View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

,

For release on delivery
5:00 p.m. EST
February 26, 2004

The Euro at Five

Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Institute for International Economics Conference
"Euro at Five: Ready for a Global Role?
Washington, D.C.
February 26,2004

I

"What is the appropriate domain of a currency area? It might seem at first that the
question is purely academic since it hardly appears within the realm of political
feasibility that national currencies would ever be abandoned in favor of any other
arrangement." Robert A. Mundell (1961, p. 657)

It is an honor for me to address such a distinguished group on the occasion of the

euro's fifth anniversary. I congratulate the Institute of International Economics for
putting together such an excellent program.
The successful introduction, five years ago, of an entirely new currency over a
wide range of polities and economies was, at a minimum, a remarkable technical
achievement. As a card-carrying member of the club of monetary economists, I like to
think that our collective expertise was helpful in making that achievement possible. As
both a policymaker and an economist, I welcome this opportunity to look back on the
first five years of the euro to see what we can learn from the experience and to consider
what this grand experiment implies for the future. I should say at the outset that, as usual,
my remarks this evening reflect my own views and not necessarily those of my
colleagues in the Federal Reserve System. 1
The economic analysis of optimal currency areas began, of course, with Robert
Mundell's seminal 1961 paper, from which I have quoted above? As you know, Mundell
argued that, ideally, economic similarity, not political boundaries, should define the
geographic area spanned by a common currency. He was the first to state the classic
tradeoff implied by the decision to adopt a common currency. According to Mundell, the

Karen Johnson and members of the Board's International Finance Division provided
helpful assistance and comments.
2 McKinnon (1963) extended Mundell's analysis.
1

-2principal advantage of a common currency is the reduction in transaction costs implied
by the use of a common medium of exchange across a broad area. The disadvantage of a
common currency is the loss of the shock-absorber properties of flexible exchange rates
and independent monetary policies. Flexible exchange rates and independent monetary
policies will be useful shock absorbers to the extent that macroeconomic shocks are
imperfectly correlated across regions, wages and prices are sticky, and other
macroeconomic adjustment mechanisms--such as factor mobility or fiscal transfers
among regions--are weak or absent. Thus, from the Mundellian perspective, the case for
a common currency within a broad area is stronger, the greater the actual or potential
economic and financial integration within the area; the greater the correlation of
macroeconomic shocks among regions within the area; and the more effective the nonmonetary shock absorbers, such as factor mobility.
Whether the nations that compose the European Monetary Union (EMU) form an
optimal currency area in Mundell's sense has been widely debated by researchers. For
example, Barry Eichengreen argued early on (Eichengreen, 1992) that Europe was
perhaps not well suited for a common currency on economic grounds (though he found
the political motivations more compelling). According to Eichengreen, the factors
reducing the desirability of a monetary union in Europe included the historical variability
of real exchange rates among European nations, the low degree of labor mobility between
countries, and a lower correlation of underlying shocks among European countries than
3

among regions of the United States. Other critics of monetary unification, such as
Martin Feldstein, have stressed the limited extent of fiscal transfers within the European

3

See also Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1992).

-3Union. Differences across countries in the nature and strength of the monetary policy
transmission mechanism are another factor that may reduce the attractiveness of a
4

monetary union. However, some more recent assessments, which have emphasized
factors such as the high propensity of European countries to trade with each other and the
increased coherence of national business cycles within Europe, have generally been more
favorable (Alesina, Barro, and Tenreyro, 2002; Agresti and Mojon, 2001). Of course,
analyses that look only at historical conditions ignore the important possibility that
monetary union itself may induce endogenous changes in trade propensities, the pattern
of macroeconomic shocks, and other components ofthe Mundellian analysis, a point that
Eichengreen and many other authors have made.
Rather than pursuing the question of whether Europe is in fact an optimal
currency area in Mundell's sense, I think it is useful simply to recognize that the
European experiment in economic and monetary union has not been motivated primarily
by Mundellian factors. (Mundell himself did not expect that such considerations would
be sufficient to lead to monetary unions, as the quote with which I began suggests.)
Political factors, rather than economic ones, have played the dominant role. The nations
of Europe share a remarkable cultural heritage in philosophy, politics, science, religion,
and the arts, and advanced thinkers have long recognized that this common heritage
might serve as a basis for the formation of a cohesive European political entity. Such an
entity presumably could influence world events and provide for a common defense more
effectively than could a collection of nation-states. Indeed, political and economic
integration within regions of Europe has occurred on a number of occasions--for

The volume edited by Angeloni, Kashyap, and Mojon (2003) documents these
differences in detail.
4

- 4-

example, in Gennany and Italy. Another important motivation for political integration
has been the desire to reduce the risk of intra-European conflict. From Napoleon to
Bismarck to the Kaiser to Hitler, Franco-Prussian and then Franco-Gennan conflicts were
flash points for continentwide and worldwide wars. European economic and monetary
union holds the promise of binding so closely the economic interests of these two powers,
as well as those of other European nations, as to make future intra-European conflict
unthinkable. Such arguments have been part ofthe debate over European integration at
least since the 1957 Treaty of Rome. Indeed, the hope ofpolicymakers is to create a
virtuous circle, in which closer economic integration promotes greater political
cooperation, which enhances opportunities for economic integration, and so on. s
The largely political origin of the union has several implications for the economic
analysis of the common currency. First, from a-purely economic point of view, the
creation of the European economic and monetary union is at least partly an exogenous
event. Thus, we have something of a natural experiment from which to learn about the
effects of such institutional innovations. Second, we should keep in mind that our
assessment of the success of the euro, indeed of the entire experiment in European
integration, rests not only on economic criteria but also on the success of Europe as a
political entity.
Ifwe think of the introduction of the euro as representing to some degree a natural
experiment in monetary economics, what can we say about the costs and benefits, at least
thus far, of this sweeping institutional change? We can look in a number of areas for

5 The importance of political factors in the European economic union has also been
illustrated by the importance of non-economic considerations in the debates about joining
the union in nations such as Sweden and the United Kingdom.

t"

-5-

effects of monetary unification, including the patterns of trade, developments in the
financial sector, changes in macroeconomic stability, and the international role ofthe new
currency. Many ofthese areas have already been examined today in much greater detail
than I can do here. Rather than trying to be exhaustive, I will instead assert and briefly
defend a hypothesis. The hypothesis is that the most significant effects of monetary
unification have been felt, and will continue to be felt, in the development of European
financial markets, and that the greatest economic benefits to Europe in the long run will
accrue through the improved functioning of these markets.
To defend this hypothesis, I need first to consider briefly the effects of monetary
unification in some other key areas. Let us begin with trade. The debate about monetary
unification was influenced to some extent by a tradition of empirical research that
provided some basis for optimism about the effects of a common currency on trade. For
example, the extensive literature on so-called border effects concluded that nations trade
with each other far less than would be expected based on the extent of trade between
regions within a country, opening up the possibility that differing national currencies are
among the factors that inhibit trade. In a recent study, Reuven Glick and Andrew Rose
(2001) provided some support for the idea that currency unions promote trade. Glick and
Rose analyzed a panel data set of 217 countries for the period 1948 through 1997. They
found that entering or leaving a currency union had large effects on trade flows; indeed,
they estimated that a pair of countries that begins to use a common currency should see a
doubling in bilateral trade. However, as Glick and Rose themselves note, many of the
countries entering or leaving currency unions during their sample period were small and
poor, not rich and (in some cases) large like the nations of western Europe. Moreover,

- 6their analysis does not rule out either reverse causality (that is, that increasing trade may
promote the adoption of a currency union, rather than vice versa) or the possibility that a
third, unmeasured factor (such as political relationships) may have influenced both trade
and currency policies.
In contrast to the findings of Glick and Rose, evidence drawn directly from the
recent European experience does not generally support the view that adoption of a
common currency has a major effect on the magnitude or direction of trade. 6 True, euroarea exports did surge after the adoption ofthe euro in January 1999. However, cyclical
conditions and the early weakness ofthe new currency no doubt played a critical role in
that increase, an inference confirmed by the substantial slowing in European export
growth since the beginning of2001. Also striking is the fact that the share of total euroarea exports destined for other members of the euro-zone did not increase with the
introduction of the new currency, as would be likely if the common currency promoted
trade. Indeed, at about 50 percent of total exports, the intra-euro-area export share today
remains noticeably below the recent peak of about 57 percent reached in the early 1990s.
The most decisive evidence on the trade question can be found by looking at
micro data. In an important study, John Rogers (2003) of the Board staff analyzed annual
data on the prices of 139 items, collected by the Economist Intelligence Unit for twentyfive European and thirteen U.S. cities. For his main results, Rogers divided the items into
traded and non-traded categories, though he considered many other ways of slicing the
data as well. He then analyzed the cross-city dispersion of prices in each year. Of
course, the reduction of barriers to trade, the harmonization of tax policies, and the

6 Micco, Stein, and Ordonez (2003), using bilateral trade data from the early years of the
monetary union, find modest trade-enhancing effects.

-7increased efficiency of cross-national markets should lead to reduced dispersion in the
prices of goods, especially actively traded goods, as competition and arbitrage reduce
local monopoly power and differences in prices.
Rogers found a substantial decline in the dispersion oftraded-goods prices across
European cities over 1990-2001. Indeed, by the end of the period, the variability of
traded goods prices across cities within EMU countries had declined by more than half,
and it was not substantially different from the variability found among cities in the United
States. This convergence of prices suggests a powerful, ongoing process of increased
economic integration and elimination of barriers to trade among the members of the
European Monetary Union. Crucially, however, Rogers found that the bulk ofthis
convergence occurred between 1990 and 1994, the period of the "single market"
initiative. Only a small part of the convergence in traded goods prices occurred after
1998, the period during which the euro was introduced and national currencies were
withdrawn from circulation. Rogers' evidence therefore suggests that the increased
integration of product markets in Europe has been an ongoing process, which may have
been assisted by the adoption of the euro but for which a common currency has hardly
proved essential.
A second question of interest is the degree to which adoption of the euro has
affected macroeconomic stability in the euro zone. In Mundell's taxonomy, adoption of a
common currency is a strictly negative factor for stability because it eliminates the shockabsorbing features of flexible exchange rates and independent monetary policies. In fact,
however, the effects of the common currency on macroeconomic stability in Europe have
been positive as well as negative. Notably, the structure and mandate of the European

-8Central Bank (ECB), as well as the perception of continuity with the policies of the preeuro Bundesbank, have enhanced the ECB's credibility and contributed to low and stable
inflation in the euro-zone. Although Gennany and several other countries in the union
enjoyed low inflation before the adoption ofthe common currency, with some partial
exceptions to be discussed in a moment, the ECB has been able to "export" that benefit to
other members of the monetary union. The common currency has also eliminated
periodic exchange-rate crises, which had plagued European monetary arrangements and
generated real and financial disturbances at least since the days of the gold standard.
On the other hand, the ECB has faced the challenge of making policy for Europe
as a whole despite differing macroeconomic conditions in member countries, a dilemma
that Mundell would have predicted. For example, since 1999 a few countries, such as
Ireland, have had inflation rates consistently above the euro-zone average. Trish inflation
peaked at 7 percent on a twelve-month basis in November 2000 and has since been in the
4 to 5 percent range. At the same time, other countries, such as Gennany, have
experienced low--perhaps uncomfortably low--rates ofinflation. 7 Patrick Honohan and
Philip Lane (2003) investigated the sources of relatively high inflation in Ireland after the
adoption of the euro. These authors found that the loss of exchange-rate flexibility and
monetary autonomy played important roles in the Irish inflation. For example, a
relatively large share ofIreland's trade is with non-European partners, so that the early
weakness of the euro stimulated Irish exports and economic activity disproportionately.
Ireland was also unable to resort to monetary restraint to cool down an economy that, for

Some cross-country differences in inflation might simply reflect convergence in price
levels, resulting from the Balassa-Samuelson effect or from initial conversion factors
from national currencies to the euro not precisely consistent with the law of one price for
tradables. Rogers (2003) finds some evidence for the latter effect but not the fonner.
7

-9-

a variety of reasons, was experiencing faster demand growth than most of the rest of
Europe. s Ireland's relatively high inflation rate may in turn have had destabilizing
effects, because, in combination with low pan-European nominal interest rates, it implied
that the Irish economy faced a negative real rate of interest. One possible consequence of
the low real rate is the boom in Irish property prices, which has fed back into higher
domestic spending. Of course, at the other end of the spectrum, Germany has
experienced weak growth and very low inflation in the past few years (Sinn, 2003).
Without the ability to use stabilizing monetary policy, Germany has eased fiscal policy
and thus has come into conflict with its obligations under the Stability and Growth Pact.
In short, with respect to macroeconomic stability, the common currency appears

to have had both positive and negative effects. More time will be needed before we can
assess whether the common currency will ultimately be a stabilizing or a destabilizing
influence at the macroeconomic level.
Yet a third area in which potential benefits of the euro have often been cited is in
respect to the common currency's potential international role. The phrase "international
role ofthe euro" covers a number of disparate possible functions of the currency. These
functions include the use of euro-denominated assets as official reserves, the use of the
euro as a vehicle currency in foreign-exchange transactions, the denomination in euros of
financing instruments issued by borrowers not resident in the euro zone, the acceptance
of euro-denominated or euro-linked assets in international investment portfolios, and the
invoicing in euros of internationally traded goods and services. Of course, during the
post-World War II period the U.S. dollar has been the dominant international currency

Of course, fiscal policy remained available, though most economists agree that fiscal
policy is less effective than monetary policy as a short-run stabilization tool.
8

- 10with respect to each of these functions. It seems plausible that the euro, a low-inflation
currency used by an economy comparable to that ofthe United States in size and
sophistication, will, over time, increase its "market share" in each of these areas.
However, the euro's potential international role, and, more importantly, the benefits to
euro-zone countries of an increased role for the euro differ significantly by function.
A summary evaluation of the euro's international position is that the common
currency's role has been increasing but that so far the euro has posed less of a challenge
to the U.S. dollar as an international medium of exchange than some analysts expected.
For example, in foreign exchange markets the U.S. dollar accounts for nearly 50 percent
of transaction "sides," compared with about 25 percent for the euro, implying that the
overwhelming majority of foreign-exchange transactions involve the dollar (European
Central Bank, 2003, p. 26; data are from Continuous Linked Settlement). Hence, the
dollar appears to remain the international "vehicle currency," serving as a temporary
abode of value for foreign-exchange transactions involving third currencies, whereas the
euro's role in foreign-exchange markets is similar to that played in earlier times by the
deutschemark (Solans, 2003). The dollar also remains the dominant invoicing currency
for internationally traded raw materials, such as oil. The dollar is even dominant in U.S.European trade, with more than 90 percent of U.S. exports to Europe and something more
than 80 percent of European exports to the United States being invoiced in dollars as of
September 2003 (European Central Bank, 2003, p. 33). With regard to the currency
composition of official reserves, dollar-denominated assets accounted for 64.5 percent of
world reserves at the end of2002, down from 67.5 percent at the end of2000. During the

- 11 -

same period, the euro's share of international reserves rose from 15.9 percent to 18.7
percent (European Central Bank, 2003, p. 45).
Although economists and financial market participants will observe the
developing role ofthe euro in international transactions with interest, the direct benefits
to euro-zone economies of having the euro play an international medium-of-exchange
role are relatively modest. Arguably, the more significant aspects of the euro's
international role arise from the strengthening and expansion of euro-denominated
financial markets as these markets take on a greater international character.
Internationalization of European financial markets increases investment opportunities,
opportunities for diversification, and sources of funding and improves liquidity and
market efficiency. On that note, let me tum finally to the effect of the common currency
on European financial markets.
As I have already suggested, the most important benefit of the currency union has
been and will likely continue to be its strengthening of European financial markets.
Traditionally, the efficiency and scope of these markets has been hampered by the costs
and risks associated with the use of multiple currencies as well as by the fragmentation
arising from international differences in legal structure, accounting rules, and other
institutions. Given the rapidity and frequency of trade in financial markets, even small
transaction costs can hamper the efficiency and liquidity of those markets. The common
currency, with ongoing efforts to harmonize financial regulations and institutions, has
significantly reduced those transaction costs. Together with lower country-specific
macro risks arising from the adoption of the common currency, this reduction in

- 12 transaction costs has greatly improved the breadth and efficiency of European financial
markets.
Importantly, the benefit of more efficient financial markets goes well beyond the
benefits to financial investors and the financial industry itself. A growing academic
literature suggests that financial development is a critical precursor to broader economic
development (King and Levine, 1993). In this vein, a study for the European
Commission estimated that financial development that brought the European financial
system close to u.s. nonns might add almost a percentage point to the growth of value
added in manufacturing in the European Union (Giannetti et aI., 2002). Whether one
accepts this optimistic assessment or not, there are evidently significant potential benefits
to financial deepening that go beyond the financial sector itself.
How has the common currency improved financial efficiency? Perhaps the most
dramatic effects of the monetary union in the financial sphere have been in fixed-income
markets, both government and private. Government debt markets, because of their size,
safety, and benchmark status, are central to a vibrant fixed-income market, and they have
been particularly strengthened by the adoption of the euro. Notably, since the run-up to
monetary union began, sovereign debt yields have converged to a remarkable extent. For
example, between 1990 and 1996, spreads on Italian and Spanish government bonds,
relative to Gennan bonds of comparable maturity, averaged about 430 and 350 basis
points, respectively. Today the spreads paid by these governments are quite small, in the
vicinity of 15 basis points over the German equivalent for Italy and essentially zero for

- 13 Spain. 9 Clearly, these governments have benefited substantially by the reduction in
inflation risk and exchange rate risk provided by the common currency. 10 The addition of
some sovereign default risk (now relevant because individual countries are no longer able
to inflate away their debts) has evidently not offset these benefits, perhaps because of the
effects of the Stability and Growth Pact.
Beyond improving the fundamentals of government finances, the common
currency has also increased the depth and breadth of government bond markets. In
particular, the development of a large market in euro-denominated government debt and
the resulting expansion in cross-border holdings of debt has improved market liquidity
and opportunities for risk sharing. For example, in their excellent survey of
developments in European financial markets since the introduction of the euro, Gabriele
Galati and Kostas Tsatsaronis (2003, p. 174) note that nonresident holdings of French
government bonds rose from about 15 percent at the end of 1997 to about 35 percent by
2002. Moreover, as of2002, foreigners held three-quarters of Belgian government longterm bonds and 63 percent of Irish government debt. A broader investor clientele implies
more potential bidders in primary markets and more transactions in secondary markets,
improving liquidity. This broadening is the sense in which an international role for the
euro, by which here I mean more internationalized European financial markets, seems to
promise the greatest potential benefits.

So-called "convergence plays" proved very profitable for financial investors who bet on
the success of the European Monetary Union and its implication that government debt
spreads would largely disappear.
10 It is interesting, however, that even nonmembers such as Sweden and the United
Kingdom have seen their bond yields converge to the German benchmark since about
1997 or 1998.

9

- 14The European government bond market has been substantially strengthened by
the adoption of the common currency, but it has not attained the liquidity of the U.S.
Treasury market (and may never do so). Although aggregate issuance of euro-zone
government debt is of the same order of magnitude as U.S. Treasury issues, there remains
the fundamental difference that euro-zone debt is the debt of twelve sovereign entities,
rather than one as in the United States. Naturally, the Stability and Growth Pact
notwithstanding, the European Union accepts no collective responsibility for the debts of
individual governments. Moreover, so far coordination of issuance schedules, the
structure of issues, and other technical details has been limited. However, opportunities
for further strengthening of the euro-zone government bond market appear to remain.
For example, if the technical details can be worked out, one can imagine the issuance of
securities backed by the obligations of multiple European governments. These securities
could be made uniform by fixing the country shares ofthe underlying debt, or by
stripping off country-specific default risks through such instruments as credit default
swaps. Such securities would provide a benchmark yield curve, among other advantages.
The benefits of the euro for government bond markets have carried over to
corporate bond markets as well. Issuance of euro-denominated bonds by corporations
took off soon after the introduction of the new currency. Although much of the boom no
doubt reflected general macroeconomic conditions and other factors, potential access to a
much larger base of investors willing to hold bonds in the common currency and resulting
improvements in pricing and liquidity also played a role. Underwriting costs have also
fallen, the result of both greater competition and the reduced costs of bringing issues to
market (Santos and Tsatsaronis, 2003). The rapid development of Europe's corporate

- 15 bond market, including a nascent high-yield market, should prove highly beneficial to
European economic development.
The benefits of the common currency for other types of securities markets have
been more mixed thus far, but the potential is there. The European interbank market was
strengthened substantially in tandem with the creation of the Eurosystem of central
banks. In contrast, markets for securities lending (repo markets) remain somewhat
fragmented, and commercial paper markets are underdeveloped. European stock
markets, which in any case account for a smaller share of financing activity than in the
United States, have not been successfully harmonized thus far, and cross-border equity
investments may still involve high transaction costs (McAndrews and Stefanadis, 2002).
However, it is widely observed that the perspectives and strategies of European equity
analysts have changed, toward a de-emphasis on country-specific factors and greater
attention to industry and company factors in the valuation of stocks (Adjaoute and
Danthine, 2002). This change indicates that financial market participants see increased
financial and economic integration in Europe as an irreversible trend. Efforts to adhere to
the Lamfalussy Process, which aims to streamline the harmonization process for financial
market legislation and regulation, should hasten the integration of European securities
markets.
European finance has traditionally been bank-centered. What will happen to
banks in the new regime? Banks may lose some loan customers to the growing securities
markets, but they will also benefit from increased access to finance, both in the interbank
market and in the corporate bond market. Indeed, the banks were large players in the
early boom in the issuance of euro-denominated corporate bonds, accounting for more

- 16 than half the new issues thus far (Galati and Tsatsaronis, 2003, p. 181). On the lending
side, banks' local knowledge and specialized services should allow them to retain an
important market share. In a study that illustrated the importance of banks' knowledge of
local conditions, Allen Berger and David Smith (2003) found that European affiliates of
multinational corporations strongly prefer working with a bank in the country oftheir
operation, rather than a bank from the country of the multinational's corporate
headquarters. Moreover, having chosen a bank in the country of operations, the affiliates
were more likely to select a bank with local or regional operations than a bank with
global reach. These results are consistent with the view that bankers' competitive
advantage relative to security markets is their knowledge oflocal firms, markets, and
economic conditions and their ability to establish long-term relationships with local
customers. Perhaps the European banking situation will begin to look more like that of
the United States, where borrowing through securities issuance and banking co-exist,
providing different services and meeting the needs of different clienteles. Moreover, the
composition of banks may settle into the pattern of the United States, where very large
banks with a global reach and the capacity to engineer highly complex transactions and
community banks that specialize in lending to the local area have both found room to
flourish. However banking may evolve in Europe, increased financial integration that
makes local banking markets more "contestable" will likely improve the efficiency with
which local banking services are delivered
My remarks this evening have only scratched the surface of a large topic, but it
seems safe to conclude that the common currency has had and will continue to have large
benefits for European finance. At a minimum, the single currency eliminates exchange-

- 17 rate risks that exist when securities are denominated in different currencies. The single
unit of account seems also likely to reduce transaction costs and eliminate a portion of the
fixed costs involved in issuing similar securities in multiple currencies. These factors are
already serving to moderate home bias in borrowing and lending, leading to larger, moreliquid, and more-diversified financial markets.
Clearly, a great deal more work needs to be done, both by the government and by
the private sector, to realize the full benefits of the common currency for European
finance. Beyond the markets that I have mentioned as needing special attention, like
equity markets, further hannonization is also required to coordinate national systems for
payments, clearing, and settlement. A larger and more integrated financial system may
carry greater systemic risks and raise new challenges for the system of financial oversight
and supervision. Further challenges will arise as new countries, including those currently
at a relatively low level of financial development, join the European monetary system.
Their accession will greatly complicate the hannonization process, but given what we
know about the role of finance in economic development, the benefits for both the new
members and the current ones could be very large.

- 18 -

References
Adjaoute, Kpate, and Jean-Pierre Danthine (2002). "European Financial Integration and
Equity Returns: A Theory-Based Assessment," paper prepared for the Second ECB
Central Banking Conference on "The Transformation of the European Financial System,"
October 24-25, Frankfurt-am-Main
Agresti, Anna-Maria, and Benoit Mojon (2001). "Some Stylized Facts on the Euro Area
Business Cycle," European Central Bank working paper no. 95 (December).
Alesina, Alberto, Robert Barro, and Silvana Tenreyro (2002). "Optimal Currency
Areas," National Bureau of Economic Research working paper no. 9072 (July).
Angeloni, Ignazio, Anil Kashyap, and Benoit Mojon, eds. (2003). Monetary Policy
Transmission in the Euro Area, Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Bayoumi, Tamim, and Barry Eichengreen (1992). "Shocking Aspects of European
Monetary Unification," National Bureau of Economic Research working paper no. 3949
(January).
Berger, Allen, and David Smith (2003). "Global Integration in the Banking Industry,"
Federal Reserve Bulletin, 89 (November), pp. 451-60.
Eichengreen, Barry (1992). "Is Europe an Optimum Currency Area?" in Silvio Bomer
and Herbert Grubel, eds., The European Community after 1992. London: Macmillan, pp.
138-61.
European Central Bank (2003). Review of the International Role of the Euro, Frankfurtam-Main, December.
Galati, Gabriele, and Kostas Tsatsaronis (2003). "The Impact of the Euro on Europe's
Financial Markets," Financial Markets, Institutions, and Instruments, 12 (August), pp.
165-221.
Giannetti, Mariassunta, Luigi Guiso, Tullio Jappelli, Mario Padula, and Marco Pagano
(2002). "Financial Market Integration, Corporate Financing and Economic Growth,"
European Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs,
Economic Paper no. 179 (November).
Glick, Reuven and Andrew Rose (2001). 'Does a Currency Union Affect Trade? The
Time Series Evidence," National Bureau of Economic Research working paper no. 8396
(July).

- 19 Honohan, Patrick, and Philip Lane (2003). "Divergent Inflation Rates in EMU," working
paper, World Bank and Trinity College (October).
,

King, Robert, and Ross Levine (1993). "Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be
Right," Quarterly Journal of Economics (108), pp. 717-37.
McAndrews, James, and Chris Stefanadis (2002). "The Consolidation of European Stock
Exchanges," Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Current Issues in Economics and
Finance (8), June.
McKinnon, Ronald (1963). "Optimum Currency Areas," American Economic Review, 53
(September), pp. 717-25.
Micco, Alejandro, Ernesto Stein, and Guillermo Ordonez (2003). "The Currency Union
Effect on Trade: Early Evidence from EMU," Economic Policy (October), pp. 315-56.
Mundell, Robert (1961). "A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas," American Economic
Review, 51 (September), pp. 657-65.
Rogers, John H. (2003). "Monetary Union, Price Level Convergence, and Inflation: How
Close is Europe to the United States?" working paper, International Finance Division,
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
Santos, Joao, and Kostas Tsatsaronis (2003). "The Cost of Barriers to Entry: Evidence
from the Market for Corporate Bond Underwriting," Federal Reserve Bank of New York
and Bank for International Settlements, working paper.
Solans, Eugenio (2003). "The International Role of the Euro in a Globalised Economy,"
speech delivered at the Pareto Securities Economic Conference, Oslo, March 27
(http://www.ech.intlkey/03/sp030327.htm) .

Sinn, Hans-Werner (2003). "The Laggard of Europe," CESifo Forum, 4, Special Issue
(Spring) .

•