holding more inconvertible
dollars, or revaluing their currencies.

The risk, rather, was of

retaliation through restrictions on exchange transactions or trade,
or both.

Indeed it was to minimize this very risk that most of us

felt that we should avoid taking the ultimate step -- implicit and
well understood though it was on all sides -- until it was clear
that the United States had no other choice.




To have renounced our

- 2 -

obligation to remain convertible before exhausting all other
possibilities would have been considered an act of bad faith by our
trading partners, and would thus have invited the retaliation that
nobody wanted.
Even when, in the face of massive outflows of dollars and
a rapidly deteriorating trade account, it became clear to nearly
everyone last summer that dollar convertibility at existing exchange
rates could no longer be sustained, the spectre that most threatened
international financial markets was that of spreadtng protectionism
through restrictions and a breakdown in cooperation.

Fortunately,

that threat, though a real one, did not materialize in any extensive
or irreversible way.
But if we have successfully avoided a collapse of the
working arrangements among nations in support of their international
commerce, there's no denying that those arrangements have undergone
a profound change in the last few months.

The world of Bretton

Woods, to which we had become so accustomed, survived as long as
it did largely because there was no practical alternative that could
be set in its place, even when it became increasingly apparent that
the postulates of 1945 were no longer workable.

Now, however, the

situation is different -- the system has already changed in fact,
and the task is no longer how to preserve the semblance of past
traditions, but how to forge new rules and postulates in keeping
with the needs of the future.
Perhaps the most difficult aspect of the task is the need
to construct a system that will work in a world where the balance
of economic power is now more evenly distributed than at any time




- 3 -

in the post-war period.

For it's difficult to avoid the feeling

that what made Bretton Woods as durable and workable as it was,
was the existence of a dominant, and by and large benevolent, center
of power in the system -- namely, the United States.

No amount of

negotiation is going to restore that concentration of power, nor
provide a ready substitute for it in the near future.

Instead, we

are going to have to recognize that internationally agreed rules
must replace dominant sovereign powers as the guardians of peace
and order.

But as we know from our experience in other areas, the

recognition of this fact doesn't make the task of fashioning the
rules any easier.
As you know, the communique issued at the time of the Smi th­
sonian Agreement last December spelled out the areas in which further
discussions were needed -- in effect, an agenda of unfinished business.
I'd like to comment on a number of those areas this evening in hopes
that wider discussion of the issues will help to advance the cause.
Two prefatory remarks are in order, however.

First, although I

continue to work for an official institution, my responsibilities
no longer encompass the field of international finance, and I have
not tried to stay in touch with official thinking in this fastmoving area.

So when I say that my comments represent strictly

personal views, I hope you will believe me.

Second, when I started

to think about these remarks a couple of weeks ago, I had no idea
that the subject would already have received such extensive coverage
as a result of the ABA's International Monetary Conference last week
in Montreal.

But despite that coverage -- or even perhaps because

of it -- I think there is still room for some clarification of
views in this admittedly difficult area.




- 4 -

ADJUSTMENTS IN THE EXCHANGE RATE MECHANISM
One of the first Items on anyone's agenda of unfinished
business is the regularization of the present ad hoc arrangements
with respect to exchange rates.

After a pretty bumpy take-off,

the new central rates agreed upon last December now seem to be
accepted increasingly widely as a reasonable reflection of viable
exchange relationships for the foreseeable future.

Inevitably,

one hears comments about the durability of this or that rate, but
by and large, the general structure is acknowledged to have been
worked out pretty well, and fears that the whole Smithsonian A gree­
ment would fall apart, so prevalent only a couple of months ago,
have now disappeared.
Floating Rates
Similarly, with one or two well-reported exceptions,
there has been a notable absence of calls for a return to floating
rates.

There are those, of course, who saw the re-establishment

of central rates as snatching defeat from the jaws of victory,
believing that with a little more time, businessmen would have
learned to cope with the uncertainties implied by floating rates.
But such comments, I'm afraid, don't accurately gauge the depth of
anxiety on the part of many businessmen who saw export orders,
especially for long-delivery capital goods, literally dry up during
the interregnum from mid-August to mid-December.
Now I would be the first to acknowledge that the four
months following August 15 was about the worst possible time to
conduct a meaningful experiment with floating exchange rates.
Hardly a week went by but what there was some new announcement




- 5 -

or rumor as to the eventual rate structure that was likely to
emerge from the tugging and hauling among the major trading
countries.

Uncertainty, in other words, was not the product of

floating rates as such, but rather of the official poker game
(and associated fears of restrictions) that was going on just
beneath the surface throughout that period.
But even granting that little light was shed on the in­
herent viability of a floating rate system by last fall's "experi­
ment", the fact remains that few businessmen and fewer officials
have any inclination to weigh anchor again on such seas for some
time to come.

Indeed, perhaps the best hope for those who remain

philosophically wedded to a world of freely flexible rates is to
push for as much flexibility as possible, not just in the immediate
institutional arrangements with respect to exchange rates, but in
the degree to which such arrangements can themselves be easily
amended in the future.

Frankly, the arguments pro and con floating

rates have long since exhausted both the tellers and the listeners,
and only practical evidence is likely to advance the cause - one
way or the other.

Thus if experience with wider bands or more

frequent changes in rates turns out to have a salutary effect on
trade and commerce, there at least will be a case for pushing the
limits somewhat further.
Transitional Floats
For the time being, however, the main task with respect
to exchange rates is to seek agreement on the changes that must
be made in the Articles of Agreement of the International Monetary
Fund (IMF) to bring existing (or perhaps slightly modified) arrange­




- 6 -

ments back within the bounds of law.
this area has already been laid.

Much of the groundwork in

It's now two years since the IMF

executive directors issued their report on possible means of achieving
greater flexibility in exchange rate adjustments.

And the areas of

common ground have been further solidified by the sanction of expe ­
rience.

For example, the technique of using transitional floats

to move from one rate to another has now been used often enough to
nearly qualify for common law status.

There are any number of details

that remain to be settled before the principle can be codified in
legal language, of course.

How long may such a float last, for

instance; must it be approved in advance, and if so under what
circumstance?

But at least the principle is no longer very contro­

versial .
Wider Bands
Likewise, differences of view concerning wider bands have
narrowed.

From the beginning of discussions on this subject, it was

recognized that there was no magic number that would provide the
unique balance between a range wide enough to accommodate seasonal
swings and minor transitional shocks on the one hand, and narrow
enough to permit forward planning by those engaged in international
trade on the other.

Now, however, there is a number that has been

accepted as a workable compromise among conflicting views and
interests - namely, the 2 1/4 percent either side of parity that
was agreed in December.

At least there is now a pragmatic starting

point, in other words, on which to base language to replace the
inflexible 1 percent limit in the present Articles.
word is "inflexible."




But the key

As Roosa and others have pointed out, what

- 7 -

is needed is some degree of discretion on the part of the IMF
to adjust the width of the permitted band in the light of further
experience, without having to crank up the extremely cumbersome
machinery required to change the Articles themselves.
It goes without saying that a country, or a group of
countries, could decide to operate on narrower limits than those
set by the IMF.

Indeed, that has been the practice throughout

much of the post-war period, and we are now witnessing a new v a ria­
tion on the same theme within the European Economic Community (EEC).
The implications of this particular experiment, of course, go far
beyond the question of appropriate widths of the band around parities.
To the extent that the expanded Common Market forges an increasingly
closely linked currency system, the greater will be the pressures
for harmonization of policies internally, and the greater will be
its ability to act as a unit vis-a-vis outside currency blocs, and
the dollar in particular.

Indeed, even if the EEC adopts an out-

ward-oriented policy stance - which at this point is by no means
certain - it is hard to escape the conclusion that progress toward
a unified currency within the Common Market will mean a reduced
role, relatively at least, for the dollar as an international
currency.
Diminished International Role of the Dollar
It is convenient to divide the international role of the
dollar, conceptually, into three aspects; as a reserve currency;
as an intervention currency; and as a transactions currency.

As

and when the arrangements among the Common Market partners provide
for some pooling of reserves, it seems reasonable to assume that




- 8 -

their need for reserves in the aggregate, and hence for dollars,
will be diminished somewhat.

And while the pooling of reserves

is one of the more sensitive political issues among them, it is
worth noting that the first steps along this path have already
been taken, first in the establishment of credit facilities for
use within the group, and more recently in the agreement to settle
monthly balances through transfers of reserves from net debtor to
net creditor in proportion to the composition of the debtor's
reserve assets.
Second, the partners have agreed to use each others'
currencies rather than the dollar for official intervention in
the exchange market so long as the narrower band (2 1/4 percent
vs. 4 1/2 percent against outside currencies) is not at the per­
mitted outside limits against the dollar.

In this case as well,

therefore, reliance on the dollar has been diminished, though by
no means eliminated.
Incidentally, by adopting the technique of intervention
in each others' currencies, the Common Market partners seem to
have finessed one of the stickier political problems that they
would have faced had they used the dollar exclusively;

namely,

a conscious decision as to where within the wider band against
the dollar (the "tunnel") the narrower Market band (the "snake")
should fall.

The potential for disagreement among partners (i.e.

those with strong payments wishing the band to be at the upper
end of the permitted range, while those with the weaker payments
wishing to conserve reserves by permitting the Market band to
settle toward the lower end of the range) has not been eliminated,




- 9 -

but apparently the inner Market band will now simply "float"
within the tunnel in response to market forces, thus avoiding
an explicit decision on its position against the dollar.
Finally, a narrower band among Common Market currencies
is also likely to diminish the role of the dollar as a tr ansac­
tions currency, at least in trade and financial transactions within
the Common Market itself, and perhaps more widely.

The argument

here is that as the risk of exchange fluctuation is reduced re la­
tive to the dollar through the narrowing of the permitted band,
Common Market businessmen will find it increasingly convenient to
denominate transactions in each others' currencies, and in practice
hold those currencies rather than the dollar as working balances.
This point was in fact made quite explicitly by Andr£ deLattre,
Deputy Governor of the Bank of France, in a talk three years ago
outlining the advantages of moving to a narrower internal band.
In my own view, the prospect of a diminished role for
the dollar as an international currency is not cause for alarm,
but rather a fact to be taken into account in assessing the like­
lihood and timing of exchange market equilibrium for the dollar,
and thus is part of the calculus on the timing and terms of co n­
vertibility.

If we could expect the same rate of growth in demand

for the dollar in the future as was experienced in the past whether as a reserve, intervention, or transactions currency this would imply one set of circumstances with respect to an
equilibrium exchange rate.

If we cannot - and it is quite certain

that we cannot - then this implies a lower rate of exchange other things equal - against other currencies.




As a practical

-

10

-

matter, of course, the dollar is not likely to be displaced in
any of its international roles very quickly, at least in any
absolute sense, so that there should be time to adjust gradually
to any decline in relative demand.
Smaller, More Frequent Exchange Rate Adjustments
Perhaps the toughest question facing those who must
translate the present pragmatic compromise on exchange rate
mechanisms into precise formal language for amendment of the IMF
Articles is how to define the terms that would justify, or even
require, a change in parities.

There is now fairly widespread

agreement that waiting for a "fundamental dis-equilibrlum" to be
documented and certified, at least as practiced in the past under
the IMF rules, involves waiting too long.

We are now prepared to

accept the idea of smaller, more frequent changes as representing
an improvement in the system.
But this is a very slippery concept, as anyone knows
who has tried to come to grips with it in detail, and translate
the principle into workable rules.

Much of the advice on this

issue seems to advocate moving the rate before the case is clear,
in order not to be caught holding out too long.

Indeed, when one

hears the Chancellor of the Exchequer assure British businessmen
in the budget message that they can count on an expansionist policy
in their investment plans, since the exchange rate will not be
allowed to stand in the way, one wonders whether the desired
flexing of the system may not produce more mischief than improve­
ment.




- 11 -

Clearly, the basic point must not be lost that changes
in exchange rates by definition involve consequences for more than
one country, and cannot be allowed to become a tool of, or co m­
pletely subservient to, domestic policy goals.

This implies inter­

national surveillance of rate changes, whether they are made "more
flexible" or not.

Again, I would subscribe to a suggestion put

forward by Roosa that the IMF be allowed to establish a limit,
say 2 percent, within which countries would be permitted to adjust
their parities annually without explicit authorization from the IMF.
This limit, in turn, could be adjusted in the light of experience.
As you recognize, this is simply a modification of the principle
incorporated in the original Articles that permitted countries to
adjust their parities unilaterally up to a cumulative change of
10 percent.
Exchange Rate Changes for the Dollar:

Symmetry?

Related to the question of new, and more flexible, rules
for exchange rate changes generally is the equally difficult
problem of assuring that the dollar, too, will be able to avail
itself of the same possibilities for exchange rate changes that
are open to other currencies; assuring, in other words, that the
system works symetrically for the dollar.

The inherent problem,

of course, is that even though the dollar is now "more equal" than
in the past, it is still the dominant currency and is likely to
remain so for some time, regardless of whether one wants it to
be so or not.

And so long as this is the case, it is hard to

imagine that the rest of the world will permit us to adjust our
rate on the same terms as, say, the Belgian franc or the pound




- 12 -

sterling.

Yet so long as we do not have the same "rights" with

respect to exchange rate changes, or there is no mechanism for
requiring surplus countries to revalue, it's hard to see how we
can be expected to adhere to exactly the same rules on co nverti­
bility.
DOLLAR CONVERTIBILITY
Which brings us right up against the much-debated issue
of dollar convertibility.

Again, it's useful to distinguish the

different senses in which this term is used.

Dollar convertibility,

meaning interchangeability into other currencies, exists now and for
the most part has existed throughout the difficult transition period
through which we have been passing.

(The main qualification to this

statement is the reduced useability of the dollar resulting from
restrictions, both U.S. and foreign, on certain types of exchange
transactions or investment outlets imposed in an effort to limit
foreign accumulations of dollars.)

Earlier this year, as e xp ec ta­

tions of a dollar reflow were washed away in a flood of new o u t ­
flows, the markets began to question whether this interchange­
ability

- at least at then-existing rates - would survive.

Day-

to-day responsibility for defense of the newly established rates
fell squarely and solely on the foreign central banks, and the
question was posed as to how many more inconvertible dollars they
were prepared to swallow.
In these circumstances, a number of people argued that
the United States had a responsibility to take some initiative in
defense of the new rates.




Roosa, for example, suggested that we

- 13 -

offer some form of exchange guarantee on dollar accumulations above
a given level.

But my own impression is that such guarantees have

raised as many problems as they have solved in the aftermath of
actual rate changes.

Moreover, since Roosa suggests a guarantee

only against the effects of a dollar devaluation and not against
foreign currency appreciations, it's questionable whether foreign
countries would consider such an offer very meaningful.

Perhaps

the best that can be said on this issue is that it seems to have
gone away for the time being.

With the cessation of dollar o u t ­

flows and the distinct possibility of increased inflows, the
pressures to restrict further Interchangeability of currencies has
faded, and in some notable cases has even been reversed.
Convertibility into Gold and Reserve Assets
Dollar convertibility in the pre-August sense, however,
usually implied ultimate convertibility into gold.

So far as that

is concerned, I'm afraid we can only speak of the golden past, for
I see no chance of resumption of convertibility into gold as such.
The more meaningful question is when, and under what conditions,
the dollar should again become convertible into reserve assets
generally.

You'll note that I didn't say "whether", for in a

world of more or less fixed parities, I can see no rationale for
the dollar remaining inconvertible indefinitely.

To permit the

system to operate in such a fashion would be to accord to the
Federal Reserve the role of central bank to the world, a role
which it neither seeks nor deserves.

(It should perhaps be noted

that in a world of freely floating rates, the question of con-




- 14 -

vertibility into reserve assets would not arise, since in the
extreme case even the need for reserves would disappear.)
Convertibility - the Implications
1.

A Strong U.S. Balance of Payments.

Agreeing to the

principle of convertibility doesn't take us very far in the real
world, however.

The crux of the matter lies in the terms and

conditions, a couple of which I've already alluded to.

In the

first place, we have to have more assurance than we can possibly
have at present that the exchange rate relationships agreed to in
Washington will in fact bring the U.S. balance of payments back
into equilibrium.

The science of economic forecasting is hazard­

ous at best, and predicting the results of changes in parities is
particularly uncertain.

Only time and experience can give us

sufficient assurance that U.S. payments equilibrium is in fact a
reasonable prospect - without 1t, convertibility would be a fraud.
2.

Symmetry:

Deficit countries.

Dollar vs. other currencies; Surplus vs.

Related to this point is the need for some

mechanism that will either permit the United States more easily
to change its rate in relation to other currencies, or provide
sufficient pressure on surplus countries to Induce needed revalu­
ations, or preferably both.

Substituting SDR's for gold as the

numeraire or yardstick by which the values of all currencies are
defined should ease the cosmetics, and hence the politics, of
any future changes 1n dollar parity.

But this will do nothing

to reduce the "first among equals" position of the dollar that
will continue to hamper, if my earlier reasoning was correct, any
willingness by the rest of the world to treat the dollar symmet-




- 15 -

rically when it comes to exchange rate changes.
This particular bias against the dollar, based on the
realities of the world as it exists and is likely to exist, would
not be particularly troublesome if a way could be found to provide
for symmetry as between surplus and deficit countries.

But again

I am not very optimistic that major countries will be any more
prepared to have the IMF play a strong role in signaling the need
for upward rate changes in the future than they have been in the
past.

The sanctions of the scarce currency clause have always

been available, but never used.

Even if one is fairly optimistic

about achieving somewhat greater symmetry in exchange rate ad just­
ments between surplus and deficit countries than in the past, it
is hard to imagine that the system won't continue in some small
measure to favor devaluations rather than revaluations, thus
biasing the chances of maintaining an equilibrium position for the
dollar, even when achieved.
As in other areas, some modus operandi may be worked out
to overcome these natural biases inherent in the system, but until
it is - and no solution is Immediately apparent - moving to make
the dollar convertible would involve risks.
3.

The "Overhang".

Then, there is the sticky question of

what to do about the nearly $50 billion already in foreign official
hands.

As a practical matter, I cannot picture U.S. officials

agreeing to any plan that contemplated an amortization schedule for
the repayment of these balances.

But nor can I imagine any repu ­

diation of responsibility for these balances either.

As a sort

of middle ground, some have suggested a special "consolidation"




- 16 -

issue of SDR's - a funding into a fiduciary issue without a repay ­
ment schedule.

But this strikes me as equally difficult to nego ­

tiate, both because it would appear to be a special concession to
the U.S., and because the haphazard distribution of such an issue
among dollar-holding countries would conflict sharply with the
concept of orderly distributions that are supposedly a hallmark
of the SDR.
Faced with these many unacceptable alternatives, I see
little choice but to wait until a better balance is achieved
between U.S. assets and liabilities, either through a rebuilding
of U.S. reserves (through surpluses or regular SDR allocations) or
through reductions in liabilities (through basic surpluses or reflows
of dollars).
4.

The Link between Financial and Trade Arrangements.

Finally, there is the very practical question of whether the U.S.
should agree to convertibility of the dollar without assurance of
progress toward what Administration officials refer to as "fair
trading practices."

Should the U.S. be satisfied, in other words,

with arrangements that promised overall equilibrium, but were
silent on the composition of the U.S. balance of payments.

In

the real world, I suspect that most countries, including the U.S.,
do care about structure - export surpluses, non-discrimination on
certain categories of trade, etc. - and that this concern goes far
beyond a crude mercantilist approach to economic life.

For the

United States, for example, the ability to finance aid to Less
Developed Countries depends in large measure on our having a




- 17 -

current account, and hence a trade, surplus.

Similarly, military

burden sharing is something about which we feel strongly, quite
apart from balance of payments equilibrium.

Thus, I find it quite

understandable that the Administration seeks to associate discussions
of trade and financial matters, even though this probably Implies
slower progress toward convertibility.

The more troublesome q u e s ­

tion with respect to trade discussions is whether dismantling of
restrictions, however desirable, Isn't going to be as painful for
some vested U.S. interests as it is for foreign countries, once
all the areas for discussion are out on the table.
FUTURE RESERVE ASSETS
If agreements on exchange rate mechanisms and convertibility
are high on the agenda of unfinished business, so too is the question
of the nature of future reserve assets.

Here, though, I believe a

consensus is much closer, and I largely subscribe to the conventional
wisdom.

There is little doubt in my mind that SDR's, perhaps some­

what modified, should be the source of future additions to reserves,
and hence will fairly soon become the dominant reserve asset.

In

one sense, it seems a bit odd to describe this view as "conventional
wisdom", since agreement on the creation and issuance of SDR's is
so recent.

Yet the implications for other types of reserves, at

least among those negotiating the SDR's, were clear enough some
years back.

If SDR's worked, there would no longer be any need

for additional gold - or dollars - to provide reserve growth.
only question was whether SDR's would work, and be accepted.

The
That

question has now been answered 1n the affirmative, at least to my
sati sfaction.




- 18 -

I've already indicated my belief that the role of gold as
a monetary metal will continue to diminish, and I accept the d imin­
ishing role of the dollar as an International currency as well.
The awkward question is whether one takes the logic of this position
to its ultimate conclusion and tries to prevent countries from
accumulating dollars by requiring periodic encashments into reserve
assets.

I frankly think that any effort on the part of a few

countries or the IMF to push this extreme view would seriously delay
agreement on other matters.

Indeed, I question whether such a system

wouldn't be so fragile, particularly in the absence of strict controls
on short-term capital movements, as to represent a step backward in
attempts to create a more flexible international financial system.
The rationale, yet impracticality, for rigidly restricting
accumulations of dollars or other reserve currencies in a world
whose reserves are to be supplied through SDR's is vividly dem on­
strated by the present circumstances.

No case can be made on grounds

of needed additions to international liquidity for a new round of
SDR distributions next year, given the massive infusion of dollars
into the system 1n the last two years.

Yet there is probably no

single step that would do more to demonstrate continued support
for the system than agreement to carry forward this experiment in
coordinated reserve creation, if only in a modest way.

In the

future as well, when a choice must be made between strict logic
and practical reality for dollars as reserves, I would opt for
the latter.
One side point that arises in connection with reserve




- 19 -

creation through SDR's is whether there should be a link to
development assistance through direct allocations primarily to
less developed countries.

The issues involved are perhaps more

easily understood by putting the question in terms of domestic
institutions:

should the central bank create reserves for the

banking system, and hence determine the money supply, by buying
the obligations of, say, a regional development bank?

The danger,

of course, is that political pressures to increase the financing
of development efforts may influence inappropriately the decisions
of the central bank on the need for monetary growth.

Perhaps I

am unduly influenced by the gingerly way in which the Federal Reserve
has approached the question of purchases of agency issues - which
raised some of the same questions - but my own view is that, given
the many other hurdles that must be cleared in the next couple of
years in restructuring the international financial system, the
issue of the aid link had best be kept off the agenda at this time.
CONCLUSION
This survey of some of the issues that must be resolved
before we can claim to have codified a Bretton Woods Mach II is
daunting, even while being incomplete.

In the pursuit of the

common goal of international monetary reform, I'm not sure that
it advances the cause to search for differences of approach within
the U.S. administration, amusing and time-honored though this game
may be.
For what it is worth, my own impression is that there
was really very little difference between the basic positions set
forth last week by Dr. Burns and Undersecretary Volcker in Montreal.




- 20 -

It's true that their approaches differed:

the Chairman emphasized

the broad principles that he would expect to find in a new monetary
system; Volcker on the other hand, stressed the difficult practical
problems that would have to be overcome in reconciling conflicting
national interests, agreeing on a set of mutually consistent prin­
ciples, and finding workable mechanisms to implement those principles
once agreed.

Similarly, while the Chairman emphasized the necessity

to start the rebuilding process promptly, Volcker made it clear
that one should not expect that process to be easy or short.
Despite the clear desire on the part of many Europeans
to get on with the job of reform, I personally think that we are
fortunate now 1n being able to afford to take time to do the job
well.

My optimism rests in the belief that the dollar is on the

road toward greater strength, despite the lack of much concrete
evidence thus far to support this view.

And if the dollar is

strong, then experience indicates that the international financial
system can operate pretty well, almost regardless of the detailed
characteristics of that system during the interim period of
negotiations.
Because important national interests are at stake, not
just for the U.S., but for the rest of the world; because mens'
conception of reality changes more slowly than reality itself;
because we are engaged in building a system that should serve us
in changing circumstances for at least another quarter century;
and because a false start could be as disillusioning as the
British rush to convertibility in 1947, but with far wider




- 21 -

repercussions - for all these reasons, we should not expect
progress on international monetary reform to be easy or rapid.
But because the most important asset along the way will
be the good will and continued cooperation of the world's trading
nations, we should get started.