View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
11:00 a.m. EDT [8:00 a.m. PDT]
July 23, 2003

An Unwelcome Fall in Inflation?

Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Economics Roundtable
University of California, San Diego
La Jolla, California
July 23, 2003

Achieving and maintaining price stability is the bedrock principle of a sound
monetary policy. Price stability promotes economic growth and welfare by increasing
the efficiency of the market mechanism, facilitating long-term planning, and minimizing
distortions created by the interaction of inflation and the tax code, accounting rules,
financial contracts, and the like. Price stability also increases economic welfare by
promoting stability in output and employment. In particular, the marked decline in the
variability of both inflation and output in recent decades, not only in the United States but
also in most of the rest of the world, is by no means an accident. A significant portion of
this improved performance has resulted from a reorientation of central bank policies
toward a greater emphasis on keeping inflation low and stable. These policies have
helped to anchor the public's inflation expectations at a low level, which has not only
helped to contain inflation but has also given central banks greater latitude to stabilize the
real economy with less concern than in the past about potential inflationary
consequences.
Since the inflation crisis of the 1970s, the Federal Reserve has consistently
pursued the goal of price stability in the United States. And not too long ago, something
remarkable happened--the goal was achieved! Core inflation measures (that is, measures
of inflation that exclude the prices of the relatively volatile food and energy components)
now lie in the general range of 1 to 2 percent per year, which (taking into account factors
such as measurement biases in inflation indexes) is probably the de facto equivalent of
price stability.
Attaining price stability is an important accomplishment, one of which my
predecessors on the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) can justifiably be proud.

- 2But this development has also forced the Federal Reserve--as well as the public--to
reorient its thinking about inflation in a fundamental way. After a long period in which
the desired direction for inflation was always downward, we are now in a situation in
which risks to the inflation rate can be either upward, toward excessive inflation, or
downward, toward too-low inflation or deflation. As many of you are aware, the Federal
Reserve officially recognized this new situation in its balance-of-risks statement issued at
the close of the FOMC meeting this past May 6. That statement was the first to assess
the risks to economic activity and inflation separately, recognizing explicitly that upside
and downside risks to inflation could exist under varying conditions of the real economy.
Previous FOMC statements had characterized the balance of risks one-dimensionally, as
being either in the direction of economic weakness or in the direction of excessive
inflation.
The May 6 statement was more than a procedural innovation; it also broke new
ground as the first occasion in which the FOMC expressed the concern that inflation
might actually fall too low. Let me repeat the critical portion of the statement for you:

"Although the timing and extent of [the] improvement remain uncertain, the
Committee perceives that over the next few quarters the upside and downside
risks to the attainment of sustainable growth are roughly equal. In contrast, over
the same period, the probability of an unwelcome substantial fall in inflation,
though minor, exceeds that of a pickup in inflation from its already low level.
The Committee believes that, taken together, the balance of risks to achieving its
goals is weighted toward weakness over the foreseeable future."

Though terse, the FOMC's statement--and the subsequent statement after the June
meeting, which contained similar language--evoked powerful reactions in the media and
in the financial markets. Notably, since the May 6 statement, the concept of deflation has

-3commanded wide public attention for the first time in many decades. Moreover, longterm government bond yields have fluctuated sharply, falling to unusually low levels
immediately after May 6 but rising more recently as bond market participants have
reacted both to Fed pronouncements and to incoming economic data.
Today I would like to share my own thoughts on the prospect of an "unwelcome
substantial fall in inflation" --in particular, why a substantial fall in inflation going
forward would indeed be unwelcome; why some risk of further disinflation, though
"minor," should not be ignored; and what such a fall would imply for the conduct of
monetary policy. Obviously, the opinions I will express are strictly my own and are not
necessarily those of my colleagues on the Federal Open Market Committee or the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 1
Why a Fall in Inflation Would Be Unwelcome
After a decades-long war on inflation--dubbed "public enemy number one" in
some public opinion polls in the 1970s--imagining that a "substantial fall in inflation"
would be unwelcome seems just a bit strange. Why does this risk, minor though it may
be, concern the Fed?
Let's first be clear what we are talking about. Some in the media apparently
interpreted the May 6 statement as saying that the Federal Reserve anticipated imminent
deflation in the United States and informed the public accordingly. In my view, such an
interpretation substantially overstates the concerns that the FOMC intended to
communicate with its statement. First, we have no reason to think that a drastic change in
the inflation rate is imminent. Should further declines occur, a more gradual downward

1 I would like to thank members of the Board staff for valuable assistance, particularly Flint
Brayton, Deb Lindner, David Reifschneider, and Jeremy Rudd.

- 4drift over a period of one to two years would be the more likely scenario. Second,
nowhere did the statement refer specifically to deflation (that is, to a decline in the
general price level); rather, the reference was, again, to a "substantial fall in inflation." In
the present circumstances, a disinflation (a decline in the rate of inflation) and a deflation
(a falling price level) are not necessarily the same thing. Inflation could decline
somewhat from present levels and still remain positive, although it is true that the lower
the inflation rate goes, the greater is the risk of actual deflation at some future time.
This distinction between inflation that is positive yet too low and deflation is
worth exploring for a moment. Although the Federal Reserve does not have an explicit
numerical target range for measured inflation, FOMC behavior and rhetoric have
suggested to many observers that the Committee does have an implicit preferred range
for inflation. Most relevant here, the bottom of that preferred range clearly seems to be a
value greater than zero measured inflation, at least 1 percent per year or so. Both the
apparent tendency of measured inflation to overstate the true rate of price increase, as
suggested by a range of studies, and the need to provide some buffer against accidental
deflation serve as rationales for aiming for positive (as opposed to zero) measured
inflation, both in the short run and in the long run. To the extent that one accepts the
view that measured inflation should be kept some distance above zero, a very low
positive measured rate of inflation (say, 112 percent to 1 percent per year) is undesirable
and implies a need for highly accommodative monetary policy, just as would be required
for outright deflation. The language of the May 6 statement encompasses the risks of
both very low inflation and deflation. I suspect that for the foreseeable future, of the two,
the risk of very low but positive inflation is considerably the greater. That is, inflation in

-5the range of 112 percent per year in the United States in the next couple of years, though
relatively unlikely, is considerably more likely than deflation of 112 percent per year.
Having drawn a distinction between very low inflation and deflation, however, I
must also point out that, in terms of their costs to the economy, no sharp discontinuity
exists at the point that measured inflation changes from positive to negative values. Very
low inflation and deflation pose qualitatively similar economic problems, though the
magnitude of the associated costs can be expected to increase sharply as deflationary
pressures intensify.
What are these costs? In practice, the potential harm of very low inflation or
deflation depends importantly on the economic environment in which it occurs. For
example, deflation can be particularly harmful when the financial system is already
fragile, with household and corporate balance sheets in poor condition and with banks
undercapitalized and heavily burdened with nonperforming loans. Under such
circumstances, deflation or unexpectedly low inflation, by increasing the real burden of
debts, may exacerbate financial distress and cause further deterioration in the functioning
of the financial markets. This process of "debt deflation" (a term coined by the early
twentieth-century American economist Irving Fisher) was important in the U.S. deflation
and depression of the 1930s and may have played an important role in the economic
problems of contemporary Japan. Fortunately, financial conditions in the United States
today are sound, not fragile. Both households and firms have done excellent jobs during
the past few years of restructuring and rationalizing their balance sheets. For example,
households have taken advantage of low interest rates to refinance their mortgages, in the
process both lowering their monthly house payments and using accumulated equity to

- 6-

payoff more expensive forms of consumer debt, such as credit card debt. Likewise,
firms have lengthened the maturities of their debts, lowered their interest-to-earnings
ratios, and improved their liquidity. Completing the picture, the U.S. banking system is
highly profitable and well-capitalized and has managed credit risk over the latest cycle
exceptionally well. Thus, in my view, a deflation that was relatively limited in
magnitude and duration would be unlikely to have serious adverse effects on the U.S.
financial system.
A second set of circumstances in which deflation or very low inflation may pose
significant problems is potentially more relevant to the current U.S. economy. That
situation is one in which aggregate demand is insufficient to sustain strong growth, even
when the short-term real interest rate is zero or negative. Deflation (or very low
inflation) poses a potential problem when aggregate demand is insufficient because
deflation places a lower limit on the real short-term interest rate that can be engineered by
monetary policymakers. This limit is a consequence of the well-known zero-lowerbound constraint on nominal interest rates. For example, if prices are falling at a rate of 1
percent per year, the short-term real interest rate cannot be reduced below 1 percent, since
doing so would require setting the nominal interest rate below zero, which is impossible.
(Likewise, the very low inflation rate of 112 percent would prevent setting the real
interest rate lower than minus 112 percent.) Thus, in a situation of insufficient aggregate
demand, deflation or very low inflation might prevent the Fed from achieving full
employment, at least by means of the Fed's traditional policy tool of changing the shortterm nominal interest rate?

Even when the zero bound is not binding, a fall in the rate of inflation raises real interest rates,
thereby eroding the effects of any previous monetary easing.

2

-7In the worst-case scenario, one might worry that the interaction of deflation, the
short-term nominal interest rate, and aggregate demand could conceivably touch off a
destabilizing dynamic. Suppose that initially short-term nominal interest rates were
already near zero and prices were falling. If aggregate demand was sufficiently low
relative to potential supply, deflation might grow worse, as economic slack led to more
aggressive wage- and price-cutting. Because the short-term nominal interest rate cannot
be reduced further, worsening deflation would raise the real short-term interest rate,
effectively tightening monetary policy. The higher real interest rate might further reduce
aggregate demand, exacerbating the deflation and continuing the downward spiral. That,
at least, is the theoretical possibility. Fortunately, in practice, even if the Fed's ability to
influence aggregate demand was weakened by the interaction of worsening deflation and
the zero-bound constraint on nominal interest rates, other factors could serve to shortcircuit any incipient downward spiral. First, even in the presence of deflation, aggregate
demand can be raised by fiscal actions. Second, the link between excess capacity in the
economy and increased deflation, essential to this story, is not hard and fast. For
example, despite a decade of economic weakness in Japan, deflation there has remained
relatively stable at less than 1 percent per year; it has not worsened over time, as the
"deflationary spiral" scenario would imply. Third, if inflation expectations remain well
anchored, the real return expected by borrowers and lenders--equal to the nominal
interest rate less expected inflation--need not rise even as inflation declines. Finally, as I
have discussed in earlier talks and will allude to again today, the Fed's tools for
managing aggregate demand are not limited to control over the short-term nominal
interest rate, but include other channels as well.

- 8-

In any case, I hope we can agree that a substantial fall in inflation at this stage has

the potential to interfere with the ongoing U.S. recovery, and that in conceivable--though
remote--circumstances, a serious deflation could do significant economic harm. Thus,
avoiding a further substantial fall in inflation should be a priority of monetary policy. To
my mind, the central import of the May 6 statement is that the Fed stands ready and able
to resist further declines in inflation; and--if inflation does fall further--to ensure that the
decline does not impede the recovery in output and employment.
A Further Fall in Inflation: What is the Likelihood?
What, then, is the likelihood of a further, possibly substantial fall in inflation?
And, in particular, why worry about further disinflation when financial markets and
forecasters seem moderately optimistic about economic recovery in the United States?
As a starting point, we should note that underlying inflation has declined
noticeably in the past year or so. Let me cite a few numbers, focusing on core inflation
measures, which I remind you are defined to exclude the relatively more volatile food
and energy prices. According to numbers just released, inflation as measured by the core
consumer price index, or CPI, was 1.5 percent in the year ending June 2003, compared
with 2.3 percent in the year ending June 2002, a deceleration of 0.8 percentage points
over the year. Inflation as measured by the core personal consumption expenditure
(PCE) price index, a so-called chain-weight index that has the advantage of allowing for
shifting expenditure weights, also fell, though less dramatically, from 1.7 percent in the
year ending May 2002 to 1.2 percent in the year ending May 2003 (June data are not yet

- 9-

available), a fall of 0.5 percentage points.

3

These inflation rates, though declining (and

they have declined a bit more in the past six months), remain generally above the
1 percent "buffer zone," and it is always possible that their recent declines will prove to
be short-lived. Nevertheless, watchfulness is certainly warranted.
Where is inflation likely to go over the foreseeable future? Medium-term
inflation forecasting is highly contentious--not least because the underlying theory of the
determination of inflation continues to divide macroeconomic schools of thought--and I
cannot begin to do justice to the topic in a short talk. The Board staff, for example, uses
an eclectic approach that includes a number of components, including data analysis,
statistical techniques, a suite of econometric models, andjudgment.

4

However, much of

the analytic framework used by the staff and other leading forecasters can be summarized
by an expectations-augmented Phillips curve, of the type implied by the work of
Friedman (1968) and Phelps (1969), further augmented by measures of "supply shocks,"

3 Part of the reason that core PCE inflation fell less than CPI inflation is that the PCE index
includes so-called nonmarket prices--prices that are imputed by the Bureau of Economic Analysis
because reliable market data are not available--and nonmarket prices have been trending upward
lately. Indeed, the market-based portion of core PCE inflation for the year ending in May was
only 0.7 percent.
4 The success of the Board staff in forecasting inflation is well documented (Romer and Romer,
2000; Sims, 2002). Much of this success comes from intensive data analysis (including
computing projections of many components of the important price indexes, using a wide variety
of data and anecdotal information) that leads to highly accurate short-term inflation forecasting.
Since inflation tends to be inertial, "getting the initial conditions right" is important for mediumterm forecasting success (Sims, 2002).
Another important element of successful inflation forecasting, at the Board and
elsewhere, is the use of a wide range of information in forming the forecast. Cecchetti, Chu, and
Steindel (2000) show that single indicators, such as unemployment or the money supply, are
unlikely to be reliable forecasters of inflation. Purely statistical forecasting methods based on
multiple indicators have been developed by Stock and Watson (1999), among others. The
Chicago Fed National Activity Index, an index of eighty-five economic indicators, is based on the
Stock-Watson work and has been used to forecast both inflation and economic activity (Fisher,
2000; Evans, Liu, and Pham-Kanter, 2002).

- 10as suggested for example by the work of Robert Gordon (for a recent application, see
Gordon, 1998). This model is familiar from many textbook treatments. In addition, most
variants of the model include dynamic elements, in order to capture aspects of
expectations formation, multi-year contracts, and other factors. According to this class of
models, inflation in the intermediate term is affected primarily by four factors:
1. Economic slack. If aggregate demand is below potential output, implying a

positive output gap, the rate of increase in labor compensation and other input
costs should slow, firms should be less able to pass price increases, and thus
inflation should slow.
2. Inflation expectations. All else being equal, higher expected rates of inflation
will intensify pressure for increases in wages and other costs and thus raise
actual inflation. The objectives and performance of monetary policymakers
over the long run are key determinants of these expectations.
3. Supply shocks, such as changes in energy prices, food prices, or import
prices. Some supply shocks, such as shocks to import prices other than those
of food and energy, affect core inflation directly. Shocks to the prices of
energy or food may affect core inflation if they become embodied in inflation
expectations or if they boost core prices indirectly by raising the costs of
inputs in the production of non-energy, non-food goods and services.
4. Inflation persistence. Many economists have argued that inflation tends to be
persistent, or "sticky", perhaps for institutional reasons related to the process
of wage determination, supply contracts, and the like. Hence, current trends
in inflation can be expected to persist.

- 11 -

Of course, this model, like any model, will have an error term, which represents a
portion of the behavior of inflation that we can't reliably explain or predict. Historically,
the error terms of estimated inflation models have tended to be large relative to the
overall variability of inflation, implying that inflation is more difficult to forecast than we
would like. This difficulty of forecasting inflation has important implications, as we shall
see.
You may have noted that I did not include money growth in this list of inflation
determinants. Ultimately, inflation is a monetary phenomenon, as suggested by Milton
Friedman's famous dictum. However, no contradiction exists, as the expectational
Phillips curve is fully consistent with inflation's being determined by monetary forces in
the long run. This point, originally made by Friedman himself, has been demonstrated in
many textbooks and so I will not discuss it further here. I only note that, as an empirical
matter, instabilities in money demand, financial innovation, and many special factors
affecting the monetary aggregates make them relatively poor predictors of inflation at
medium-term horizons. For this reason, the role of the money supply remains implicit in
this discussion.
Within this framework for thinking about price dynamics, the factor most likely to
exert downward pressure on the future course of inflation in the United States is the
degree of economic slack that is currently prevailing and will likely continue for some
time yet. Although (according to the National Bureau of Economic Research) the U.S.
economy is technically in a recovery, job losses have remained significant this year, and
capacity utilization in the industrial sector (the only sector for which estimates are
available) is still low, suggesting that resource utilization for the economy as a whole is

- 12well below normal. By conventional analyses, therefore, even if the pace of real activity
picks up considerably this year and next, persistent slack might result in continuing
disinflation. 5
A highly simplified, though not quantitatively unreasonable, calculation may help.
Let us suppose that economic activity does pick up in the second half of this year, by
enough to bring real GDP growth in line with its long-run potential growth rate--roughly
3 percent or so, by conventional estimates. Moreover, suppose that activity strengthens
further next year so, so that real GDP growth climbs to approximately 4 percent, a full
percentage point above potential. What will happen to resource utilization and inflation?
Focusing first on the implications for economic slack, we note that this projected
path for real GDP gap would imply no change in the output gap through the end of this
year, followed by a percentage point reduction in the output gap during 2004. Given the
average historical relationship between the change in the output gap and labor market
conditions, known as Okun's Law, the unemployment rate would be expected to remain
at about its current level of 6.4 percent through the end of the year and then decline
gradually to about 6.0 percent by the end of next year. This projection is fairly close to
many private-sector forecasts.

Atkeson and Ohanian (2001) criticized the idea that measures of economic slack are useful for
forecasting inflation. They showed that, for the sample period 1984-99, three statistical models
that included measures of slack were no better on average at predicting inflation than the "naIve"
alternative of guessing that inflation next year would be the same as inflation this year. They
make a similar finding when comparing the naIve forecast to Board staff inflation forecasts
(which incorporate an economic slack concept). However, the Atkeson-Ohanian results, it turns
out, are dependent on their choice of sample period, a period that included only one relatively
moderate recession. Extending their sample period to include additional recessions (or, for that
matter, using alternative measures of inflation) tends to overturn their main results (see, for
example, Sims, 2002).
5

- 13 Let us turn now to the implications for inflation. From 1994 to 2002, core PCE
inflation remained in a stable range while the unemployment rate averaged about 5
percent; so let us suppose, for purposes of this example, that the unemployment rate at
which inflation is stable is 5 percent. (If the unemployment rate at which inflation is
stable is lower than 5 percent, the disinflation problem I am discussing becomes larger.)
A little arithmetic shows that this scenario involves 1.9 point-years of extra
unemployment (relative to the full-employment benchmark) between now and the end of
2004. Now make the additional assumption that the sacrifice ratio (the point-years of
unemployment required to reduce inflation by 1 point) is 4.0, a high value by historical
standards but one in the range of many current estimates. Then the additional disinflation
between now and the end of next year should be about 1.9 divided by 4, or about 0.5
percentage points. So given our assumptions about GDP growth, core PCE inflation, say,
might fall from 1.2 percent currently to 0.7 percent or so by the end of 2004.
The precise figures I have used in this exercise should be taken with more than a
few grains of salt. But the bottom line (which would not be much affected if we played
around with the numbers) is that, even if the economy recovers smartly for the rest of this
year and next, the ongoing slack in the economy may still lead to continuing disinflation.
So the FOMC's May 6 statement, by indicating both balanced risks to economic growth
(that is, a reasonable chance of a good recovery) and a downward risk to inflation, had no
internal inconsistency.
Now, further disinflation of half a percentage point in conjunction with a
significant strengthening of the real economy would not pose a significant problem. But
of course, the simple scenario I just outlined has risks. If the recovery is significantly

- 14weaker than we hope, for example, the greater level and persistence of economic slack
could intensify disinflationary pressures at an inopportune time. Another possibility,
given the uncertainty inherent in measures of potential output, is that the amount of
effective slack currently in the economy is greater than most analysts think--which, if
true, would help to explain the recent pace of disinflation.
There are good reasons not to discount this possibility. For example, during the
late 1990s, economists worked hard to explain the combination of an unusually low
unemployment rate and stable inflation--possible evidence of a decline in the economy's
sustainable unemployment rate. Factors that were thought to have contributed to a lower
sustainable rate of unemployment included the maturation of the labor force (Shimer,
1998); increased numbers of people on disability insurance (Autor and Duggan, 2002)
and increased rates of incarceration (Katz and Krueger, 1999), both of which tended to
remove less employable individuals from the labor force; improved matching between
workers and jobs, facilitated by increased access to the Internet and the rise of temporary
help agencies (Katz and Krueger, 1999); and perhaps other factors as well. Many of
these forces continue to operate in today's economy, conceivably with greater force than
in the late 1990s. 6 In addition, measured labor productivity has continued to increase
rapidly since early 200l--remarkably so, considering that productivity tends to be
strongly procyclical--raising the possibility that we have underestimated the degree to
which innovation and better use of existing resources have increased potential output. If

6 Some economists argued that the tendency of real wages to lag behind the unexpectedly strong
producti vity gains of the 1990s also reduced sustainable unemployment during that period (Ball
and Moffitt, 2001; see also Braun, 1984). To the extent this argument was valid, presumably this
factor is less relevant today, because productivity growth has moderated somewhat and has
probably become more fully incorporated into the wage determination process.

- 15 so, the true level of slack in the economy is higher than conventional estimates suggest,
implying that incipient disinflationary pressures may be more intense.
Of the various elements that make up the expectations-augmented Phillips curve,
the degree of economic slack is the one currently providing the greatest impetus for
further disinflation. By contrast, other elements of this conventional framework offer
somewhat more reason to hope that inflation will instead stabilize at current levels or fall
only slightly. In particular, as best we can tell, the public's inflation expectations have
not declined very much, particularly at longer horizons. For example, according to the
University of Michigan's Survey Research Center, the median respondent's expectation
of inflation over the next twelve months fell from 2.5 percent in January 2003 to 2.1
percent in June; however, the median expectation for inflation for the next five to ten
years was 2.7 percent in both January and June. 7 Inflation compensation at the five-year
horizon as measured by indexed government bonds has cycled up and down recently but
has averaged about 1.5 percent since early 2001. Interpretation of all these measures of
expected inflation is made more difficult by the fact that they are defined for total (as
opposed to core) CPI inflation and hence presumably are affected by fluctuations in
energy prices. Nevertheless, the evidence thus far does not support the view that there
has been a significant break in medium-term inflation expectations.
Supply shocks are another element of the modern Phillips curve framework. In
this category the most relevant current factor is probably the recent decline in the
exchange value of the dollar. For a various reasons, including the limited pass-through of
price increases by foreign producers and uncertainties about the future course of the

Preliminary July figures show a drop in the 12-month median inflation expectation to 1.7
percent. However the long-term inflation expectation edged up in July to 2.8 percent.

7

- 16 dollar, the dollar's fall is likely to have only a modest effect on the inflation rate; but any
effect it has should work against further disinflation. Overall, the stabilizing effects of
well-anchored inflation expectations and the slightly inflationary effect of the dollar
depreciation are two reasons to expect whatever disinflation takes place to be reasonably
gradual.
One more element of the model for inflation is important to mention: the error
term. At the upcoming August meeting, the Board staff, as it always does, will present
the FOMC with its forecasts for inflation. Based on historical experience (using actual
staff forecasts for 1985-97), the staff's forecast for CPI inflation for the full year 2003
(that is, the current year) will prove fairly accurate; the confidence interval for that
forecast, as measured by the root mean squared error, will be only 0.3 percentage points.
However, if history is a guide, the forecast the staff provides next month for CPI inflation
during 2004 will have a confidence interval of about 1.0 percentage points, a fairly wide
range. This amount of uncertainty is no reason to be defeatist about trying to forecast
inflation but it is a reason to be cautious. We are currently in a range where
undershooting our inflation objective by 1 percentage point is more costly than
overshooting by 1 percentage point. All else being equal, that fact should put us our
guard against unwanted further declines in inflation.
Implications for Monetary Policy
In summary, there appears to be some possibility that the recent trend toward
disinflation will continue, primarily because of the potentially large amount of economic
slack in the system. Stable expectations of inflation and the recent weakening of the

- 17 dollar may help to offset that tendency. In any case, we must keep in mind that the
uncertainty regarding our forecasts of inflation is significant.
What are the implications for monetary policy of these observations? First, as the
May 6 statement made clear, for the foreseeable future the risk of further declines in
inflation from an already low level outweighs the risk of a resurgence of inflation.
Hence, monetary ease appears to be indicated for a considerable period. Of course, an
extended period of ease dovetails well with the FOMC's objective of supporting a strong
and self-sustaining recovery in output and employment.
The form that this continued ease will take depends on developing conditions.
Keeping the federal funds rate target at or near its current level for an extended period
may be sufficient. Alternatively, as Chairman Greenspan testified last week, we could
certainly cut the rate from where it is now. In my view, though recognizing that such an
action imposes costs on savers and some financial institutions, we should be willing to
cut the funds rate to zero, should that prove necessary to provide the required support to
the economy.
Should the funds rate approach zero, the question will arise again about so-called
non-traditional monetary policy measures. I first discussed some of these measures in a
speech last November (Bernanke, 2002). Thanks in part to a great deal of fine work by
the staff, my understanding of these measures and my confidence in their success have
been greatly enhanced since I gave that speech. Without going into great detail, I see the
first stages of a "nontraditional" campaign as focused on lowering longer-term interest
rates. The two principal components of that campaign would be a commitment by the
FOMC to keep short-term yields at a very low level for an extended period (I'll say more

- 18 about this in a moment) together with a set of concrete measures to give weight to that
commitment. Such measures might include, among others, increased purchases of
longer-term government bonds by the Fed, an announced program of oversupplying bank
reserves, term lending through the discount window at very low rates, and the issuance of
options to borrow from the Fed at low rates. I am sure that the FOMC will release more
specific information if and when the need for such approaches appears to be closer on the
horizon.
I motivated today's talk by reference to the May 6 statement. Let me end the talk
by discussing the role of such statements in both traditional and non-traditional monetary
policy.
A crucial element of the statement was an implicit commitment about future
monetary policy; namely, a strong indication that, so long as a substantial fall in inflation
remains a risk, monetary policy will maintain an easy stance. Particularly at very low
inflation rates, a central bank's ability to make clear and credible commitments about
future policy actions--broadly, how it plans to adjust the short-term interest rate as
economic conditions change--is crucial for influencing longer-term interest rates and
other asset prices, which are themselves key transmission channels of monetary policy
(Eggertsson and Woodford, 2003). The question is, then, how can the Fed sharpen the
communication of its policy commitments? For example, how could the Fed be more
precise about how long it will maintain monetary ease or about the conditions under
which it would change its policy?
In my view--and here I am quite obviously speaking for myself--one useful

approach would be for the FOMC to provide the public with a quantitative, working

- 19 definition of price stability. The definition of price stability would be expressed as a
range of measured inflation, with the lower boundary of the range a safe distance from
zero.8
What I have in mind here is not a formal inflation target but rather a tool for
aiding communication. The main purpose of this quantification of price stability would
be to provide some guidance to the public and to financial markets as they try to forecast
FOMe behavior. In a situation like the current one, with inflation presumably near the
bottom of the acceptable range and trending down, and with considerable slack remaining
in the real economy, the Fed could make use of this quantitative guidepost to signal its
expectation that rates will be kept low for a protracted period, and indeed that they would
be reduced further if disinflation were not contained. If private-sector forecasts also
called for disinflation, confirming the downward risk to price stability, then medium-term
bond yields should accordingly be low, supporting the Fed's reflationary efforts.
In principle, one could communicate a similar message, though perhaps less
precisely, without a quantitative measure of price stability. What is missing from the
purely qualitative communication approach, however, is an exit strategy. At some point
in the future, if all goes well, inflation will stabilize, and interest rates will begin to rise.
The task of communicating the timing of that switch to markets with a minimum of
confusion and uncertainty is crucial and difficult. A quantitative measure of price
stability provides one objective basis that bond market participants could use to help
forecast the change in policy stance. For example, they would know that as disinflation

8 Ideally, the FOMe would specify the inflation range and price index only after careful staff
work to analyze the economy's operating characteristics under various alternatives. In particular,
in keeping with the Fed's dual mandate, both employment and inflation performance should be
analyzed.

- 20risk recedes and inflation forecasts begin to cluster in the middle to upper portions of the
price stability range, the Fed is quite likely to react. And, indeed, the forecasts of bond
market participants and the resulting rise in private yields will help to contain inflation,
doing some of the Fed's work for it.
In closing, for me the lesson of the May 6 statement was to underscore the vital

importance of central bank communication. In a world in which inflation risks are no
longer one-sided and short-term nominal interest rates are at historical lows, the success
of monetary policy depends more on how well the central bank communicates its plans
and objectives than on any other single factor.

- 21 -

REFERENCES
Atkeson, Andrew, and Lee Ohanian (2001). "Are Phillips Curves Useful for Forecasting
Inflation?", Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Quarterly Review, Winter, pp. 2-11.
Autor, David, and Mark Duggan (2002). "The Rise in Disability Rolls and the Decline in
Unemployment," Massachusetts Institute of Technology, working paper, March.
Ball, Laurence, and Robert Moffitt (2001). "Productivity Growth and the Phillips
Curve," in A. Krueger and R. Solow, eds., The Roaring Nineties: Can Full Employment
Be Sustained? New York: The Russell Sage Foundation and the Century Foundation
Press.
Bernanke, Ben S. (2002). "Deflation: Making Sure That 'It' Doesn't Happen Here,"
speech before the National Economics Club, Washington D.C., November 21. Available
at www.federalreserve.g:ov.
Braun, Steven (1984). "Productivity and the NAIRU (and other Phillips Curve Issues),"
Economic Activity Section Working Paper no. 34, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.
Cecchetti, Stephen, Rita Chu, and Charles Steindel (2000). "The Unreliability of
Inflation Indicators," Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Current Issues in Economics
and Finance, 6, April, pp. 1-6.
Eggertsson, Gauti, and Michael Woodford (2003). "The Zero Bound on Interest Rates
and Optimal Monetary Policy," International Monetary Fund and Princeton University,
working paper.
Evans, Charles, Chin Te Liu, and Genevieve Pham-Kanter (2002). "The 2001 Recession
and the Chicago Fed National Activity Index: Identifying Business Cycle Turning
Points," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Economic Per5pectives, Third Quarter, pp.
26-43.
Fisher, Jonas (2000). "Forecasting Inflation with a Lot of Data," Federal Reserve Bank
of Chicago, Chicago Fed Letter, March.
Friedman, Milton (1968). "The Role of Monetary Policy," American Economic Review,
58, March, pp. 1-17.
Gordon, Robert J. (1998). "Foundations of the Goldilocks Economy: Supply Shocks and
the Time-Varying NAIRU," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, pp. 297-346.

- 22Katz, Lawrence, and Alan Krueger (1999), "The High-Pressure U.S. Labor Market of the
1990s," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, pp. 1-87.
Phelps, Edmund (1969). "The New Microeconomics in Inflation and Employment
Theory," American Economic Review, 59, May, pp. 147-60.
Romer, Christina, and David Romer (2000). "Federal Reserve Information and the
Behavior of Interest Rates," American Economic Review, 90, pp. 429-57.
Shimer, Robert (1998). "Why is the U.S. Unemployment Rate So Much Lower?" in B.
Bemanke and J. Rotemberg, eds., NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Cambridge, Mass.:
MIT Press.
Sims, Christopher (2002). "The Role of Models and Probabilities in the Monetary Policy
Process," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, pp. 1-40.
Stock, James, and Mark Watson (1999). "Forecasting Inflation," Journal of Monetary
Economics, 44, October, pp. 293-335.