View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:00 p.m. EST
February 18, 2009

Federal Reserve Policies to Ease Credit
and their Implications for the Fed’s Balance Sheet

Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
National Press Club
Washington, D.C.

February 18, 2009

We live in extraordinarily challenging times for the global economy and for
economic policymakers, not least for central banks such as the Federal Reserve. As you
know, the recent economic statistics have been dismal, with many economies, including
ours, having fallen into recession. And behind those statistics, we must never forget, are
millions of people struggling with lost jobs, lost homes, and lost confidence in their
economic future. In examples that resonate with me personally, the unemployment rate
in the small town in South Carolina where I grew up has risen to 14 percent, and I learned
the other day that what had once been my family home was recently put through
foreclosure.
Traditionally the most conservative of institutions, central banks around the world
have responded to this unprecedented crisis with force and innovation. In the United
States, the Federal Reserve has done, and will continue to do, everything possible within
the limits of its authority to assist in restoring our nation to financial stability and
economic prosperity as quickly as possible. Policy innovation has been necessary
because conventional monetary policies, which focus on influencing short-term interest
rates, have proven insufficient to overcome the effects of the financial crisis on credit
conditions and the broader economy. To further ease financial conditions, beyond what
can be attained by reducing short-term interest rates, the Federal Reserve has taken
additional steps to improve the functioning of credit markets and to increase the supply of
credit to households and businesses--a policy strategy that I have called “credit easing.”
In the first portion of my remarks, I will briefly outline the three principal approaches to
easing credit that we have undertaken, over and above cutting the short-term interest rate,
and assess their effectiveness to date.

-2Each of these policy approaches involves the provision of credit or the purchase
of debt securities by the Federal Reserve, which collectively have resulted in a substantial
expansion in the size of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet. The second portion of my
remarks addresses some issues raised by the changes in the size of the Fed’s balance
sheet. In particular, I will discuss how the size of the balance sheet affects the ability of
the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), the body that sets monetary policy, to
foster maximum sustainable employment and price stability, as well as the steps that are
being taken to manage the balance sheet appropriately.
Finally, the expansion of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet has raised some
concerns--and led to some misconceptions--about the credit risk being taken by the Fed.
I will address the issue of credit risk today. And I would also like to talk about steps that
the Fed is taking to improve the transparency of its programs to the public, consistent
with our obligations in a democracy.
Federal Reserve Policy during the Crisis
The Federal Reserve has responded forcefully to the crisis since its emergence in
the summer of 2007. The FOMC began to ease monetary policy in September 2007,
reducing the target for the federal funds rate, its policy instrument, by 50 basis points, or
1/2 percentage point. As indications of economic weakness proliferated, the Committee
continued to respond, bringing down its target for the federal funds rate by a cumulative
325 basis points by the spring of 2008. In historical comparison, this policy response
stands out as exceptionally rapid and proactive.
Monetary easing helped support employment and incomes during the first year of
the crisis. Unfortunately, the intensification of financial turbulence last fall led to further

-3significant deterioration in the economic outlook. The Committee responded by cutting
the target for the federal funds rate an additional 100 basis points in October, with half of
that reduction coming as part of an unprecedented coordinated interest rate cut by six
major central banks on October 8. In December, the Committee reduced its target
further, setting a range of 0 to 25 basis points for the target federal funds rate.
The Fed’s monetary easing has been reflected in significant declines in a number
of lending rates, especially shorter-term rates, thus offsetting to some degree the effects
of the financial turmoil on the cost of credit. However, that offset has been incomplete,
as widening credit spreads, more-restrictive lending standards, and credit market
dysfunction have worked against the monetary easing and led to tighter financial
conditions overall. Thus, in addition to easing monetary policy, the Federal Reserve has
made use of a range of additional tools to ease credit conditions and support the broader
economy.
These additional components of the Fed’s toolkit can be divided into three sets.
The first set is closely tied to the central bank’s traditional role of provider of short-term
liquidity to sound financial institutions. Over the course of the crisis, the Fed has taken a
number of extraordinary actions to ensure that financial institutions have adequate access
to short-term credit. In fulfilling its traditional lending function, the Federal Reserve
enhances the stability of our financial system, increases the willingness of financial
institutions to extend credit, and helps to ease conditions in interbank lending markets,
thereby reducing the overall cost of capital to banks. In addition, some interest rates,
including the rates on some adjustable-rate mortgages, are tied contractually to key
interbank rates, such as the London interbank offered rate (Libor). To the extent that the

-4provision of ample liquidity to banks reduces Libor, other borrowers will also see their
payments decline.
Because interbank markets are global in scope, the Federal Reserve has also
approved temporary bilateral liquidity agreements with 14 foreign central banks. These
so-called currency swap facilities have allowed these central banks to acquire dollars
from the Federal Reserve that they may lend to financial institutions in their own
jurisdictions. The purpose of these swaps is to ease conditions in dollar funding markets
globally. Improvements in global interbank markets, in turn, promote greater stability in
other markets, such as money markets and foreign exchange markets.
Although the provision of ample liquidity by the central bank to financial
institutions is a time-tested approach to reducing financial strains, it is no panacea.
Today, concerns about capital, asset quality, and credit risk continue to limit the
willingness of many intermediaries to extend credit, notwithstanding the access of these
firms to central bank liquidity. Moreover, lending to financial institutions does not
directly address instability or declining liquidity in critical nonbank markets, such as the
commercial paper market or the market for asset-backed securities, which under normal
circumstances are major sources of credit for U.S. households and firms.
To address these issues, the Federal Reserve has developed a second set of policy
tools, which involve the provision of liquidity directly to borrowers and investors in key
credit markets. Notably, we have introduced facilities to purchase highly rated
commercial paper at a term of three months and to provide backup liquidity for money
market mutual funds. The purpose of these facilities is to serve, once again in classic
central bank fashion, as backstop liquidity provider, in these cases to institutions and

-5markets that were destabilized by the rapid withdrawal of funds by short-term creditors
and investors. In addition, the Federal Reserve and the Treasury have jointly announced
a facility--expected to be operational shortly--that will lend against AAA-rated assetbacked securities collateralized by recently originated student loans, auto loans, credit
card loans, and loans guaranteed by the Small Business Administration. Last week, in
conjunction with the Treasury, we announced that we were prepared to expand
significantly this facility, known as the Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility, or
TALF, to encompass other types of newly issued AAA-rated asset-backed securities,
such as commercial mortgage-backed securities and private-label mortgage-backed
securities, as well. If this program works as planned, it should lead to lower rates and
greater availability of consumer, business, and mortgage credit.
The Federal Reserve’s third set of tools for supporting the functioning of credit
markets involves the purchase of longer-term securities for the Fed’s portfolio. For
example, we are purchasing up to $100 billion in the debt of government-sponsored
enterprises (GSEs) and up to $500 billion in mortgage-backed securities guaranteed by
federal agencies by midyear.
The Federal Reserve is engaged in continuous assessment of the effectiveness of
its credit-related tools, and we have generally been encouraged by the market responses.
Our lending to financial institutions has helped to relax the severe liquidity strains
experienced by many firms and has been associated with improvements in interbank
lending markets; for example, we believe that liquidity provision by the Fed and other
central banks is a principal reason that liquidity pressures around the end of the year-often a period of heightened liquidity strains--were relatively modest. Libor has fallen

-6sharply as well. Our commercial paper facility has helped to stabilize that market,
lowering rates significantly and allowing high-quality firms access to financing at terms
longer than a few days. Together with other government programs, our actions to
stabilize the money market mutual fund industry have also shown some success, as the
sharp withdrawals from funds seen in September have given way to modest inflows. And
rates on 30-year conforming fixed-rate mortgages have fallen nearly 1 percentage point
since we announced the program to purchase GSE-related securities. Thus, taken
together, these policies appear to give the Federal Reserve some scope to affect credit
conditions and economic performance, notwithstanding that the conventional tool of
monetary policy, the federal funds rate, is nearly as low as it can go.
The Federal Reserve’s Policies and its Balance Sheet
The various credit-related policies I have described have implications for the
Federal Reserve’s balance sheet. In the remainder of my remarks I will discuss those
implications as well as some related issues.
The three sets of policy tools I have focused on today--lending to financial
institutions, providing liquidity directly to key credit markets, and buying longer-term
securities--each represents a use of the asset side of the Fed’s balance sheet. Specifically,
loans that the Fed extends--either to financial institutions, through the discount window
and related facilities, or to other borrowers in programs like our commercial paper
facility--are recorded as assets on our balance sheet, as are securities acquired in the open
market, such as the GSE securities we are purchasing. The Fed’s assets also include
about $500 billion of Treasury securities. About 5 percent of our balance sheet, or $100
billion, consists of assets we acquired in the government interventions to prevent the

-7failures of Bear Stearns and American International Group (AIG). I won’t say much
about those interventions today, except to note that the failures of those companies would
have posed enormous risks to the stability of our financial system and economy. Because
the United States has no well-specified set of rules for dealing with the potential failure
of systemically critical nondepository financial institutions, we believed that the best of
the bad options available was to work with the Treasury to take the actions we did to
avoid those collapses. The liability side of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet is
relatively simple, consisting primarily of currency issuance (Federal Reserve notes) and
reserves held by the banking system on deposit with the Federal Reserve.
The various credit-related policies I have described today all act to increase the
size of both the asset and liability sides of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet. For
example, the purchase of $1 billion of GSE securities, paid for by crediting the deposit
account of the seller’s bank at the Federal Reserve, increases the Fed’s balance sheet by
$1 billion, with the acquired securities appearing as an asset, and the seller’s bank’s
deposit at the Fed being the offsetting liability. The quantitative impact of our credit
actions on the balance sheet has been large; its size has nearly doubled over the past year,
to just under $2 trillion.
Some observers have expressed the concern that, by expanding its balance sheet,
the Federal Reserve will ultimately stoke inflation. The Fed’s lending activities have
indeed resulted in a large increase in the reserves held by banks and thus in the narrowest
definition of the money supply, the monetary base.1 However, banks are choosing to
leave the great bulk of their excess reserves idle, in most cases on deposit with the Fed.
Consequently, the rates of growth of broader monetary aggregates, such as M1 and M2,
1

The monetary base is the sum of currency in circulation and bank reserves.

-8have been much lower than that of the monetary base.2 At this point, with global
economic activity weak and commodity prices at low levels, we see little risk of
unacceptably high inflation in the near term; indeed, we expect inflation to be quite low
for some time.
However, at some point, when credit markets and the economy have begun to
recover, the Federal Reserve will have to moderate growth in the money supply and
begin to raise the federal funds rate. To reduce policy accommodation, the Fed will have
to unwind some of its credit-easing programs and allow its balance sheet to shrink. To
some extent, this unwinding will happen automatically, as improvements in credit
markets should reduce the need to use Fed facilities. Indeed, where possible, we have
tried to set lending rates and other terms at levels that are likely to be increasingly
unattractive to borrowers as financial conditions normalize. In addition, some programs-those authorized under the Federal Reserve’s so-called 13(3) authority, which requires a
finding that conditions in financial markets are “unusual and exigent”--will, by law, have
to be phased out once credit market conditions substantially normalize. However, the
principal factor determining the timing and pace of that process will be the Federal
Reserve’s assessment of the condition of credit markets and the prospects for the
economy.
A significant shrinking of the balance sheet can be accomplished relatively
quickly, as a substantial portion of the assets that the Federal Reserve holds--including

2

M1 consists of currency, traveler’s checks, demand deposits, and other checkable deposits. M2 consists
of M1 plus savings deposits, small-denomination time deposits, and balances in retail money market
mutual funds. M2 has grown more rapidly than normal in recent months, at about a 15 percent annual rate
on a quarterly average basis in the fourth quarter. We attribute this increase primarily to investors’ demand
for greater safety, which has led them to increase their holdings of government-guaranteed bank deposits.
We expect growth in M2 to slow considerably in 2009, barring a similar shift in portfolio preferences.

-9loans to financial institutions, temporary central bank liquidity swaps, and purchases of
commercial paper--are short-term in nature and can simply be allowed to run off as the
various programs and facilities are scaled back or shut down. As the size of the balance
sheet and the quantity of excess reserves in the system decline, the Federal Reserve will
be able to return to its traditional means of making monetary policy--namely, by setting a
target for the federal funds rate.
Importantly, the management of the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet and the
conduct of monetary policy in the future will be made easier by the recent congressional
action to give the Fed the authority to pay interest on bank reserves. Because banks
should be unwilling to lend reserves at a rate lower than they can receive from the Fed,
the interest rate the Fed pays on bank reserves should help to set a floor on the overnight
interest rate. Moreover, other tools are available or can be developed to improve control
of the federal funds rate during the exit stage. For example, the Treasury could resume
its recent practice of issuing supplementary financing bills and placing the funds with the
Federal Reserve; the issuance of these bills effectively drains reserves from the banking
system, thereby improving monetary control. As we consider new programs or the
expansion of old ones, the Federal Reserve will carefully weigh the implications for the
exit strategy. And we will take all necessary actions to ensure that the unwinding of our
programs is accomplished smoothly and in a timely way, consistent with meeting our
obligation to foster maximum employment and price stability.

- 10 Credit Risk and Transparency
Two other frequently asked questions about the Federal Reserve’s balance sheet
are: First, how much credit risk is the Fed taking in its lending activities? And, second,
is the Fed informing the public adequately about these activities?
To address the first question, for the great bulk of Fed lending, the credit risks are
extremely low. The provision of short-term credit to financial institutions--our traditional
function--exposes the Federal Reserve to minimal credit risk, as the loans we make to
financial institutions are generally short-term, overcollateralized, and made with recourse
to the borrowing firm. In the case of the liquidity swaps, the foreign central banks are
responsible for repaying the Federal Reserve, not the financial institutions that ultimately
receive the funds, and the Fed receives an equivalent amount of foreign currency in
exchange for the dollars it provides foreign central banks. The Treasury stands behind
the debt and other securities issued by the GSEs.
Our special lending programs have also been set up to minimize our credit risk.
The largest program, the commercial paper funding facility, accepts only the most highly
rated paper. It also charges borrowers a premium, which is set aside against possible
losses. And the TALF, the facility that will lend against securities backed by consumer
and small business loans, is a joint Federal Reserve-Treasury program, as I mentioned,
and capital provided by the Treasury will help insulate the Federal Reserve from credit
losses.
The transactions we undertook to prevent the systemically destabilizing failures of
Bear Stearns and AIG, which, as I noted, make up about 5 percent of our balance sheet,
carry more risk than our traditional activities. But we intend, over time, to sell the assets

- 11 acquired in those transactions in a way that maximizes the return to taxpayers, and we
expect to recover the credit we have extended. Moreover, in assessing the financial risks
of those transactions, once again one must also consider the very grave risks our nation
would have incurred had public policy makers not acted in those instances.
Finally, I should remind you that all the Federal Reserve’s assets pay interest, and
the expansion of our balance sheet thereby implies increased interest income, income that
will accrue to the benefit of the federal budget. From the point of view of the federal
government, the Federal Reserve’s activities do not imply greater expenditure or
indebtedness. To the contrary, the Federal Reserve’s interest earnings have always been,
and will continue to be, a significant source of income for the Treasury.
On the second question, transparency, I firmly believe that central banks should
provide as much information as possible, both for reasons of democratic accountability
and because many of our policies are likely to be more effective if they are well
understood by the markets and the public. During my time at the Federal Reserve, the
FOMC has taken important steps to increase the transparency of monetary policy, such as
moving up the publication of the minutes of policy meetings and adopting the practice of
providing projections of the evolution of the economy at longer horizons and four times
per year rather than twice.
Later today, with the release of the minutes of the most recent FOMC meeting, we
will be making an additional significant enhancement in Federal Reserve
communications: To supplement the current economic projections by governors and
Reserve Bank presidents for the next three years, we will also publish their projections of
the longer-term values (at a horizon of, for example, five to six years) of output growth,

- 12 unemployment, and inflation, under the assumptions of appropriate monetary policy and
the absence of new shocks to the economy. These longer-term projections will inform
the public of the Committee participants’ estimates of the rate of growth of output and the
unemployment rate that appear to be sustainable in the long run in the United States,
taking into account important influences such as the trend growth rates of productivity
and the labor force, improvements in worker education and skills, the efficiency of the
labor market at matching workers and jobs, government policies affecting technological
development or the labor market, and other factors. The longer-term projections of
inflation may be interpreted, in turn, as the rate of inflation that FOMC participants see as
most consistent with the dual mandate given to it by the Congress--that is, the rate of
inflation that promotes maximum sustainable employment while also delivering
reasonable price stability. This further extension of the quarterly projections should
provide the public a clearer picture of FOMC participants’ policy strategy for promoting
maximum employment and price stability over time. Also, increased clarity about the
FOMC’s views regarding longer-term inflation should help to better stabilize the public’s
inflation expectations, thus contributing to keeping actual inflation from rising too high
or falling too low.
Likewise, the Federal Reserve is committed to keeping the Congress and the
public informed about its lending programs and balance sheet. For example, we continue
to add to the information shown in the Fed’s H.4.1 statistical release, which provides
weekly detail on the balance sheet and the amounts outstanding for each of the Federal
Reserve’s lending facilities. Extensive additional information about each of the Federal

- 13 Reserve’s lending programs is available online.3 The Fed also provides bimonthly
reports to the Congress on each of its programs that rely on the section 13(3) authorities.
Generally, our disclosure policies are consistent with the current best practices of major
central banks around the world. In addition, the Federal Reserve’s internal controls and
management practices are closely monitored by an independent inspector general, outside
private-sector auditors, and internal management and operations divisions, and through
periodic reviews by the Government Accountability Office.
All that said, recent developments have understandably led to a substantial
increase in the public’s interest in the Fed’s balance sheet and programs. For this reason,
we at the Fed have begun a thorough review of our disclosure policies and the
effectiveness of our communication. Today I would like to mention two initiatives.
First, to improve public access to information concerning Fed policies and
programs, in coming days we will unveil a new website that will bring together in a
systematic and comprehensive way the full range of information that the Federal Reserve
already makes available, supplemented by explanations, discussions, and analyses.
Second, at my request, Board Vice Chairman Donald Kohn is leading a
committee that will review our current publications and disclosure policies relating to the
Fed’s balance sheet and lending policies. The presumption of the committee will be that
the public has a right to know, and that the nondisclosure of information must be
affirmatively justified by clearly articulated criteria for confidentiality, based on factors

3

For links and references, see Ben S. Bernanke (2009), “Federal Reserve Programs to Strengthen Credit
Markets and the Economy,” testimony before the Committee on Financial Services, U.S. House of
Representatives, February 10, www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/testimony/bernanke20090210a.htm.

- 14 such as reasonable claims to privacy, the confidentiality of supervisory information, and
the need to ensure the effectiveness of policy.
Conclusion
Extraordinary times call for extraordinary measures. Responding to the very
difficult economic and financial challenges we face, the Federal Reserve has gone
beyond traditional monetary policy making to develop new policy tools to address the
dysfunctions in the nation’s credit markets. We have done so in a responsible way: The
credit risk associated with our nontraditional policies is exceptionally low, and, by
carefully monitoring our balance sheet and developing tools to drain bank reserves as
needed, we will ensure that policy accommodation can be reversed at the appropriate
time to avoid risks of future inflation.
We provide a great deal of information about our lending programs and our
balance sheet to the Congress and the public. But, as I have discussed today, we will do
more on this front, both expanding the information we provide and improving how we
communicate that information. Increased transparency is the best way to demonstrate
that the Federal Reserve’s nontraditional policies are well conceived, well managed, and
produce substantial public benefit.