View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 p.m. EST (7 p.m. PST)
March 1, 2013

Long-Term Interest Rates

Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Annual Monetary/Macroeconomics Conference: The Past and Future of Monetary Policy
Sponsored by Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
San Francisco, California

March 1, 2013

I will begin my remarks by posing a question: Why are long-term interest rates so
low in the United States and in other major industrial countries?
At first blush, the answer seems obvious: Central banks in those countries are
pursuing accommodative monetary policies to boost growth and reduce slack in their
economies. However, while central banks certainly play a key role in determining the
behavior of long-term interest rates, theirs is only a proximate influence. A more
complete explanation of the current low level of rates must take account of the broader
economic environment in which central banks are currently operating and of the
constraints that that environment places on their policy choices.
Let me start with a brief overview of the recent history of long-term interest rates
in some key economies. Chart 1 shows the 10-year government bond yields for five
major industrial countries: Canada, Germany, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the
United States. Note that the movements in these yields are quite correlated despite some
differences in the economic circumstances and central bank mandates in those countries.
Further, with the notable exception of Japan, the levels of the yields have been very
similar--indeed, strikingly so, with long-term yields declining over time and currently
close to 2 percent in each case. The similar behavior of these yields attests to the global
nature of the economic and financial developments of recent years, as well as to the broad
similarity in how the monetary policymakers in the advanced economies have responded
to these developments. Of course, Japanese yields are clearly a case apart, as Japan has
endured an extended period of deflation, while inflation in the other four countries has
been positive and generally close to the stated objectives of the monetary authorities. But

-2even Japanese yields have shown some tendency to fluctuate along with other benchmark
yields, and they have also declined over the period shown.
In my comments, I will delve more deeply into the reasons why these long-term
interest rates have fallen so low. This examination may be useful both for understanding
the current stance of policy and also for thinking about how rates may evolve. In short,
we expect that as the economy recovers, long-term rates will rise over time to more
normal levels. A return to more normal conditions in financial markets would, of course,
be most welcome. Many commentators have noted, however, that both an extended
period of low rates and the transition back toward normal levels may pose risks to
financial stability. In the final portion of my remarks, I will discuss some aspects of how
the Federal Reserve is approaching these risks.
Why Are Long-Term Interest Rates So Low?
So, why are long-term interest rates currently so low? To help answer this
question, it is useful to decompose longer-term yields into three components: one
reflecting expected inflation over the term of the security; another capturing the expected
path of short-term real, or inflation-adjusted, interest rates; and a residual component
known as the term premium. Of course, none of these three components is observed
directly, but there are standard ways of estimating them. Chart 2 displays one version of
this decomposition of the 10-year U.S. Treasury yield based on a term structure model
developed by Federal Reserve staff.1 The broad features I will emphasize are similar to
those found by other authors using a variety of methods.2

1

Estimates are based on the model of D’Amico, Kim, and Wei (2010). That model employs the “arbitragefree” term structure framework and jointly models real yields, nominal yields, and inflation as functions of
four underlying latent factors. Historical data on nominal yields, real yields, and inflation can be used to
estimate these underlying factors and the relationship of real and nominal yields to the factors. Based on

-3All three components of the 10-year yield have declined since 2007. The
decomposition attributes much of the decline in the yield since 2010 to a sharp fall in the
term premium, but the expected short-term real rate component also moved down
significantly. Let’s consider each component more closely.
The expected inflation component has drifted gradually downward for many years
and has become quite stable. In large part, the downward trend and stabilization of
expected inflation in the United States are products of the increasing credibility of the
Federal Reserve’s commitment to price stability. In January 2012, the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) underscored this commitment by issuing a statement--since
reaffirmed at its January 2013 meeting--on its longer-run goals and policy strategy, which
included a longer-run inflation target of 2 percent.3 The anchoring of long-term inflation
expectations near 2 percent has been a key factor influencing long-term interest rates over
recent years. It almost certainly helped mitigate the strong disinflationary pressures
immediately following the crisis. While I have not shown expected inflation for other
advanced economies, the pictures would be very similar--again, except for Japan.
With the expected inflation component of the 10-year rate near 2 percent and the
rate itself a bit below 2 percent recently, it is clear that the combination of the other two
components--the expected path of short-term real interest rates and the term premium-must make a small net negative contribution.

this information, the model can be used to produce estimates of the components of nominal yields shown in
chart 2. Note that inflation in chart 2 is measured by the consumer price index; inflation measured by this
index is close to but on average slightly higher than inflation as measured by the price index for personal
consumption expenditures, the measure to which the Federal Open Market Committee’s 2 percent inflation
objective refers.
2
For example, this decomposition as estimated based on expectations as reported in the Blue Chip
Financial Forecasts gives broadly similar results, as do many standard term structure models.
3
See Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy, as amended effective on January 29,
2013, at www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/FOMC_LongerRunGoals.pdf.

-4The expected path of short-term real interest rates is, of course, influenced by
monetary policy, both the current stance of policy and market participants’ expectations
of how policy will evolve. The stance of monetary policy at any given time, in turn, is
driven largely by the economic outlook, the risks surrounding that outlook, and at times
other factors, such as whether the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates is binding.
In the current environment, both policymakers and market participants widely agree that
supporting the U.S. economic recovery while keeping inflation close to 2 percent will
likely require real short-term rates, currently negative, to remain low for some time. As
shown in chart 2, the expected average of the short-term real rate over the next 10 years
has gradually declined to near zero over the past few years, in part reflecting downward
revisions in expectations about the pace of the ongoing recovery and, hence, a pushing
out of expectations regarding how long nominal short-term rates will remain low. 4
As the persistence of the effects of the crisis have become clearer, the Federal
Reserve’s communications have reinforced the expectation that conditions are likely to
warrant highly accommodative policy for some time: Most recently, the FOMC
indicated that it expects to maintain an exceptionally low level of the federal funds rate at
least as long as the unemployment rate is above 6.5 percent, projected inflation between
one and two years ahead is no more than a half percentage point above the Committee’s 2
percent target, and long-term inflation expectations remain stable.5
In discussing the role of monetary policy in determining the expected future path
of real short-term rates, I have cheated a little: What monetary policy actually controls is

4

Real interest rates are not constrained by the zero bound, and the fact that expected average real shortterm interest rates are near zero reflects that the nominal rate is expected, on average, to run close to the
expected inflation rate, which is near 2 percent.
5
See the FOMC’s December statement at Board of Governors (2012).

-5nominal short-term rates. However, because inflation adjusts slowly, control of nominal
short-term rates usually translates into control of real short-term rates over the short and
medium term. In the longer term, real interest rates are determined primarily by
nonmonetary factors, such as the expected return to capital investments, which in turn is
closely related to the underlying strength of the economy. The fact that market yields
currently incorporate an expectation of very low short-term real interest rates over the
next 10 years suggests that market participants anticipate persistently slow growth and,
consequently, low real returns to investment. In other words, the low level of expected
real short rates may reflect not only investor expectations for a slow cyclical recovery but
also some downgrading of longer-term growth prospects.6
Chart 3, which displays yields on inflation-indexed, long-term government bonds
for the same five countries represented in chart 1, shows that expected real yields over the
longer term are low in other advanced industrial economies as well. Note again the
strong similarity in returns across these economies, suggesting once again the importance
of common global factors. While indexed yields spiked up around the end of 2008,
reflecting market stresses at the height of the crisis that undercut the demand for these
bonds, these effects dissipated in 2009. Since that time, inflation-indexed yields have
declined steadily and now stand below zero in each country.7 Apparently, low longerterm real rate expectations are playing an important role in accounting for low 10-year
nominal rates in other industrial countries, as well as in the United States.
6

Between April 2009 and October 2012, expectations for average growth over the next 10 years, as
reported in Consensus Forecasts, have fallen about 0.2 percentage points for the United States. This
reduction in growth expectations is a broad phenomenon: Between April 2009 and October 2012, the
average prediction for growth over the next 10 years for Canada, Germany, Japan, and the United Kingdom
has fallen between 0.1 and 0.6 percentage points.
7
It is important to note that these indexed yields are likely being pushed down by term premiums akin to
the term premiums in nominal rates discussed in this speech.

-6The third and final component of the long-term interest rate is the term premium,
defined as the residual component not captured by expected real short-term rates or
expected inflation. As I noted, the largest portion of the downward move in long-term
rates since 2010 appears to be due to a fall in the term premium, so it deserves some
special discussion.
In general, the term premium is the extra return investors expect to obtain from
holding long-term bonds as opposed to holding and rolling over a sequence of short-term
securities over the same period. In part, the term premium compensates bondholders for
interest rate risk--the risk of capital gains and losses that interest rate changes imply for
the value of longer-term bonds. Two changes in the nature of this interest rate risk have
probably contributed to a general downward movement of the term premium in recent
years. First, the volatility of Treasury yields has declined, in part because short-term
rates are pressed up against the zero lower bound and are expected to remain there for
some time to come. Second, the correlation of bond prices and stock prices has become
increasingly negative over time, implying that bonds have become more valuable as a
hedge against risks from holding other assets.8
Beyond interest rate risk, a number of other factors also affect the term premium
in practice. For example, during periods of financial turmoil, the prices of longer-term
Treasury securities are often driven up by so-called safe-haven demands of investors who
place special value on the safety and liquidity of Treasury securities. Indeed, even during
more placid periods, global demands for safe assets increase the value of Treasury
securities. Many foreign governments and central banks, particularly those with
sustained current account surpluses, hold substantial international reserves in the form of
8

See, for example, Campbell, Sunderam, and Viceira (2009).

-7Treasuries. Foreign holdings of U.S. Treasury securities currently amount to about
$5-1/2 trillion, roughly half of the total amount of marketable Treasury debt outstanding.
The global economic and financial stresses of recent years--triggered first by the financial
crisis, and then by the problems in the euro area--appear to have significantly elevated the
safe-haven demand for Treasury securities at times, pushing down Treasury yields and
implying a lower, or even a negative, term premium.9
Federal Reserve actions have also affected term premiums in recent years, most
prominently through a series of Large-Scale Asset Purchase (LSAP) programs. These
programs consist of open market purchases of agency debt, agency mortgage-backed
securities, and longer-term Treasury securities. To the extent that Treasury securities and
agency-guaranteed securities are not perfect substitutes for other assets, Federal Reserve
purchases of these assets should lower their term premiums, putting downward pressure
on longer-term interest rates and easing financial conditions more broadly. Although
estimated effects vary, a growing body of research supports the view that LSAPs are
effective at bringing down term premiums and thus reducing longer-term rates.10 Of
course, the Federal Reserve has used this unconventional approach to lowering longerterm rates because, with short-term rates near zero, it can no longer use its conventional
approach of cutting the target for the federal funds rate.11 Accordingly, this portion of the

9

There are some additional more technical features of the Treasury market that push down the term
premium. For example, the Treasury term premium is likely also depressed by the global demand for
Treasury securities for use as collateral or margin in funding or derivatives markets.
10
See, for example, Gagnon, Raskin, Remache, and Sack (2011); Li and Wei (2012); Hamilton and Wu
(2012); D’Amico, English, López-Salido, and Nelson (2012); Rosa (2012); Krishnamurthy and VissingJørgensen (2011); and Hancock and Passmore (2012).
11
Term premiums, calculated using similar methods, have also declined fairly sharply recently in Canada,
Germany, and the United Kingdom; somewhat less so in Japan. This result is notable in that the central
banks of these economies, with the exception of the Bank of England, have not pursued large-scale
purchases of longer-term securities.

-8decline in the term premium might ultimately be attributed to the sluggish economic
recovery, which prompted additional policy action from the Federal Reserve.
Let’s recap. Long-term interest rates are the sum of expected inflation, expected
real short-term interest rates, and a term premium. Expected inflation has been low and
stable, reflecting central bank mandates and credibility as well as considerable resource
slack in the major industrial economies. Real interest rates are expected to remain low,
reflecting the weakness of the recovery in advanced economies (and possibly some
downgrading of longer-term growth prospects as well). This weakness, all else being
equal, dictates that monetary policy must remain accommodative if it is to support the
recovery and reduce disinflationary risks. Put another way, at the present time the major
industrial economies apparently cannot sustain significantly higher real rates of return; in
that respect, central banks--so long as they are meeting their price stability mandates-have little choice but to take actions that keep nominal long-term rates relatively low, as
suggested by the similarity in the levels of the rates shown in chart 1. Finally, term
premiums are low or negative, reflecting a host of factors, including central bank actions
in support of economic recovery. Thus, while the current constellation of long-term rates
across many advanced countries has few precedents, it is not puzzling: It follows
naturally from the economic circumstances of these countries and the implications of
these circumstances for the policies of their central banks.
How Are Long-Term Rates Likely to Evolve?
So, how are long-term rates likely to evolve over coming years? It is worth
pausing to note that, not that long ago, central bankers would have carefully avoided this
topic. However, it is now a bedrock principle of central banking that transparency about

-9the likely path of policy, in general, and interest rates, in particular, can increase the
effectiveness of policy. In the present context, I would add that transparency may
mitigate risks emanating from unexpected rate movements. Thus, let me turn to
prospects for long-term rates, starting with the expected path of rates and then turning to
deviations from the expected path that may arise.
If, as the FOMC anticipates, the economic recovery continues at a moderate pace,
with unemployment slowly declining and inflation expectations remaining near 2 percent,
then long-term interest rates would be expected to rise gradually toward more normal
levels over the next several years. This rise would occur as the market’s view of the
expected date at which the Federal Reserve will begin the removal of policy
accommodation draws nearer and then as accommodation is removed. Some
normalization of the term premium might also contribute to a rise in long-term rates.
To illustrate possible paths, chart 4 displays four different forecasts of the
evolution of the 10-year Treasury yield over coming years. The black line is the forecast
reported in the December 2012 Blue Chip Financial Forecasts survey. The green line
gives the Congressional Budget Office forecast published in February, and the blue line
presents the median from the Survey of Professional Forecasters, as reported in the first
quarter of this year. Finally, the purple line shows a forecast based on the term structure
model used for the decomposition of the 10-year yield in chart 2.12 While these forecasts
embody a wide range of underlying models and assumptions, the basic message is clear-long-term interest rates are expected to rise gradually over the next few years, rising (at

12

This projection assumes that two key components of the 10-year Treasury yield shown in chart 2--the
expected average real short-rate and the term premium--revert to their respective mean levels over the
period 2000 to 2006 during the next 5 years; the expected average inflation component is assumed to
remain constant near the 2 percent level prevailing at the end of 2012.

- 10 least according to these forecasts) to around 3 percent at the end of 2014. The forecasts
in chart 4 imply a total increase of between 200 and 300 basis points in long-term yields
between now and 2017.
Of course, the forecasts in chart 4 are just forecasts, and reality might well turn
out to be different. Chart 5 provides three complementary approaches to summarizing
the uncertainty surrounding forecasts of long-term rates. The dark gray bars in the chart
are based on the range of forecasts reported in the Blue Chip Financial Forecasts, the blue
bars are based on the historical uncertainty regarding long-term interest rates as reflected
in the Board staff’s FRB/US model of the U.S. economy, and the orange bars give a
market-based measure of uncertainty derived from swaptions. These three different
measures give a broadly similar picture about the upside and downside risks to the
forecasts of long-term rates. Rates 100 basis points higher than the expected paths in
chart 4 by 2014 are certainly plausible outcomes as judged by each of the three measures,
and this uncertainty grows to as much as 175 basis points by 2017. Note, though, that
while the risk of an unexpected rise in interest rates has drawn much attention, the level
of long-term interest rates also could prove to be lower than forecast. Indeed, by the
measures shown in chart 5, the upside and downside risks to the level of rates are roughly
symmetric as of 2017.
We also have some historical experience with increases in rates during tightening
cycles to consider. For example, in 1994, 10-year Treasury yields rose about 220 basis
points over the course of a year, reflecting an unexpected quickening in the pace of
economic growth and signs of building inflation pressures. This increase in long-term
rates appears to have reflected a mix of a pronounced rise in the expected path of the

- 11 policy interest rate and some increase in the term premium.13 A rise of more than 200
basis points in a year is at the upper end of what is implied by the mean paths and
uncertainty measures shown in charts 4 and 5, but these measures still admit a substantial
probability of higher--and lower--paths.
Overall, then, we anticipate that long-term rates will rise as the recovery
progresses and expected short-term real rates and term premiums return to more normal
levels. The precise timing and pace of the increase will depend importantly on how
economic conditions develop, however, and is subject to considerable two-sided
uncertainty.
Managing Risks Associated with the Future Course of Long-Term Interest Rates
As I noted when I began my remarks, one reason to focus on the timing and pace
of a possible increase in long-term rates is that these outcomes may have implications for
financial stability. Commentators have raised two broad concerns surrounding the
outlook for long-term rates. To oversimplify, the first risk is that rates will remain low,
and the second is that they will not. In particular, in an environment of persistently low
returns, incentives may grow for some investors to engage in an unsafe “reach for yield”
either through excessive use of leverage or through other forms of risk-taking. My Board
colleague Jeremy Stein recently discussed how this behavior may arise in some financial
markets, including credit markets.14 Alternatively, we face a risk that longer-term rates
will rise sharply at some point, imposing capital losses on holders of fixed-income

13

The two components were intertwined, as measures of uncertainty about the path of policy moved up
sharply, likely contributing to a rise in term premiums. Notably, in this episode, the rise in rates created
some stress in financial markets but did not lead to serious financial instability, nor did it significantly
impair economic activity. However, one would not want to conclude from that one case that sharp rises in
rates do not pose risks.
14
See Stein (2013).

- 12 instruments, including financial institutions. Of course, the two risks may very well be
mutually reinforcing: Taking on duration risk is one way investors may reach for yield,
and the losses resulting from a sharp rise in longer-term rates will be greater if investors
have done so.15
One might argue that the right response to these risks is to tighten monetary
policy, raising long-term interest rates with the aim of forestalling any undesirable
buildup of risk. I hope my discussion this evening has convinced you that, at least in
economic circumstances of the sort that prevail today, such an approach could be quite
costly and might well be counterproductive from the standpoint of promoting financial
stability. Long-term interest rates in the major industrial countries are low for good
reason: Inflation is low and stable and, given expectations of weak growth, expected real
short rates are low. Premature rate increases would carry a high risk of short-circuiting
the recovery, possibly leading--ironically enough--to an even longer period of low longterm rates. Only a strong economy can deliver persistently high real returns to savers and
investors, and the economies of the major industrial countries are still in the recovery
phase.
So how can financial stability concerns--which the Federal Reserve takes very
seriously--be addressed? Our strategy, undertaken in cooperation with other regulators
and central banks, has a number of elements.

15

On the other hand, some risk-taking--such as when an entrepreneur takes out a loan to start a new
business or an existing firm expands capacity--is a necessary element of a healthy economic recovery.
Moreover, although accommodative monetary policies may increase certain types of risk-taking, in the
present circumstances they also serve in some ways to reduce risk in the system, most importantly by
strengthening the overall economy, but also by encouraging firms to rely more on longer-term funding, and
by reducing debt service costs for households and businesses.

- 13 First, we have greatly increased our macroprudential oversight, with a particular
focus on potential systemic vulnerabilities, including buildups of leverage and unstable
funding patterns as well as interest rate risk.16 Under the umbrella of our
interdisciplinary Large Institutions Supervision Coordinating Committee, we pay special
attention to developments at the largest, most complex financial firms, making use of
information gathered in our supervision of the institutions and drawn from financial
market indicators of their health and systemic vulnerability. We also monitor the shadow
banking sector, especially its interaction with regulated institutions; in this work, we look
for factors that may leave the system vulnerable to an adverse “fire sale” dynamic, in
which declining asset values could force leveraged investors to sell assets, depressing
prices further. We exchange information regularly with other regulatory agencies, both
directly and under the auspices of the Financial Stability Oversight Council. Throughout
the Federal Reserve System, work in these areas is conducted by experts in banking,
financial markets, monetary policy, and other disciplines, and at the Federal Reserve
Board we have established our Office for Financial Stability Policy and Research to help
coordinate this work. Findings are presented regularly to the Board and to the FOMC for
use in its monetary policy deliberations.
Second, recognizing that our monitoring of the financial sector will always be
imperfect, we are using regulatory and supervisory tools to help ensure that financial
institutions are sufficiently resilient to weather losses and periods of market turmoil
arising from any source. Indeed, reflecting expectations embodied in the new Basel III
and Dodd-Frank standards, the largest and most complex financial firms have
substantially increased both their capital and their liquidity in recent years. Our current
16

See Adrian, Covitz, and Liang (forthcoming).

- 14 round of stress testing of the largest bank holding companies, to be completed early this
month, examines whether the largest banking firms have sufficient capital to come
through a seriously adverse economic downturn and still have the capacity to perform
their roles as providers of credit. In a related exercise, we are also asking banks to stresstest the adequacy of their capital in the face of a hypothetical sharp upward shift in the
term structure of interest rates.
Third, our approach to communicating and implementing monetary policy
provides the Federal Reserve with new tools that could potentially be used to mitigate the
risk of sharp increases in interest rates. In 1994--the period discussed earlier in which
sharp increases in interest rates strained financial markets--the FOMC’s communication
tools were very limited; indeed, it had just begun issuing public statements following
policy moves. By contrast, in recent years, the Federal Reserve has provided a great deal
of additional information about its expectations for the path of the economy and the
stance of monetary policy. Most recently, as I mentioned, the FOMC announced
unemployment and inflation thresholds characterizing conditions that will guide the
timing of the first increase in the target for the federal funds rate. Further, the FOMC
stated that a highly accommodative stance of monetary policy is likely to remain
appropriate for a considerable time after our current asset purchase program ends. By
providing greater clarity concerning the likely course of the federal funds rate, FOMC
communication should both make policy more effective and reduce the risk that market
misperceptions of the Committee’s intentions would lead to unnecessary interest rate
volatility.

- 15 In addition, the Federal Reserve could, if necessary, use its balance sheet tools to
mitigate the risk of a sharp rise in rates. For example, the Committee has indicated its
intention to sell its agency securities gradually once conditions warrant. The Committee
also noted, however, that the pace of sales could be adjusted up or down in response to
material changes in either the economic outlook or financial conditions. In particular,
adjustments to the pace or timing of asset sales could be used, under some circumstances,
to dampen excessively sharp adjustments in longer-term interest rates.
Conclusion
Let me finish with some thoughts on balancing the risks we face in the current
challenging economic environment, at a time when our main policy tool, the federal
funds rate, is near its effective lower bound. On the one hand, the Fed’s dual mandate
has led us to provide strong support for the recovery, both to promote maximum
employment and to keep inflation from falling below our price stability objective. One
purpose of this support is to prompt a return to the productive risk-taking that is essential
to robust growth and to getting the unemployed back to work. On the other hand, we
must be mindful of the possibility that sustained periods of low interest rates and highly
accommodative policy could lead to excessive risk-taking in some financial markets.
The balance here is not an easy one to strike. While the recent crisis is vivid testament to
the costs of ill-judged risk-taking, we must also be aware of constraints posed by the
present state of the economy. In light of the moderate pace of the recovery and the
continued high level of economic slack, dialing back accommodation with the goal of
deterring excessive risk-taking in some areas poses its own risks to growth, price
stability, and, ultimately, financial stability. Indeed, as I noted, a premature removal of

- 16 accommodation could, by slowing the economy, perversely serve to extend the period of
low long-term rates.
For these reasons, we are responding to financial stability concerns with the
multipronged approach I summarized a moment ago, which relies primarily on
monitoring, supervision and regulation, and communication. We will, however, be
evaluating these issues carefully and on an ongoing basis; we will be alert for any
developments that pose risks to the achievement of the Federal Reserve’s mandated
objectives of price stability and maximum employment; and we will, of course, remain
prepared to use all of our tools as needed to address any such developments.

- 17 References
Adrian, Tobias, Daniel Covitz, and Nellie Liang (forthcoming). “Financial Stability
Monitoring,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series. Washington: Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (2012), “Federal Reserve Issues
FOMC Statement,” press release, December 12,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/press/monetary/20121212a.htm.
Campbell, John Y., Adi Sunderam, and Luis M. Viceira (2009). “Inflation Bets or
Deflation Hedges? The Changing Risks of Nominal Bonds,” NBER Working
Paper Series 14701. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research,
February.
D’Amico, Stefania, William English, David López-Salido, and Edward Nelson (2012).
“The Federal Reserve’s Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programmes: Rationale and
Effects,” Economic Journal, vol. 122 (November), pp. F415-F446.
D’Amico, Stefania, Don H. Kim, and Min Wei (2010). “Tips from TIPS: The
Informational Content of Treasury Inflation Protected Security Prices,” Finance
and Economics Discussion Series 2010-19. Washington: Board of Governors of
the Federal Reserve System, December 2009,
www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2010/201019/201019abs.html.
Gagnon, Joseph, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache, and Brian Sack (2011). “The
Financial Market Effects of the Federal Reserve’s Large-Scale Asset Purchases,”
International Journal of Central Banking, vol. 7 (March), pp. 3-43.
Hamilton, James D., and Jing Cynthia Wu (2012). “The Effectiveness of Alternative
Policy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound Environment,” Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking, vol. 44 (February supplement), pp. 3-46.
Hancock, Diana, and Wayne Passmore (2012). “The Federal Reserve’s Portfolio and Its
Effects on Mortgage Markets,” Finance and Economic Discussion Series 201222. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2012/201222/201222pap.pdf.
Krishnamurthy, Arvind, and Annette Vissing-Jørgensen (2011). “The Effects of
Quantitative Easing on Interest Rates: Channels and Implications for Policy,”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall, pp. 215-65.
Li, Canlin, and Min Wei (2012). “Term Structure Modelling with Supply Factors and the
Federal Reserve’s Large Scale Asset Purchase Programs,” Finance and
Economics Discussion Series 2012-37. Washington: Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, May,
www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2012/201237/201237abs.html.

- 18 Rosa, Carlo (2012). “How ‘Unconventional’ Are Large-Scale Asset Purchases? The
Impact of Monetary Policy on Asset Prices,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Staff Reports 560. New York: Federal Reserve Bank of New York, May,
www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr560.pdf.
Stein, Jeremy C. (2013). “Overheating in Credit Markets: Origins, Measurement, and
Policy Responses,” speech delivered at “Restoring Household Financial Stability
after the Great Recession: Why Household Balance Sheets Matter,” a symposium
sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, St. Louis, February 5-7,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/stein20130207a.htm.

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System