View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
9:00 a.m. EDT
August 6, 2012

Economic Measurement

Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
via Prerecorded Video
to the
32nd General Conference of the
International Association for Research in Income and Wealth
Cambridge, Massachusetts

August 6, 2012

I appreciate the opportunity to speak at a conference with the important theme of
economic measurement. In many spheres of human endeavor, from science to business
to education to economic policy, good decisions depend on good measurement. More
subtly, what we decide to measure, or are able to measure, has important effects on the
choices we make, since it is natural to focus on those objectives for which we can best
estimate and document the effects of our decisions. One great pioneer in this subject
area, of course, is Simon Kuznets, who was awarded the Nobel Prize in 1971 for his work
on economic measurement, including the national income accounts. Over the years many
economists have built on his work to further improve our ability to quantify aspects of
economic activity and thus to improve economic policymaking and our understanding of
how the economy works. The remarkably broad and ambitious research program of this
conference and the impressive expertise that has been assembled illustrate the continued
vitality of this field. Evolving technologies that allow economists to gather new types of
data and to manipulate millions of data points are just one factor among several that are
likely to transform the field in coming years.
As we think about new directions for economic measurement, we might start by
reminding ourselves of the purpose of economics. Textbooks describe economics as the
study of the allocation of scarce resources. That definition may indeed be the “what,” but
it certainly is not the “why.” The ultimate purpose of economics, of course, is to
understand and promote the enhancement of well-being. Economic measurement
accordingly must encompass measures of well-being and its determinants.
In the tradition of national income accounting, economic policymakers have
typically focused on variables such as income, wealth, and consumption. The Federal

-2Reserve has a statutory mandate to foster maximum employment and price stability,
which motivates our extensive efforts to monitor and forecast measures of employment
and inflation. Substantial research and the development of data collection infrastructures
have, over the years, greatly enhanced our ability to receive timely and accurate measures
of those variables. Aggregate measures, such as gross domestic product and personal
consumption expenditures, are useful for monitoring people’s ability to meet basic
material needs and for tracking cyclical and secular changes in the economy as a whole.
Indeed, the experience of the recent financial crisis and the ensuing recession was
strongly reflected in nearly all of these aggregate measures, indicating the severe
economic stress felt by millions of people and hundreds of communities across the
country.
But, as many of you will discuss this week, aggregate statistics can sometimes
mask important information. For example, even though some key aggregate
metrics--including consumer spending, disposable income, household net worth, and debt
service payments--have moved in the direction of recovery, it is clear that many
individuals and households continue to struggle with difficult economic and financial
conditions. Exclusive attention to aggregate numbers is likely to paint an incomplete
picture of what many individuals are experiencing. One implication is that we should
increase the attention paid to microeconomic data, which better capture the diversity of
experience across households and firms. Another implication, however, is that we should
seek better and more-direct measurements of economic well-being, the ultimate objective
of our policy decisions.

-3Although the field is still young, there have been interesting developments in the
measurement of economic well-being. In a commencement address two years ago titled
“The Economics of Happiness,” I spoke about the concepts of happiness and life
satisfaction from the perspective of economics and other social science research.1
Following the growing literature, I define “happiness” as a short-term state of awareness
that depends on a person’s perceptions of one’s immediate reality, as well as on
immediate external circumstances and outcomes. By “life satisfaction” I mean a longerterm state of contentment and well-being that results from a person’s experiences over
time. Surveys and experimental studies have made progress in identifying the
determinants of happiness and life satisfaction. Interestingly, income and wealth do
contribute to self-reported happiness, but the relationship is more complex and contextdependent than standard utility theory would suggest.2 Other important contributors to
individuals’ life satisfaction are a strong sense of support from belonging to a family or
core group and a broader community, a sense of control over one’s life, a feeling of
confidence or optimism about the future, and an ability to adapt to changing
circumstances. Indeed, an interesting finding in the literature is that the overwhelming
majority of people in the United States and in many other countries report being very
happy or pretty happy on a daily basis--a finding that researchers link to people’s intrinsic
abilities to adapt and find satisfaction in their lives even in very difficult circumstances.3

1

See Ben S. Bernanke (2010), “The Economics of Happiness,” speech delivered at the University of South
Carolina commencement ceremony, Columbia, S.C., May 8,
www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20100508a.htm.
2
Canonical models of economic decisionmaking presume individual maximization of “utility,” or wellbeing. They tend to focus on the consumption of goods or services and assume that more consumption is
preferred to less. For example, see Andrew Mas-Colell, Michael D. Whinston, and Jerry R Green (1995),
Microeconomic Theory (New York: Oxford University Press).
3
For examples drawn from Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development countries from the
mid-1970s to the mid-1990s, see Rafael Di Tella and Robert MacCulloch (2008), “Gross National

-4This line of research has generated alternative measures of well-being that are
frequently survey-based and incorporate elements such as psychological wellness, the
level of education, physical health and safety, community vitality and the strength of
family and social ties, and time spent in leisure activities. These measures have begun to
inform official statistics and have started to be discussed in policy debates. An
interesting and unique case is the Kingdom of Bhutan, which abandoned tracking gross
national product in 1972 in favor of its Gross National Happiness index based on a
survey that incorporates these types of indicators. Taking the measurement of well-being
in a cross-country framework, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and
Development (OECD), as part of its OECD Better Life Initiative, has created a “better
life index” that allows a side-by-side comparison of countries according to various
quality-of-life indicators that could, at least in principle, be followed over time.4 Other
somewhat-more-conventional economic indicators that bear on quality of life, and that
accordingly might be developed and followed in more detail, include changes in the
distribution of income, wealth, or consumption; the degree of upward mobility in material
measures of well-being; indications of job security and confidence about future
employment prospects; and households’ liquidity buffers or other measures of their
ability to absorb financial shocks. All of these indicators could be useful in measuring
economic progress or setbacks as well as in explaining economic decisionmaking or
projecting future economic outcomes.

Happiness as an Answer to the Easterlin Paradox?” Journal of Development Economics, vol. 86 (April),
pp. 22-42. For a survey of evidence on adaptability, see Shane Frederick and George Loewenstein (1999),
“Hedonic Adaptation,” in Daniel Kahneman, Ed Diener, and Norbert Schwarz, eds., Well-Being: The
Foundations of Hedonic Psychology (New York: Russell Sage Foundation), pp. 302-29.
4
See Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (2011), How’s Life? Measuring WellBeing (Washington: OECD Publishing).

-5Continued work on the measurement of economic well-being will likely lead to
greater recognition by economists of the contributions of psychology--an area that has
been explored by pioneers like 2002 Nobel laureate Daniel Kahneman. One topic on the
frontier of economics and psychology is the neurological basis of human decisions,
including decisionmaking under risk and uncertainty, intertemporal choice, and social
decisionmaking.5 Researchers are investigating behavioral tendencies in a variety of
circumstances--for instance, by examining human responses to perceived inequality,
losses, risk, and uncertainty; the need for autonomy; and the importance for well-being of
social ties and community. For example, brain imaging research has documented
differences in the brain regions that light up in response to losses and gains--a clear
physical manifestation of the “loss aversion” documented in the earlier behavioral studies
in economics and psychology.6 Evolutionary psychologists suggest that humans
experienced evolutionary benefits from brain developments that included aversion to loss
and risk, and from instincts for cooperation that helped strengthen communities.
Measurement of well-being is an important direction, but just one of many new
directions for economic measurement being explored in the field generally and at this
conference in particular. I am glad to see scholars and practitioners continuing to push
the frontiers of economic measurement with a broad perspective and with open minds.
As Arthur Conan Doyle’s immortal character Sherlock Holmes aptly put it, “It is a capital
mistake to theorize before one has data.”7 As I said at the beginning, good economic
5

For example, see George Loewenstein, Scott Rick, and Jonathan D. Cohen (2008), “Neuroeconomics,”
Annual Review of Psychology, vol. 59 (January), pp. 647-72.
6
See Sabrina M. Tom, Craig R. Fox, Christopher Trepel, and Russell A. Poldrack (2007), “The Neural
Basis of Loss Aversion in Decision-Making under Risk,” Science, vol. 315 (January), pp. 515-18.
7
See Arthur Conan Doyle ([1892] 1900), “A Scandal in Bohemia,” in The Adventures of Sherlock Holmes
(New York: Harper & Brothers), p. 7, available at
http://books.google.com/books?id=RxAJAAAAIAAJ&printsec=frontcover&dq=adventures+of+sherlock+

-6analysis and policymaking depend on good measurement, and the work you are doing
will accordingly yield significant benefits. I thank you for the opportunity to give these
short remarks, and I wish you the best for a productive and stimulating conference.

holmes&source=bl&ots=tr8SxsUQhJ&sig=8d1uYsvD13W5iU5T66tnzUFbOc&hl=en#v=onepage&q=It%20is%20a%20capital%20mistake%20to%20theorize
%20before%20one%20has%20data&f=false.