View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:15 p.m. EDT (12:15 p.m. CDT)
April 15, 2004

What Policymakers Can Learn from Asset Prices

Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Member
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
The Investment Analyst Society of Chicago
Chicago, Illinois
April 15,2004

Central bankers naturally pay close attention to interest rates and asset prices, in
large part because these variables are the principal conduits through which monetary
policy affects real activity and inflation. But policymakers watch financial markets
carefully for another reason, which is that asset prices and yields are potentially valuable
sources of timely information about economic and financial conditions. Because the
future returns on most financial assets depend sensitively on economic conditions, asset
prices--if determined in sufficiently liquid markets--should embody a great deal of
investors' collective information and beliefs about the future course of the economy.
I thought you might find it interesting to hear a bit about how the staff of the
Federal Reserve uses financial-market information to try to improve forecasts and help
guide policy decisions. As you will see, asset prices provide information, particularly
about market expectations, that is difficult to obtain elsewhere. However, a recurring
theme of my remarks will be that extracting accurate information from asset prices and
yields is more difficult and requires greater sophistication than is commonly supposed.
Ongoing research in financial economics thus has great potential to provide practical
assistance to monetary policy makers.
As usual, the views I will express today are not necessarily those of my
colleagues in the Federal Reserve System.!
Market Expectations of Inflation: The Information in Inflation-Indexed Securities
I will begin by discussing what financial markets can tell us about inflation
expectations. The inflation expectations of financial-market participants are of particular
interest to central bankers, for several reasons. First, as price stability is a key

-2-

objective of monetary policy, the Federal Reserve puts substantial resources into
forecasting inflation. To the extent that financial markets serve to aggregate
private-sector information about the likely future course of inflation, data on asset prices
and yields might be used to validate and perhaps improve the Fed's forecasts. Second,
inflation expectations are of interest to policymakers independent of inflation itself. A
considerable literature suggests that successful monetary policies should stabilize, or
"anchor," inflation expectations so as to prevent them from becoming a source of
instability in their own right (Goodfriend, 1993; Evans and Honkapohja, 2003). Finally,
knowledge of the expectations of inflation in financial markets permits the calculation of
real interest rates, which are important indicators of both the condition of the economy
and the stance of monetary policy.
Although clues about inflation expectations abound in financial markets,
inflation-indexed securities would appear to be the most direct source of information
about inflation expectations and real interest rates. 2 Government securities whose
realized yields depend on inflation, known on the Street as "linkers," have become
increasingly common in industrial countries, Japan being the latest nation to introduce an
inflation-indexed government bond. The U.S. Treasury began issuing TIIS (for Treasury
inflation-indexed securities), more popularly known as TIPS (for Treasury
inflation-protected securities), in January 1997. TIPS promise a yield-to-maturity that is
guaranteed in real terms. To provide the promised real yield, TIPS coupon and principal
payments are escalated based on increases in the consumer price index from the time at
which the security was issued.

-3-

The difference between the real yield guaranteed by an inflation-linked security
and the nominal yield provided by a conventional security of the same maturity is known
as the breakeven inflation rate or, alternatively, as inflation compensation. The top panel
of Figure 1 shows the yield on nominal ten-year Treasury bonds (top line) and the real
yield on ten-year TIPS since 1999 (bottom line). The vertical distance between the two
lines is known as breakeven inflation at the ten-year horizon. The bottom panel uses
overlapping issues of nominal securities and TIPS to disaggregate breakeven inflation
into the rate that applies to bonds maturing five years from now and the implied forward
breakeven rate from five to ten years out. The breakeven rate of inflation is often treated
as a direct reading of investors' expectations of inflation. Under this interpretation, the
lower line in the bottom panel of Figure 1 is an estimate of market inflation expectations
over the next five years, and the upper line represents five-year forward expectations of
inflation, that is, today's expectation of what average inflation will be between 2009 and
2014.
Unfortunately, as a measure of market participants' expected inflation, breakeven
inflation has a number of problems (Sack, 2000; Shen and Coming, 2001). First, and
probably the most important, breakeven inflation includes a return to investors for
bearing inflation risk, implying that the breakeven rate likely overstates the market's
expected rate of inflation. Estimates of the inflation risk premium for bonds maturing
during the next five to ten years are surprisingly large, generally in a range between 35
and 100 basis points, depending on the time period studied (Ang and Bekaert, 2003; Goto
and Torous, 2003; Buraschi and Jiltsov, 2004). If the inflation risk premium averages 50

-4-

basis points, for example, then breakeven inflation will overstate the market's true
expectation of inflation by half a percentage point, a substantial amount. A further
complication is that inflation risk premiums are not constant but instead appear to vary
over time as economic circumstances change.
Second, although the issuance of inflation-protected securities has risen
significantly, the outstanding quantities of these securities remain much smaller than
those of conventional Treasury securities. Moreover, TIPS are attractive to buy-and-hold
investors, in contrast to nominal Treasury securities, which are extensively used for
trading and hedging (Sack and Elsasser, 2004). For both reasons, the market for TIPS
remains significantly less liquid than those for most Treasury securities. All else equal,
the likely presence of a liquidity premium in the TIPS return tends to make breakeven
inflation an underestimate of expected inflation, thus offsetting to some degree the effect
of the inflation risk premium. 3 Like inflation risk premiums, liquidity premiums on TIPS
appear to vary over time, further complicating the interpretation of breakeven inflation.
A third issue is that the real values of the coupon payments on an indexed security
are fixed by construction, while the real coupons of a nominal bond usually decline over
its life. Hence, an indexed security typically has a longer duration with respect to real
interest rate changes than does the nominal security, a difference that affects the relative

-5-

riskiness of real and nominal securities. 4 More generally, because TIPS returns are
imperfectly correlated with the yields on both nominal Treasuries and stocks, some
investors demand TIPS for general diversification purposes--a demand that appears to
have increased significantly as investors have become more familiar with this new type
of asset. As the supply of TIPS has been fairly limited, the rise in demand by
institutional investors and others may push down the equilibrium real return on TIPS and
thus raise measures of breakeven inflation.5
A separate issue that bears on the relevance of breakeven inflation for
policymaking is that TIPS returns depend on the overall consumer price index (Cpr),
whereas for many purposes policymakers are more interested in the behavior of core
inflation, a measure of inflation that strips out volatile food and energy prices. In fact,
TIPS returns appear sensitive to fluctuations in oil prices.
As you can see in Figure I, break even inflation rates have proven surprisingly
volatile over their short history. For example, when nominal Treasury yields swung
sharply during the spring and summer of 2003, ten-year breakeven inflation moved

sharply as well, declining about 40 basis points as the bond market rallied, then rising
about 80 basis points when nominal yields came back up (top panel). This effect was
seen also in inflation compensation at the five-to-ten-year horizon (bottom panel), a
rather counterintuitive result.
What should we make of the volatility of breakeven inflation over recent years?
One interpretation is that inflation expectations are not as well anchored as policymakers
would like (see Bemanke, 2004, for additional evidence on this point). The fact that

-6-

inflation compensation tends to react strongly both to releases of macroeconomic data
and to unexpected changes in monetary policy (Gurkaynak, Sack, and Swanson, 2003)
supports this interpretation.
Still, at this point I think we need to be cautious about drawing strong conclusions
about the short-run behavior of expected inflation from the data on breakeven inflation.
The fact that the volatility of breakeven inflation is so much greater than that of standard
survey measures of inflation expectations (such as those collected by the Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia for professional forecasters or by the University of Michigan for
consumers) should give us pause. The responsiveness of breakeven inflation to what
might be construed primarily as liquidity disturbances, such as the Russian debt crisis and
recent bouts of mortgage hedging activity that roiled Treasury markets, suggests that
variable liquidity premiums, together with varying inflation risk premiums, contaminate
breakeven inflation as a measure of expected inflation. 6
I have emphasized some reasons to be cautious in interpreting breakeven inflation
as expected inflation. Nevertheless, I expect that the usefulness of inflation-indexed
securities as a tool for measuring expected inflation will increase over time. The liquidity
of TIPS should continue to improve as the share of government debt issued in
inflation-linked form continues to rise, particularly if the Treasury decides to expand the
range of maturities of indexed bonds that it offers. Moreover, as I will discuss briefly
later in the talk, our ability to model risk and liquidity premiums is improving, which will
help us control for an important source of volatility in breakeven inflation. Finally, the
universe of inflation-linked financial assets seems to be increasing, which will allow for

-7-

fruitful comparisons and cross-checking. For example, futures on the

cpr were recently

introduced on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange. Although these contracts are not yet
widely traded, they may at some point provide useful measures of break even inflation out
to the maturity of the shortest-term TIPS, thereby filling in an important portion of the
term structure of breakeven inflation.

Interest Rates and Spreads as Leading Indicators
An alternative approach to extracting information from financial markets is to
examine a range of asset prices and yields to determine whether they are useful as leading
indicators of economic developments. Financial prices meet several key criteria for
being useful leading indicators. As I already noted, asset prices and yields are inherently
forward looking and thus may contain information about future economic conditions not
evident in other series. Moreover, asset prices, unlike many data series, are available on
a timely and continuous basis and are not revised. At least since the 1930s, when Wesley
Mitchell and Arthur Bums (1938) published their pioneering work, economists have
noted the usefulness of asset prices in forecasting economic activity--though perhaps we
should keep in mind Paul Samuelson's wry observation that "the stock market has
predicted nine ofthe last five recessions."
Although many financial quantities have been used in forecasting (an index of
stock prices is included in the official index ofleading indicators), interest rates on
various financial instruments have perhaps been most often cited for their value as
leading indicators'? For example, in a 1992 paper, Alan Blinder and r found evidence
that the federal funds rate, the short-term interest rate used by the Federal Reserve as its

-8-

policy instrument, has significant predictive power for a variety of measures of economic
activity.
Various yield spreads have also been found to be informative about the future
course of the economy. In 1989, James Stock and Mark Watson proposed a new index of
leading indicators based on seven variables with exceptionally good forecasting track
records up to that date. Among these variables were the spread between the ten-year and
one-year Treasury yields (the term spread), the yield differential between commercial
paper and Treasury bills (the public-private spread), the change in the ten-year Treasury
yields, and the nominal exchange rate. 8 Thus, Stock and Watson found that two of the
best seven macroeconomic forecasting variables were interest rate spreads, and four of
the best seven forecasters were financial in nature.
Of these variables, the term spread (also known as the slope of the yield curve)
had been recognized for some time as a useful indicator of cyclical conditions. Figure 2
shows the historical behavior of the term spread (top panel, here measured as the ten-year
rate less the three-month rate), as well as that of the federal funds rate and the spread
between commercial paper and three-month T -bill yields for comparison. The shaded
areas indicate periods of recession as designated by the National Bureau of Economic
Research. It is interesting that the slope of the Treasury yield curve has turned negative
(top panel), at least briefly, at between two and six quarters before every u.s. recession
since 1964 (Ang, Piazzesi, and Wei, 2003). It has given only one false signal, in 1966,
when an economic slowdown--but not an official recession--followed the inversion of the
yield curve. The slope ofthe yield curve is potentially informative for several reasons.

-9-

To some extent, it captures the stance of monetary policy. For example, when the yield
curve is sharply upward sloping, as is the case today, one can usually conclude that
monetary policy is in an expansionary mode (because the short-term policy rate lies
below the average of expected future short-term rates). Either an expected pickup in
economic growth or higher expected future inflation would also tend to raise long-term
rates relative to short rates, steepening the yield curve. Evidence for the predictive power
of the slope of the yield curve has been found for other industrialized countries as well as
for the United States. 9
Although the evident information content of the term spread and other yields and
spreads is intriguing, these variables--like breakeven inflation--hardly provide a foolproof
forecasting tool. For example, the Stock-Watson indicator and other indicators based on
interest rates and spreads signaled the 1990-91 recession very weakly and rather late.
The yield curve was inverted from June 2000 through March 2001, which presaged the
2001 recession, but other financial indicators (such as the public-private spread) missed
the downturn entirely (Stock and Watson, 2003a), as you can see in Figure 2. More
generally, Stock and Watson (2003b) have recently documented that simple forecasting
relationships are typically quite unstable, presumably because both the nation's economic
structure, the conduct of policy, and the mix of shocks that buffet the economy change
over time.
Although the use of financial data as leading indicators is not without risks, I
suspect that economists will continue to try to find better ways to extract the information
in these data. I see two general approaches as being especially promising. First,

- 10-

forecasting relationships that simultaneously use information from a large number of data
series may be more robust than prediction equations based on only a few variables (Stock
and Watson, 2003b). One effective way to summarize the information in large data sets
is through the estimation of statistical models that extract the common information
conveyed by many variables. 10 Currently, the U.S. Treasury uses a model of this type in
preparing its forecasts of gross domestic product (GDP), and the Chicago Fed's national
activity index, which draws on earlier work by Stock and Watson, is also based on these
methods. The Board staff is currently investigating the potential of this approach for
forecasting the economy.
The other promising approach is to combine financial and macroeconomic
information in a more structured way. For example, Ang, Piazzesi, and Wei (2003) have
used modem financial theory to construct a model of the Treasury yield curve that
closely links the behavior of real GDP and a few key interest rates. In particular, their
framework incorporates the possibility of two-way causality, allowing for both
interest-rate effects on the economy and the impact of economic developments on interest
rates. These authors show that combining financial and macroeconomic elements in a
single model permits better forecasts of both GDP and of interest rates than can be
achieved through less formal methods. 11 Other work, for example by Ang and Bekaert
(2003), shows how modeling the links between interest rates and the economy may help
us obtain more efficient forecasts of inflation. These methods are also being studied at
the Federal Reserve Board.
One important advantage of this theory-based modeling approach is that it permits

- 11 -

the estimation of risk premiums. For example, presumably the predictive power of the
term spread would be enhanced if we could separate changes in the spread resulting from
changes in rate expectations from those arising from changes in risk premiums.
Similarly, better estimates of inflation risk premiums would prove useful for adjusting
breakeven inflation rates from TIPS to get more reliable measures of expected inflation.

Market Expectations of Monetary Policy
What do markets expect about the future course of monetary policy? The
question is important to policymakers, not because we are concerned necessarily that we
should meet the market's expectations--such a strategy quickly degenerates into a hall of
mirrors--but as a check on the efficacy of our communication. If the policy expectations
of the market differ significantly from the policy expectations of central bankers, then the
two leading possibilities are, first, that the policy committee has not accurately
communicated its outlook and objectives or, second, that the market hears the policy
committee's message but is skeptical of it.
A number of financial instruments provide readings on the market's policy
expectations. Two of the most useful are federal funds futures contracts and eurodollar
futures contracts. These contracts are traded in highly liquid markets. 12 Moreover, by
their nature they are closely tied to expectations of monetary policy changes, as both
reflect rates paid in the interbank market, the market that is targeted by the Federal
Reserve's open-market operations. 13
Implied forward values of short-term interest rates at various horizons can be
extracted from federal funds and eurodollar futures contract prices in a straightforward

- 12 -

way. Figure 3 provides an illustration. The lower, dashed line shows the path of the
expected federal funds rate through 2008 as implied by federal funds and eurodollar
futures at the close of the market on April 1, 2004, with an adjustment for the average
level of term premiums. The upper, solid line shows the path of expected funds rates as
of the market close on the next day, April 2. As you probably know, the payroll
employment numbers announced on April 2 significantly exceeded market expectations.
Figure 3 shows that the payroll data seems to have caused the market to price in an
expectation of a higher federal funds rate target over the entire policy horizon. Of
course, that change in policy expectations is consistent with the significant rise in
Treasury yields that occurred after the employment report.
Observing market expectations of policy provides useful feedback to the
policymakers. Yet again, however, caution is needed in interpreting these data. As with
inflation-indexed securities, forward interest rates implied by futures contracts do not
necessarily correspond to market expectations of the short-term rate, because of the
presence of premiums for interest-rate risk. 14 Indeed, research suggests that risk
premiums in federal funds and eurodollar futures contracts are not trivial and may vary
over time. For example, a study by Piazzesi and Swanson (2004) has found that risk
premiums on federal funds futures are both strongly countercyclical and predictable at
longer horizons. The implication is that, although futures prices provide good estimates
of market expectations of policy at short horizons of six months or so, at longer horizons
they can be misleading. In particular, Piazzesi and Swanson (2004) find that if analysts
ignore risk premiums in federal funds and eurodollar futures, they will estimate

- 13 -

longer-horizon policy expectations that "lag behind" actual market expectations,
remaining too high when the Fed is easing and too low when the Fed is tightening. 15
Fortunately, this research also shows how to correct the futures data to account for the
time variation in risk premiums. Once again, we see that some subtlety is required to
extract the information available in asset prices.
A great advantage of market-based measures of policy expectations, relative to
periodic surveys that ask market participants about their expectations, is that market
measures are available essentially continuously. 16 These measures thus lend themselves
to "event studies" of two types, both of which are employed at the Board of Governors.
The first type analyzes how various events, such as Federal Reserve statements; the
release of minutes, testimony, or speeches by members ofthe Federal Open Market
Committee (FOMC); and macroeconomic news affect market expectations of monetary
policy. One simply compares the implied policy expectations before and after the event
being studied. We have already considered an example, the effects of the most recent
payroll report, in Figure 3. Analyses of this type provide insights for policymakers into
the question of what economic factors the "market," viewed collectively, is focusing on
at a given time.

- 14 -

The second type of event study uses market-based measures of policy
expectations to analyze the effects of policy changes on the economy. In particular,
when
the FOMe chooses to set the target for the federal funds rate at a value different from that
expected by the market, asset prices tend to react strongly. For example, in a recent
paper, Kenneth Kuttner and I (2004) studied the effects on stock prices of unanticipated
changes in monetary policy, as measured by settings of the federal funds rate target that
differ from those implied by federal funds futures market. We found that a surprise
increase of 25 basis points in the funds rate target typically results in a decline in broad
equity indexes of about 1 percent, whereas a change in the funds rate that is expected by
the market has essentially no effect on stock prices. 17 Our work is just one example of a
number of event-study analyses that may well shed light on the effects of monetary
policy and the channels of monetary policy transmission.
Policymakers are concerned not only about market expectations of output,
inflation, interest rates, and other key variables, but also about the extent of market
uncertainty about those and other variables. Financial data provide insight about market
uncertainty that is obtainable nowhere else. For example, the Board's staff regularly
analyzes the prices of options on eurodollar futures to estimate the degree of uncertainty
that market participants have about monetary policy at different horizons. Indeed, by
examining options with different strike prices, and under some reasonable additional
assumptions, one can produce a full probability distribution of market expectations for
the level of the federal funds rate at various dates in the future. Likewise, analysis of

- 15 -

various types of options can generate distributions of expectations for economic and
financial variables ranging from oil prices to the exchange value of the dollar to future
stock prices. IS
Conclusion
Financial markets aggregate enormous amounts of information and thus provide a
rich hunting ground for central bankers trying to learn about the economy. Today I have
tried to provide a small taste of the many types of financial data that are analyzed by the
staff at the Federal Reserve as well as to give you some sense of the techniques that they
bring to bear. A message that I also hope to leave with you is that some of the potentially
most valuable information in financial markets often requires considerable theoretical
and empirical sophistication to extract. For this reason, and as I mentioned at the
beginning, financial research of the type being conducted at the Board, in academia, and
in the investment community will prove invaluable to the Federal Reserve in our efforts
to support a stronger and more stable economy.

- 16-

- 17 -

Figure 1

Yields on Ten-Year TIPS and on Nominal Ten-Year Treasury Notes

Percent

8

L-~

________

~~

________- L__________

2000

1999

~

__________

~

________

2002

2001

~

____

~

0

2003

Inflation Compensation

Percent
4

Five- to ten-year horizon
"l

U.

.~ ~

~ I~A J ~ \., I: ~:r.t'''4f~
~ , r '1\ .' ..
's,
~~,.
..,~

f\

; ~\ A ,
:r'i
"iN'!'
~ 'if
~i\

3

I
l

.....~
2

L-~

________

1999

~~

________

2000

~

__________

2001

~

__________

2002

~

________

2003

~

____

~

0

- 18 -

- 19 -

Figure 2

Treasury Term Spread: Ten-Year Note less Three-Month Bill

Percent

5

4
3

2

o
-1
-2

~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~

1960

1964

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

-3
-4

2004

Note. In each panel, shaded bars are periods of recession as determined by the
National Bureau of Economic Research.

Federal Funds Rate

Percent

20

15

10

5

o
1960

1964

1968

1972

1976

1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

2000

Public-Private Spread: Commercial Paper less Treasury Bill*

2004

Percent

5

~~

,
I

4

k1}

3
2

o
1971

1974

1977

'Three-month securities.

1980

1983

1986

1989

1992

1995

1998

2001

2004

- 20-

Figure 3

Expected Federal Funds Rate
Percent
4.5
4.0

..
.. ' .. '

'

3.5

...............

3.0
2.5

....
....

April 1, 2004

2.0

1.5
1.0

Apr.

Aug.
Apr.
Aug.
Dec.
Apr.
Aug.
Dec.
Apr.
Aug.
Dec.
2004
2007
2005
2006
Note. Estimates are from federal funds futures and Eurodollar futures, with an allowance for
term premia and other adjustments.

Dec.
2008

- 21 -

References
Ang, Andrew, and Geert Bekaert (2003). "The Tenn Structure of Real Interest Rates and
Expected Inflation," Columbia Business School, working paper (September).

Ang, Andrew, and Monika Piazzesi (2003). "A No-Arbitrage Vector Autoregression of
Tenn Structure Dynamics with Macroeconomic and Latent Variables," Journal of
Monetary Economics, 50 (December), pp. 745-87.
Ang, Andrew, Monika Piazzesi, and Min Wei (2003). "What Does the Yield Curve Tell
Us About GDP Growth?" Columbia Business School and the University of Chicago,
working paper (October).
Bernanke, Ben (2004). "Fedspeak," At the meetings ofthe American Economic
Association, San Diego, California, January 3. Available at www.federalreserve.gov.
Bernanke, Ben, and Alan Blinder (1992). "The Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of
Monetary Transmission," American Economic Review, 82 (September), pp. 901-21.
Bernanke, Ben, and Jean Boivin (2003). "Monetary Policy in a Data-Rich Environment,"
Journal of Monetary Economics, 50 (April), pp. 525-46.
Bernanke, Ben, and Kenneth Kuttner (2004). "Why Does Monetary Policy Affect the
Stock Market?" Journal of Finance (forthcoming).
Buraschi, Andrea, and Alexei Jiltsov (2004). "Time-Varying Inflation Risk Premia and
the Expectations Hypothesis: A Monetary Model of the Treasury Yield Curve," Journal
of Financial Economics (forthcoming).
Craig, Ben, and Joseph Haubrich (2003). "Pricing Kernels, Inflation, and the Tenn
Structure of Interest Rates," Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Working Paper 03-08
(September).
Diebold, Francis, Glenn Rudebusch, and S. Boragan Aruoba (2003). "The
Macroeconomy and the Yield Curve: A Nonstructural Analysis," University of
Pennsylvania and Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, working paper (October).
Estrella, Arturo and Frederic Mishkin (1997). "The Predictive Power of the Tenn
Structure of Interest Rates in Europe and the United States: Implications for the European
Central Bank," European Economic Review, 41, pp. 1375-401.
Evans, George, and Seppo Honkapohja (2003). "Expectations and the Stability Problem
for Optimal Monetary Policies," Review of Economics Studies (forthcoming).
Forni, Mario, Marc Hallin, Marco Lippi, and Lucrezia Reichlin (2000). "The

- 22 -

Generalized Dynamic Factor Model: Identification and Estimation," Review of
Economics and Statistics, 82 (November), pp. 540-54.
Friedman, Benjamin, and Kenneth Kuttner (1993). "Why Does the Paper-Bill Spread
Predict Real Economic Activity?" in James Stock and Mark Watson, eds., Business
Cycles, Indicators, and Forecasting. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Goodfriend, Marvin (1993). "Interest Rate Policy and the Inflation Scare Problem,
1979-1992," Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic Quarterly, 1 (Winter), pp.
1-23.
Goto, Shingo, and Walter Torous (2003). "The Conquest of U.S. Inflation: Its
Implications for the Fisher Hypothesis and the Term Structure of Nominal Interest
Rates," University of South Carolina and UCLA, working paper (November).
Gurkaynak, Refet, Brian Sack, and Eric Swanson (2002). "Market-Based Measures of
Monetary Policy Expectations," Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2002-40 (September).
Gurkaynak, Refet, Brian Sack, and Eric Swanson (2003). "The Excess Sensitivity of
Long-term Interest Rates: Evidence and Implications for Macroeconomic Models,"
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance and Economics Discussion
Series 2003-50 (November).
Gurkaynak, Refet, Brian Sack, and Eric Swanson (2004). "The Effect of Monetary
Policy on Asset Prices: An Intraday Event-Study Analysis," Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, working paper (February).
Hordahl, Peter, Oreste Tristiani, and David Vestin (2002). "A Joint Econometric Model
of Macroeconomic and Term Structure Dynamics," European Central Bank, working
paper (February).
Kozicki, Sharon (1997). "Predicting Real Growth and Inflation with the Yield Spread,"
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Economic Review (82), pp. 39-57.
Kozicki, Sharon, and Peter Tinsley (2001). "Shifting Endpoints in the Term Structure of
Interest Rates," Journal of Monetary Economics, 47 (June), pp. 613-52.
Mitchell, Wesley, and Arthur Bums (1938). Statistical Indicators of Cyclical Revivals,
NBER Bulletin 69, New York. Reprinted in Business Cycle Indicators, Geoffrey Moore,
ed., Princeton, N. 1.: Princeton University Press, 1961.
PerIi, Roberto, and Brian Sack (2003). "Does Mortgage Hedging Amplify Movements in
Long-Term Interest Rates?" Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance
and Economics Discussion Series 2003-49 (September).

- 23 -

Piazessi, Monika, and Eric Swanson (2004). "Futures Prices as Risk-Adjusted Forecasts
of Monetary Policy," University of Chicago and Board of Governors ofthe Federal
Reserve System, working paper (March).
Roll, Richard (2004). "Empirical TIPS," Financial Analysts Journal, 60 (January), pp.
31-53.
Rudebusch, Glenn, and Tao Wu (2003). "A Macro-Finance Model of the Term
Structure, Monetary Policy, and the Economy," Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco,
working paper (October).
Sack, Brian (2000). "Deriving Inflation Expectations from Nominal and
Inflation-Indexed Treasury Yields," Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2000-33 (May).
Sack, Brian (2004). "Extracting the Expected Path of Monetary Policy from Futures
Rates," Journal ofFinancial Markets (forthcoming).
Sack, Brian, and Robert Elsasser (2004). "Treasury Inflation-Indexed Debt: A Review of
the U.S. Experience," Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Economic Review
(forthcoming).
Shen, Pu, and Jonathan Coming (2001). "Can TIPS Help Identify Long-Term Inflation
Expectations?" Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Economic Review (Fourth
Quarter), pp. 61-87.
Stock, James, and Mark Watson (1989). "New Indexes of Coincident and Leading
Economic Indicators," in Olivier Blanchard and Stanley Fischer, eds., NBER
Macroeconomics Annual. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 352-94.
Stock, James, and Mark Watson (1999). "Forecasting Inflation," Journal of Monetary
Economics, 44 (October), pp. 293-335.
Stock, James, and Mark Watson (2003a). "How Did Leading Indicator Forecasts
Perform During the 2001 Recession?" Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic
Quarterly, 89 (Summer), pp. 71-90.
Stock, James, and Mark Watson (2003b). "Forecasting Output and Inflation: The Role of
Asset Prices," Journal of Economic Literature, 61 (September), pp. 788-829.

- 24-

lThanks are due to James Clouse and Brian Sack for superb assistance.
2Indeed, their potential usefulness in this respect was an explicit motivation for their
introduction in the United States.
3As a partial fix ofthis problem, the break even inflation rates shown in Figure 1 are
calculated by comparing the yields of TIPS and so-called off-the-run securities. Within a
given class of securities, say Treasury bonds with ten years until maturity, off-the-run
securities are securities other than those most recently issued. Because off-the-run
securities are less liquid than newly issued (on-the-run) securities, they provide a more
appropriate benchmark against which to compare the yields of relatively illiquid
inflation-indexed bonds.
4As Sack (2000) has pointed out, this difference in duration implies that the breakeven
inflation rate may be sensitive to the expected profile of future short real rates or be
affected by differences in risk premiums arising from different exposure to interest-rate
risk. Sack addressed the issue of differing durations of nominal securities and TIPS by
comparing yields on TIPS to yields on artificial securities constructed to provide the
same pattern of real payments as a TIPS security, thereby eliminating the differences in
duration noted in the text. He found, however, that the duration mismatch is less
important quantitatively than differences in liquidity between on-the-run nominal
securities and TIPS.
5 A number of technical issues, such as the lags in the inflation adjustment procedure,
affect the relationship of breakeven inflation and expected inflation. One such potential
complication arises if the tax rates applicable to the marginal TIPS investor and to the
marginal holder of nominal government securities are not the same, in which case the
equilibrium breakeven inflation level will be affected. Roll (2004) discusses the effects
of taxation on the breakeven inflation rate.
6Indeed, Shen and Coming (2001) note that breakeven inflation is correlated with other
measures ofliquidity premiums, such as the spread between on-the-run and off-the-run
securities. Perli and Sack (2003) discuss the volatility in Treasury bond markets
associated with mortgage hedging activity.
7Stock and Watson (2003b) provide an exhaustive survey of the literature on the
predictive power of asset prices for output and inflation. Parts of my discussion in this
section draw from their paper.
8Friedman and Kuttner (1993) independently recognized the rather remarkable
forecasting record of the pUblic-private spread.
9For example, Estrella and Mishkin (1997) studied the predictive value of the term
premium using data from France, Germany, Italy, the United Kingdom, and the United
States. Estrella and Mishkin found that the slope of the yield curve is useful for
predicting growth at about a six-quarter horizon, with the link being somewhat stronger
in the United States than in Europe. They also found that the slope of the yield curve
helps to predict inflation (as measured by the GDP deflator), but at much longer horizons
of about five years. Also using international data, Kozicki (1997) found that the term
spread is a good short-run forecaster of output, but that the level of yields is a more
useful predictor of inflation.
lOIn other work, Stock and Watson (1999) have shown that these so-called factor models
can provide superior and more robust forecasts than methods based on only a few

- 25 -

variables. Forni, Hallin, Lippi, and Reichlin (2000) and Bernanke and Boivin (2003)
have obtained related results.
l1Kozicki and Tinsley (2001), Hordahl, Tristani, and Vestin (2002), Aug and Piazzesi
(2003), Craig and Haubrich (2003), Diebold, Rudebusch, and Aruoba (2003), and
Rudebusch and Wu (2003) are among the many interesting papers in the recent
"macro-finance" literature on the term structure.
12The volume of federal fund futures contracts traded has grown about sixfold in the past
four years, to about 8.3 million contracts 2003.
J3Gurkaynak, Sack, and Swanson (2002) examined the predictive power of federal funds
and eurodollar futures contracts for settings of the federal funds rate target and found that
in this respect they outperform other financial instruments. Specifically, they found that
the federal funds futures contract dominates alternative instruments for forecasting the
funds rate out to a horizon of several months, while eurodollar futures do slightly better
than alternative instruments at longer horizons.
14Liquidity premiums are less of an issue for these markets.
lsSack (2004) also allows for time-varying risk premiums, making the assumption that the
risk premium is related to the slope of the eurodollars futures curve at longer horizons.
Like Piazzesi and Swanson (2004), he finds that time variation in the risk premium has
little effect on estimated policy expectations at shorter horizons (six to twelve months, in
his study) but becomes increasingly important at longer horizons.
16Auother advantage is that, unlike survey participants, traders back up their forecasts
with their money--a powerful incentive to make forecasts that are as accurate as possible.
170ur analysis used daily data. Using intraday data, Gurkaynak, Sack, and Swanson
(2004) found an effect of similar magnitude.
lsA caveat: These probability distributions are derived under an assumption of risk
neutrality. Thus, unobserved risk premiums are potentially a problem here as well.