View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 a.m. EDT
June 16,2008

Challenges for Health-Care Reform

Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Senate Finance Committee Health Reform Summit
Washington, D.C.

June 16,2008

Improving the performance of our health-care system is without a doubt one of
the most important challenges that our nation faces. In recent decades, improvements in
medical knowledge and standards of care have allowed people to live healthier, longer,
and more productive lives. New medical technologies and treatments promise more and
better to come. From a social point of view, we hope as many people as possible benefit
from these advances. But health care is not only a scientific and social issue; it is an
economic issue as well. The decisions we make about health-care reform will affect
many aspects of our economy, including the pace of economic growth, wages and living
standards, and government budgets, to name a few.
By any measure, the health-care sector represents a major segment of our
economy. Spending on health-care services currently exceeds 15 percent ofthe gross
domestic product (GDP). Indeed, health-care spending is the single largest component of
personal consumption--Iarger than spending on either housing or food. Importantly,
health care also has long been, and continues to be, one of the fastest-growing sectors in
the economy: Over the past four decades, this sector has grown, on average, at a rate of
about 2-112 percentage points faster than the GDP. Should this rate of growth continue,
health spending would exceed 22 percent of GDP by 2020 and reach almost 30 percent of
GDP by 2030. 1
Health-related spending is also a large and growing share of government budgets.
Last year, health care accounted for about one-quarter of total federal spending. The
Congressional Budget Office (CBO) projects that, under current policies, health spending
will account for almost one-half of all federal non-interest outlays by 2050?

I

2

Congressional Budget Office (2007).
Ibid.

- 2-

As the public interest in these issues testifies, the stakes associated with healthcare reform, both economic and social, are very high. But we must keep in mind that, for
all its problems, the U.S. health-care system also has many strengths. We must take care
that we do not lose what is good about our system as we try to address the significant
concerns that certainly exist.
In the remainder of my remarks, I will discuss three key challenges for health-care
reform. These challenges are, in short, the issues of access, quality, and cost.
Challenges for Health-Care Reform

Access
Access to health care is the first major challenge that health-care reform must
address. In 2006, a total of 47 million Americans, or almost 16 percent of the population,
lacked health insurance. Although the federal and state governments spent more than $35
billion to finance uncompensated care in 2004, the evidence nonetheless indicates that
uninsured persons receive less health care than those who are insured and that their health
suffers as a consequence. Per capita expenditures on health care for uninsured
individuals are, on average, roughly half those for fully insured individuals. 3 People who
are uninsured are less likely to receive preventive and screening services, less likely to
receive appropriate care to manage chronic illnesses, and more likely to die prematurely
from cancer--Iargely because they tend to be diagnosed when the disease is more
advanced. 4 One recent study found that uninsured victims of automobile accidents

3
4

Hadley and Holohan (2004).
Institute of Medicine (2002).

-3receive 20 percent less treatment in hospitals and are 37 percent more likely to die of
their injuries than those who are insured. 5
Quality
The second key challenge is improving the quality of health care. The quality of
medical research, training, and technology in the United States is generally very high.
However, the quality of health care is determined not only by, say, technological
advances in preventing and treating disease but also by our ability to deliver the benefits
of those advances to patients. For maximum impact, advances in medical knowledge
must be widely disseminated and consistently and efficiently implemented. But evidence
suggests a disturbing gap between the quality of health services that can be provided in
principle and the quality of health services that actually are provided in practice. For
example, in 2000, the Institute of Medicine issued a landmark report that concluded that
up to 98,000 Americans died each year in hospitals as a result of medical errors. 6 Many
of the errors identified by the report--for example, errors caused by adverse drug events,
improper transfusions, wrong-site surgery, and mistaken patient identity--could have
been prevented if hospitals had adopted appropriate safety systems. Although hospitals
have implemented a number of new safety practices since the time of that report, the
scope for improving patient safety remains large.?
Inconsistent use of best practices by doctors and hospitals is also surprisingly
widespread. For example, numerous studies have pointed to the lack of adherence to
evidence-based guidelines for the treatment of heart attacks. In particular, it has long
been well established that restoring blood flow to the heart and using aspirin, beta
Doyle (2005).
Institute of Medicine (2000).
7 Leape and Berwick (2005).

5

6

-4blockers, and ACE inhibitors at the appropriate times significantly reduce deaths
resulting from heart attacks. 8 Yet studies show that the dissemination of these treatments
occurred only slowly.9 More widespread application of evidence-based medicine could
help health-care workers make better use of the medical knowledge they already have to
improve patients' outcomes.
Although some patients do not receive the care they need, others receive more
(and more expensive) care than necessary. Research on geographic variation in healthcare practices and costs confirms this point. For example, Medicare expenditures per
eligible recipient vary widely across regions, yet areas with the highest expenditures do
not appear to have better health outcomes than those with the lowest expenditures;
indeed, the reverse seems to be true. IO

Cost
This observation brings me to a third important challenge for health-care reform:
controlling costs. The problem here is not only the current level of health-care spending
(U.S. spending exceeds that of most other industrial countries) but, to an even greater
degree, the continued rapid growth of that spending. Per capita health-care spending in
the United States has increased at a faster rate than per capita income for a number of
decades. Should that trend continue, as many economists predict it will, the share of
income devoted to paying for health care will rise relentlessly. A piece of wisdom
attributed to the economist Herbert Stein holds that if something cannot go on forever, it
will stop. At some point, health-care spending as a share of GDP will stop rising, but it is
difficult to guess when that will be, and there is little sign of it yet.
Beta blockers and ACE inhibitors are drugs that relieve stress on the heart.
Joint Commission (2007).
10 Skinner, Staiger, and Fischer (2006).

8

9

-5-

Although the high cost of health care is a frequently heard complaint, it is
important to note that a substantial portion of the cost increases that we have seen in
recent decades reflects improvements in both the quality and quantity of care delivered
rather than higher costs of delivering a given level of care. Notably, new technologies,
despite greatly adding to cost in many cases, have also yielded significant benefits in the
form of better health. People put great value on their health, and it is not surprising that,
as our society becomes wealthier, we would choose to spend more on health-care
services. Indeed, although quantifying the economic value of improved health and
greater expected longevity is difficult, most researchers who have undertaken an exercise
of this type find that, on average, the health benefits of new technologies and other
advances have significantly exceed the economic costs. II
That said, the evidence also suggests that the cost of health care in the United
States is greater than necessary to allow us to achieve the levels of health and longevity
we now enjoy. I have already mentioned research that finds large regional differences in
the cost of treating a given condition, with high-cost areas showing no better results. The
slow diffusion of the use of aspirin and beta blockers for treating heart-attack patients
shows that cheap, effective treatments are not always used, potentially leading to higher
costs and worse outcomes. Moreover, because insurance companies and the government
play such prominent roles in financing health care, patients and doctors have far less
incentive to consider the extra costs of optional tests or treatments. But, as we all know,
although testing and treatment decisions may be undertaken on the presumption that
"someone else will pay," the public eventually pays for all these costs, either through
higher insurance premiums or higher taxes.
II

CUller and McClellan (200]).

- 6The effects of high health-care costs on government budgets deserve special note.

In the United States, a large and growing portion of both federal and state expenditures is
for subsidized health insurance. In 1975, federal spending on Medicare and Medicaid
was about 6 percent oftotal non-interest federal spending. Today, that share is about 23
percent. Because of rising costs of health care and the aging of the population, the CBO
projects that, without reform, Medicare and Medicaid will be about 35 percent of noninterest federal spending in 2025. 12 This trend implies increasingly difficult tradeoffs for
legislators and taxpayers, as higher government spending on health-care spending will, of
necessity, require reductions in other government programs, higher taxes, or larger
budget deficits.
Rapid increases in health spending also portend increasingly difficult access to
health services for people with lower incomes.13 As health spending continues to outpace
income, health insurance and out-of-pocket payments will become increasingly
unaffordable. 14 One way that society has addressed this problem in the past has been to
expand government subsidies for health spending. The Medicare Part D program, which
assists seniors with the costs of prescription drugs, is an example. However, to continue
limiting the effects of rising medical costs on household budgets, the government may
have to absorb an increasing proportion of the nation's total bill for health care, putting
even greater pressure on government budgets than official projections suggest.

CBO (2007).
For the purposes of this speech, "low income" means those in the bottom 20th percentile of the income
distribution.
14 For example, a recent study estimated that, without increases in the share of health spending that is
publicly financed, the budget share of health spending for low-income elderly households would increase
from about 25 percent of their income today to about 35 percent by 2040 (Follette and Sheiner, 2(07).
12
13

-7Taking on these challenges will be daunting. Because our health-care system is
so complex, the challenges so diverse, and our knowledge so incomplete, we should not
expect a single set of reforms to address all concerns. Rather, an eclectic approach will
probably be needed. In particular, we may need to first address the problems that seem
more easily managed rather than waiting for a solution that will address all problems at
once.

Thinking About Solutions
In health-care reform, it is certainly easier to pose questions than to provide
answers. Moreover, even putting aside the scope and technical complexities of the
problems we face, the types of reforms we choose will depend importantly on value
judgments and the tradeoffs made among social objectives. Such choices are
appropriately left to the public and their elected representatives. Consequently, I will
have little to say here regarding specific proposals. However, I will suggest a few
questions and considerations that those seeking reform might wish to keep in mind.
Regarding access, one important consideration is that people who are uninsured
are not all alike. They include people who have low incomes, people who may not be
poor but have costly pre-existing health conditions, those whose employers do not offer
group health insurance and who cannot afford to buy insurance in the more-expensive
nongroup market, and people who are eligible for Medicaid or other programs but for
some reason have not enrolled. Some people who can afford health insurance do not
purchase it, presumably because they do not anticipate having significant medical
expenses. Broadening access to health care may thus require us to consider a mix of
policies. The following are some of the questions with which we will have to wrestle.

-8-

First, should enrollment in a health insurance program be mandated, or at least
strongly encouraged, for example, through tax incentives? Supporters argue that
mandates lead to better risk pooling and prevent those who could afford insurance but
choose not to buy it from "free-riding" on the public safety net. Opponents argue that
mandates infringe on what should be an individual choice and may require a substantial
government budgetary commitment to help those who cannot afford insurance on their
own to meet the mandate.
Second, should we continue to rely on employer-provided health insurance as the
key element of our system? The employees of large companies in particular typically
constitute a good risk -sharing pool, allowing insurance to be provided at a lower overall
cost. But the dominance of the insurance market by employer-provided plans means that
the market for individual and small-group policies is underdeveloped and that the cost of
such coverage is very high. Employer-based systems also reduce the portability of health
insurance between jobs, which reduces labor mobility and the efficiency of the labor
market as well as creating a burden for those changing jobs.
Third, to help people with costly pre-existing conditions, should we impose
requirements on insurance companies to accept all applicants and mandate the conditions
that must be covered? Doing so would help some people obtain coverage, but the
resulting increases in insurance premiums might exclude others. An alternative approach
would be to promote bare-bones, high-deductible policies that are affordable and
attractive to healthy people while offering government help to those who need coverage
for costly conditions.

-9Finally, to what extent are we willing to use public funds to reduce the number of
those who are uninsured, for example, by providing subsidies to low-income people not
covered by Medicaid or to people, such as the self-employed, who find it difficult to
obtain affordable coverage in the non-group market? How would we finance additional
spending? For instance, would we consider limiting the employers' tax exemption for the
cost of employee health insurance?
The issue of access to health care, though difficult politically, is in some sense the
technically least complex of the three challenges I have identified; it is mostly about
financing, and possibly regulation, rather than about medicine. Of course, access to
health care is closely entwined with the other issues, notably the issue of cost. In
particular, restraining the growth of health-care costs would increase the number of
people who can afford insurance coverage.
On the second challenge, improving the quality of health care, a number of
private and public initiatives have been undertaken in recent years. These include
programs to monitor hospitals' performance in ensuring patient safety and adherence to
best practices; greater efforts to identify and disseminate best practices, as determined
from clinical trials; and public and private initiatives to increase the use of information
technology in health care. Researchers are also examining how the structure of healthcare delivery systems affects the quality of care. For example, some evidence suggests
that vertically integrated systems like that of the Veterans Administration are quicker to
adopt health information technology and have been more successful in applying it. Some
instances of initiatives that aim to encourage quality through financial incentives or
disincentives--so-called pay-for-performance--have begun to emerge. Examples include

- 10accreditation practices that require hospitals to comply with established standards and
best practices, and the recent decision that Medicare will not cover costs caused by
certain medical errors.
Efforts to improve the quality of health care are a vital component of
comprehensive reform and are likely to yield high social returns. Additional research and
experimentation can help us address difficult questions such as how best to measure
quality and cost-effectiveness in health-care delivery and how to give doctors and
hospitals incentives to adopt best practices and improved information technologies.
The solutions we choose for access and quality will interact in important ways
with the third critical issue--the issue of cost. Greater access to health care will improve
health outcomes, but it almost certainly will raise financial costs. Increasing the quality
of health care, although highly desirable, could also result in higher total health-care
spending. For example, increased patient screening may avoid more serious problems
and thus be cost-saving, but it could also identify problems that might otherwise have
gone untreated--a good outcome, certainly, but one that increases overall spending.
These are certainly not arguments against increasing access or improving quality. My
point is only that improving access and quality may increase rather than reduce total
costs.
From the economist's perspective, the question of whether we are spending too
much on health care cannot ultimately be answered by looking at total expenditures
relative to GDP or the federal budget. Rather, the question, whatever we spend, is
whether we are getting our money's worth. In general, good information and appropriate
incentives are necessary to allocate resources efficiently. In health care, the necessary

- 11 -

information should include not only the clinical effectiveness of certain tests or courses
of treatment but also their cost-effectiveness. As the regional comparison of health-care
costs illustrates, cost-effective approaches may be at least as useful as more costly
approaches in delivering good health outcomes.
Knowledge of the costs of alternative approaches is likely to be insufficient by
itself. Patients, doctors, and hospitals must also be given incentives for choosing costeffective approaches. However, the questions of how to structure incentives and monitor
performance are hotly debated. For example, advocates of "consumer-driven" health
care argue that, given appropriate information and incentives, patients--or in some cases,
private insurers acting on their behalf--can effectively impose at least some degree of
market discipline on health-care providers. Others see an inevitable role for government
in setting standards of care and in measuring performance. Professional associations,
hospitals, medical researchers, and other stakeholders may also have a role to play. At
the heart of the debate are the fundamental social questions of how we determine when
various medical services are worth their cost and how we measure and reward good
performance by providers.
Rising health spending increases stress on both private and public budgets, and
thus stakeholders in both spheres are aiming to reduce costs. Cost-saving reforms in the
private sector will inevitably reverberate in the public sector and vice versa. For
example, the shift toward managed care in the private sector also resulted in more
managed care in the public sector. Similarly, innovations in public insurance programs,
such as the introduction of reimbursement by diagnosis-related groups in Medicare,

- 12 changed the way private insurance payments were structured. IS Our health-care system
is, de facto, a private-public partnership; as a result, governments should not view healthcare costs narrowly as a budgetary issue. Rather, they should consider how the totality of
government intervention in the health-care market--including tax policies, insurance
regulation, and the structure of Medicare and Medicaid--affect the sector as a whole. The
\

best way to reduce the fiscal burdens of health care is to deliver cost-effective health care
throughout the entire system.
Conclusion
Let me conclude by restating a point I made at the beginning: As we focus on the
problems of our health system, it is easy to forget that much is good about it. Our health
system has produced innovations in basic science, in the understanding and diagnosing of
disease, and in pharmacology and medical technology. These advances have resulted in
more-effective treatments and significant reductions in mortality across a wide spectrum
of diseases. In devising policies to reform our health-care system, we must take care to
maintain the vitality and spirit of innovation that has been its hallmark.

15 Diagnosis-related groups are a system for classifying cases into disease-related groups that are likely to
require the same hospital resources, on average. In the early I 980s, Medicare began reimbursing hospitals
a fixed amount per admission based on the diagnosis-related group rather than reimbursing them for the
actual costs incurred for each patient.

- 13 -

,
References

Congressional Budget Office (2007). "The Long-Term Budget Outlook." Washington:
Congressional Budget Office, December, www.cbo.gov/doc.cfm?index=8877.
Cutler, David M., and Mark McClellan (2001). "Is Technological Change in Medicine
Worth It?" Health Affairs, vol. 20 (July), pp. 11-29.
Doyle, Joseph J., Jr. (2005). "Health Insurance, Treatment, and Outcomes: Using Auto
Accidents as Health Shocks," Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 87 (May),
pp.256-70.
Follette, Glenn, and Louise Sheiner (2007). "A Microeconomic Perspective on the
Evolution of Health Spending," unpublished paper, Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System.
Hadley, Jack, and John Holahan (2004). "The Cost of Care for the Uninsured: What Do
We Spend, Who Pays, and What Would Full Coverage Add to Medical
Spending?" Issue Update No. 7804. Washington: Kaiser Commission on
Medicaid and the Uninsured, May 10, www.kff.org/uninsuredl7084.cfm.
Institute of Medicine (2000). To Err Is Human: Building a Safer Health System.
Washington: National Academy Press.
_ _ _ _ (2002). Care without Coverage: Too Little, Too Late. Washington:
National Academy Press.
Joint Commission (2007). "Improving America's Hospitals: The Joint Commission's
Annual Report on Quality and Safety 2007." Oakbrook Terrace, Ill.: Joint
Commission, November, www.jointcommissionreport.org.
Leape, Lucian L., and Donald M. Berwick (2005). "Five Years After To Err Is Human:
What Have We Learned?" lAMA, vol. 293 (May 18), pp. 2384-90.
Skinner, Jonathan S., Douglas O. Staiger, and Elliott S. Fisher (2006). "Is Technological
Change in Medicine Always Worth It? The Case of Acute Myocardial
Infarction," Health Affairs, vol. 25 (March), pp. w34-w47.