View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
11:00 a.m. EDT (8:00 a.m. PDT)
October 19, 2009

Asia and the Global Financial Crisis

Remarks by
Ben S. Bernanke
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Conference on
Asia and the Global Financial Crisis
Santa Barbara, California

October 19, 2009

The rise of the Asian economies since World War II has been one of the great
success stories in the history of economic development. Japan’s transition to an
economic powerhouse was followed by the rapid ascent of the Asian tigers, and
subsequently by China taking a prominent place on the world economic stage.1 Since the
beginning of this decade, Asia has accounted for more than one-third of the world’s
economic growth, raising its share of global gross domestic product (GDP) from 28
percent to 32 percent.2 Importantly, its economic success has resulted in large-scale
reductions in poverty and substantial improvements in the standards of living of hundreds
of millions of people. China and India, which together account for almost 40 percent of
the world’s population, have seen real per capita incomes rise more than 10-fold and
3-fold, respectively, since 1980. As would be expected given the increasing size and
sophistication of their economies, the nations of the region have also begun to exert a
substantial influence on global economic developments and on international governance
in the economic and financial spheres.
It is widely agreed that a key source of Asia’s rapid advancement has been the
openness of countries in the region to global trade and finance. Notwithstanding this
consensus, the considerable progress of these countries in developing domestic
institutions, policies, and industrial capacity--together with their strong growth in the
initial phase of the ongoing global financial crisis--led some to speculate that the Asian
economies had “decoupled” from the advanced economies of North America and Europe.
Of course, in hindsight, given the magnitude of the shocks that have struck these
advanced economies over the past two years, as well as their strong economic and
1
2

The term “Asian tigers” refers to the economies of Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan.
This estimate is based on purchasing power parity measures of GDP.

-2financial links to Asia, it should not have been surprising that Asia was ultimately hit
quite hard by the global downturn, even though the origins of the turmoil were elsewhere.
As a prelude to the papers and discussions to follow, I will provide a brief
overview of the Asian experience during the global financial crisis. I will highlight the
diversity of experiences, both within Asia and between Asia and other regions, and draw
some inferences about the different channels through which the effects of the financial
crisis were transmitted around the world. I will discuss Asia’s policy response to the
economic and financial consequences of the crisis. Finally, I will focus on medium-term
challenges. For both Asia and the United States, perhaps the greatest medium-term
challenge is to achieve more balanced growth and, in the process, to further reduce global
imbalances.
Asia’s Experience in the Crisis
During the years following the financial crisis of the late 1990s, many emerging
market economies, in Asia and elsewhere, took advantage of relatively good global
economic conditions to strengthen their economic and financial fundamentals; they
improved their fiscal and external debt positions, built foreign exchange reserves, and
reformed their banking sectors. Hence, at the onset of the financial turmoil in the
summer of 2007, the Asian economies appeared well-positioned to avoid its worst
effects. Although global financial markets, including Asian markets, deteriorated sharply
following the start of the crisis, Asia’s recovered swiftly, with equity prices reaching
new highs early in the fourth quarter of that year. Moreover, economic activity in the
region continued to expand.

-3However, toward the end of 2007, at about the same time that the United States
entered a recession, the headwinds facing the Asian economies appeared to strengthen.
Asian equity markets began to fall again--they were to underperform global markets
throughout much of 2008--and other signs of financial stress, such as widening credit
spreads, appeared as well. By the second quarter of 2008, many of the region’s
economies were slowing, and growth in Hong Kong, Singapore, and Taiwan--small, open
economies particularly sensitive to shifts in global conditions--had ground to a halt.
In September and October 2008, as you know, the global financial crisis
intensified dramatically. Concerted international action prevented a global financial
meltdown, but the effects of the crisis on asset prices, credit availability, and consumer
and business confidence resulted in sharp declines in demand and production worldwide.
Reflecting this worsening economic climate, Asian GDP growth slowed further in the
second half of 2008. For the region as a whole, the economic contraction in the fourth
quarter of 2008 was pronounced, with activity falling at an annual rate of nearly
7 percent.3 The fourth-quarter declines were especially dramatic in Taiwan and Thailand
(more than 20 percent at an annual rate) and in South Korea and Singapore (more than 15
percent at an annual rate). Among the major Asian economies, only those of China,
India, and Indonesia did not contract during the crisis.
Early this year, with many of the Asian economies in freefall, a quick recovery
seemed difficult to imagine, but recent data from the region suggest that a strong rebound
is, in fact, under way. Although the regional economy continued to contract in the first
months of 2009, it expanded at an impressive 9 percent annual rate in the second quarter,
3

The Asian region here refers to Australia, China, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, New
Zealand, Pakistan, the Philippines, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, and Vietnam. The
economic growth calculation weights these economies by GDP at market exchange rates.

-4with annualized growth rates well into double digits in China, Hong Kong, Korea,
Malaysia, Singapore, and Taiwan.4 At this point, while risks to the economic outlook
certainly remain, Asia appears to be leading the global recovery.
Diversity of Experiences
This brief review of Asia’s experience during the crisis raises a number of
important questions: Through what channels were the effects of the financial crisis
transmitted across the globe? In particular, why was Asia, whose financial systems
largely escaped the serious credit problems that erupted in the United States and Europe,
hit so hard by the global recession? What enabled the Asian economies to bounce back
so sharply more recently? And why did some countries--around the world and within
Asia--suffer much deeper contractions than others? Some light can be shed on these
questions by examining the diversity of experiences among both Asian and non-Asian
economies during the downturn.
Transmission Channels: Trade and Finance
The crisis that began in the West affected Asia through various transmission
channels, whose relative importance depended in some degree on the particular
characteristics of each economy. However, for virtually all of the Asian economies,
international trade appears to have been a critical channel. Exhibit 1 shows the course of
global merchandise exports since the beginning of this decade. As the exhibit shows,
after a period of strong growth, international trade plunged about 20 percent in real terms
from its pre-crisis peak to its trough in early 2009 (the dashed red line), and about 35

4

These growth rates are measured on a quarter-to-quarter basis at an annual rate. China’s quarterly growth
rate is estimated from published four-quarter growth rates.

-5percent in U.S. dollar terms (the solid blue line).5 The trade-dependent economies of
Asia could certainly not be immune to the effects of such a decline.
Why did global trade fall so abruptly? The severe recession in the advanced
economies greatly restrained aggregate spending, including spending on imports, but the
decline in international trade appears surprisingly large even when the depth of the
recession in the advanced countries is taken into account. One possible explanation for
the outsized decline in trade volumes lies in the extreme uncertainty that prevailed in the
darkest months of the crisis. Consumers and businesses knew last fall that economic
conditions were poor, but, in light of the severity and the global nature of the financial
crisis, many feared outcomes that might be much worse. Perhaps to a greater extent than
they might have otherwise, households and firms put off purchases of big-ticket items,
such as consumer durables and investment goods. Durable goods figure prominently in
trade and manufacturing, so these sectors may have been particularly vulnerable to the
elevated uncertainty and weakened confidence that prevailed during the height of the
crisis.
Credit conditions also likely affected the volume of trade, through several
channels. The turmoil in credit markets doubtless exacerbated the sharp decline in
demand for durable goods, and thus in trade volumes, as purchases of durable goods
typically involve some extension of credit. Manufacturing production, a major
component of trade flows, may have been cut back more sharply than would otherwise
have been the case as producers, concerned about credit availability, attempted to

5

The nominal data are the sum of the total merchandise exports of 44 economies, including the United
States, expressed in U.S. dollars. The real data are calculated by deflating these dollar-value nominal
exports by export price indexes constructed from local-currency deflators drawn from country sources and
dollar exchange rates.

-6preserve working capital. Finally, although it is difficult to assess the size of the effect,
problems in obtaining trade finance may have also impeded trade for a time.
With trade falling sharply around the world, economies particularly dependent on
trade were hit especially hard. Exhibit 2 illustrates this point for a group of Asian and
non-Asian economies. The vertical axis of the figure shows real GDP growth, measured
relative to trend, during the most severe stage of the downturn, and the horizontal axis
shows a measure of openness to trade.6 Combinations of growth and openness observed
in various economies are indicated by red squares for a number of Asian countries and by
black dots for several non-Asian countries. The exhibit shows that countries most open
to trade (those located further to the right in the figure) suffered, on average, the greatest
declines in growth relative to trend. The most extreme cases are Hong Kong and
Singapore, shown to the far right; the economies of Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, and
Malaysia, which are also very open, suffered significant growth deficits as well.
Indeed, the GDP contractions in some Asian economies during that period rivaled
those during the Asian financial crisis of the late 1990s. Relative to pre-crisis trend, the
six Asian economies just mentioned plus Japan experienced declines in real GDP growth
of about 13 to 20 percentage points at an annual rate during the last quarter of 2008 and
the first quarter of 2009. Growth fell somewhat less severely in the Philippines and only
moderately in Australia and New Zealand. As noted earlier, real GDP growth remained
positive throughout the crisis in China, India, and Indonesia, but, as exhibit 2 shows, even
those fast-growing economies experienced noticeable declines in growth relative to their
6

Specifically, the vertical axis shows each country’s deviation of average GDP growth from trend growth
(at an annual rate) over 2008:Q4 and 2009:Q1. Trend growth is defined as the average annualized growth
rate during 2006 and 2007 of historical GDP data smoothed using the Hodrick-Prescott filter. The
horizontal axis shows each country’s trade openness as measured by the sum of its imports and exports as a
fraction of its nominal GDP in 2007.

-7earlier trends. The exhibit shows that a similar relationship between growth and
openness to trade holds for non-Asian countries; for example, more trade-dependent
nations like Germany saw sharper declines in output during the crisis than other less-open
economies.
Variations across countries in trade openness do not fully explain the diversity of
growth experiences during the downturn, suggesting that other factors were also at work.
Notably, although financial institutions in emerging market economies were not, for the
most part, directly affected by the collapse of the market for structured credit products
and other asset-backed securities, financial stress nevertheless affected these countries.
As international investors’ appetite for risk evaporated, the flow of capital shifted away
from countries that had historically been viewed as more vulnerable, including some
emerging Asian and Latin American economies, even though many of these countries
appeared to be much better positioned to weather an economic crisis than in the past.
Moreover, regardless of perceived risks, financial institutions pulled money from risky
assets in advanced and emerging markets alike in an effort to strengthen their balance
sheets.
Following the reversal in capital flows engendered by the crisis, strains in banking
appeared across Asia, leading to severe credit tightening in some countries. Fears of
counterparty risk disrupted interbank lending in many countries, intensifying already
existing funding difficulties. The drying up of the wholesale funding market hurt Korea’s
banking system in particular; prior to the crisis, it had accounted for about one-third of
Korean bank funding. In Japan, some banks’ exposures to equity markets damaged their
capital positions. With Asian banks experiencing dollar funding pressures similar to

-8those arising elsewhere in the world, the Federal Reserve established 5 of its 14 liquidity
swap lines with central banks in the region: Australia, Japan, Korea, New Zealand, and
Singapore. The reversal in capital flows also caused rapid exchange rate depreciation in
some countries, particularly Korea, Indonesia, and Malaysia. The Korean won
depreciated 40 percent against the dollar from the beginning of 2008 through its trough in
March of this year, and it has only partially recovered. Over the same period, the
Indonesian rupiah fell 22 percent against the dollar.
Exhibit 3 shows the relationship between rates of GDP growth during the
downturn, relative to trend, and financial openness, as measured by the sum of each
country’s international assets and liabilities relative to its GDP.7 The exhibit shows that,
for both Asian and non-Asian economies, financial openness was associated with greater
declines in output, though the linkage appears somewhat less tight than that for trade.8
Again, the most extreme cases are Singapore and especially Hong Kong (which is not
shown, as it is more than twice as open as even Singapore). Taiwan is another example
of a financially open Asian economy that experienced a particularly severe downturn. By
the same token, China, India, and Indonesia, the three Asian countries in which output
expanded throughout the crisis, are among the least financially open.
Trade and financial channels influenced other emerging markets as well, such as
those in Latin America and Eastern Europe. Many of these economies also contracted
sharply, but thus far they have recovered more slowly than economies in Asia. In the

7

A country’s international assets are claims on foreigners by its residents, and liabilities are foreigners’
claims on the country’s residents. Data on these claims are from Haver and the U.S. Bureau of Economic
Analysis.
8
Whether the relationship shown in Exhibit 3 is causal is not entirely clear, however, as economies that are
more exposed to the global financial system also tend to be those economies most open to trade, as can be
seen by comparing Exhibit 3 to Exhibit 2.

-9case of Latin America, closer links to the U.S. economy (especially in the case of
Mexico) and greater dependence on commodity exports (whose prices declined during
the most intense phase of the crisis) were additional sources of weakness. In Eastern
Europe, preexisting macroeconomic imbalances and structural weaknesses likely
magnified the effects of the adverse global shocks.
It is important not to take the wrong lesson from the finding that more open
economies were more severely affected by the global recession. Although tighter
integration with the global economy naturally increases vulnerability to global economic
shocks, considerable evidence suggests that openness also promotes stronger economic
growth over the longer term. Protectionism and the erecting of barriers to capital flows
should thus be strongly resisted. Instead, as I will discuss, striking a reasonable balance
between trade and growth in domestic demand is the best strategy for driving economic
expansion.
Policy Responses
By and large, countries in Asia came into the crisis with fairly strong
macroeconomic fundamentals, including low inflation and favorable fiscal and current
account positions. Good fundamentals, in turn, provided scope for strong policy
responses in many countries. China, Japan, Korea, and Singapore were among those
employing relatively aggressive policy strategies; in particular, China undertook a sizable
fiscal program, supplemented by accommodative monetary and bank lending policies.
The stimulus packages in China and elsewhere have lifted domestic demand throughout
the region, boosting intraregional trade.

- 10 Not all Asian nations responded so aggressively to the crisis. Some countries
with weaker fiscal positions no doubt felt constrained in the extent of fiscal stimulus they
provided. Similarly, monetary policies were likely influenced by differences in inflation
performance. On the one hand, countries experiencing low inflation or deflation, such as
China, Japan, and Thailand, were able to implement expansionary monetary policies
without concerns about increasing inflationary pressures. Indeed, Japan used
unconventional monetary easing in part to avoid deeper deflation. On the other hand,
inflation concerns were more pressing for Indonesia, the Philippines, and Korea, with the
result that their monetary policy responses may have been more muted than would
otherwise have been the case. The national variation in policy responses likely also
reflected differences in the severity of the crisis across countries.
Generally speaking, the Asian response to the crisis appears thus far to have been
effective. Importantly, as I have suggested, the Asian recovery to date has been in
significant part the result of growth in domestic demand, supported by fiscal and
monetary policies, rather than of growth in demand from trading partners outside the
region. To illustrate the point, for each of the countries in the region, exhibit 4 shows
industrial production (the solid blue bars) and exports (the striped red bars) measured
relative to the pre-crisis peak.9 You can see that the blue bars are generally taller than the
red bars, indicating that, except for New Zealand and Hong Kong, industrial production
has rebounded by more than exports. Indeed, industrial production in China, India, and
Indonesia has already reached new highs, and it is within about 5 percent of its previous
peak in Australia and Korea. We would expect to see this pattern if growth in domestic
demand, rather than growth in exports, was the predominant driver of increases in
9

The data are quarterly through the second quarter of 2009. Exports are measured in U.S. dollars.

- 11 domestic production.10 The revival of demand in Asia has, in turn, aided global
economic growth.
Despite the initial successes of Asian economic policies, risks remain. As in the
advanced economies, unwinding the stimulative policies introduced during the crisis will
require careful judgment. Policymakers will have to balance the risks of withdrawing
policy support too early, which might cut short a nascent recovery, against the risks of
leaving expansionary policies in place for too long, which could overheat the economy or
worsen longer-term fiscal imbalances. In Asia, as in the rest of the world, the provision
of adequate short-term stimulus must not be allowed to detract from longer-term goals,
such as the amelioration of excessive global imbalances or ongoing structural reforms to
increase productivity and support balanced and sustainable growth.
Lessons from Crises and Medium-Term Challenges
For now, Asian countries look to be weathering the current storm. In part, their
successful responses reflect the lessons learned during the Asian financial crisis of the
1990s, including the need for sound macroeconomic fundamentals.
One crucial lesson from both that crisis and the recent one is that financial
institutions must be carefully regulated, transparent, and sufficiently well capitalized and
liquid to withstand large shocks. In part because of the reforms put in place after the
crisis of the 1990s, along with improved macroeconomic policies, Asian banking systems
were better positioned to handle the more recent turmoil. With the increased prominence
of the Group of Twenty (G-20) as a forum for discussing the global responses to the

10

In principle, some rebuilding of inventories for export could also be boosting production, but such
inventory data for the region that are available do not strongly support this view.

- 12 crisis, emerging market economies, including those in Asia, will play a larger role in the
remaking of the international financial system and financial regulation.
Another set of lessons that Asian economies took from the crisis of the 1990s may
be more problematic. Because strong export markets helped Asia recover from that
crisis, and because many countries in the region were badly hurt by sharp reversals in
capital flows, the crisis strengthened Asia’s commitment to export-led growth, backed up
with large current account surpluses and mounting foreign exchange reserves. In many
respects, that model has served Asia well, contributing to the rapid growth rates in the
region over the past decade. In fact, it bears repeating that evidence from the world over
shows trade openness to be an important source of economic growth. However, too great
a reliance on external demand can also pose problems. In particular, trade surpluses
achieved through policies that artificially enhance incentives for domestic saving and the
production of export goods distort the mix of domestic industries and the allocation of
resources, resulting in an economy that is less able to meet the needs of its own citizens
in the longer term.
To achieve more balanced and durable economic growth and to reduce the risks
of financial instability, we must avoid ever-increasing and unsustainable imbalances in
trade and capital flows. External imbalances have already narrowed substantially as a
consequence of the crisis, as reduced income and wealth and tighter credit have led
households in the United States and other advanced industrial countries to save more and
spend less, including on imported goods. Together with lower oil prices and reduced
business investment, these changes in behavior have lowered the U.S. current account
deficit from about 5 percent of GDP in 2008 to less than 3 percent in the second quarter

- 13 of this year. Reflecting in part reduced import demand from the United States, China’s
current account surplus fell from about 10 percent of GDP in the first half of 2008 to
about 6-1/2 percent of GDP in the first half of this year.
As the global economy recovers and trade volumes rebound, however, global
imbalances may reassert themselves. As national leaders have emphasized in recent
meetings of the G-20, policymakers around the world must guard against such an
outcome. We understand, at least in principle, how to do this. The United States must
increase its national saving rate. Although we should deploy, as best we can, tools to
increase private saving, the most effective way to accomplish this goal is by establishing
a sustainable fiscal trajectory, anchored by a clear commitment to substantially reduce
federal deficits over time. For their part, to achieve balanced and sustainable growth, the
authorities in surplus countries, including most Asian economies, must act to narrow the
gap between saving and investment and to raise domestic demand. In large part, such
actions should focus on boosting consumption. Admittedly, just as increasing private
saving in the United States is challenging, promoting consumption in a high-saving
country is not necessarily straightforward. One potentially effective strategy is to reduce
households’ precautionary motive for saving by strengthening pension systems and
increasing government spending on health care and education. Of course, such measures
are likely to improve welfare and productivity as well as to contribute to more balanced,
robust, and sustainable economic growth.
Conclusion
The United States has benefited significantly from Asia’s rapid development and
integration into the global economy, and the payoffs to the Asian economies from global

- 14 economic integration have been substantial as well. Indeed, the financial crisis has
starkly demonstrated the extent to which the fortunes of the United States, Asia, and the
rest of the global economy are intertwined. These powerful economic linkages, as well
as the importance of both the United States and Asia in the global economy, underscore
the need for consultation and cooperation in addressing common issues and concerns.
Our shared stakes in the prospects of the global economy bring with them a heightened
responsibility to work together to maintain those prospects. I am optimistic that the
United States and Asia will rise to the challenge and address in a mutually beneficial
fashion the range of issues confronting the global economy. Conferences such as this
one, which bring together policymakers and scholars from both sides of the Pacific, will
further the cause of this cooperation.

Exhibit 1

Global Merchandise Exports

Billions of U.S. dollars
1300
,

Nominal*
Real (in 2000 dollars)**
1100
,

900

700

500

2000

2001

2002

2003

2004

2005

2006

2007

2008

*The nominal data are the sum of the total merchandise exports of 44 economies, including the United States,
expressed in U.S. dollars.
**The real data are calculated by deflating dollar-value nominal exports by export price indexes constructed from
local-currency deflators drawn from country sources and dollar exchange rates.
Source: CEIC, Haver, and staff estimates.

2009

300

Exhibit 2

Trade Openness and GDP Growth
(2008Q4 - 2009Q1)

5

Growth relative to trend*

5

0

-5

0

Australia
India
US

Non-Asia

-5

France
Colombia
Argentina

-10

Asia

Indonesia
New Zealand

Euro area UK
Brazil
Japan

-15

China
Philippines
Chile

-10

Germany
Korea

-15
Hong Kong

Taiwan
Thailand

Mexico

Malaysia

-20

-20

Singapore

-25
0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

-25
4.0

Trade openness**
*Growth relative to trend is the percentage point difference between the realized rate of growth during 2008Q4 and 2009Q1,
measured at an annual rate, and trend growth. Trend growth is the average annualized growth rate during 2006 and 2007
of smoothed gross domestic product (GDP) using the Hodrick-Prescott filter.
**(Exports+Imports) / GDP in 2007.
Source: CEIC, Haver, and staff estimates.

Exhibit 3

Financial Openness and GDP Growth
(2008Q4 - 2009Q1)

5

Growth relative to trend*

5
Hong Kong values (excluded from plot):
Financial openness: 23.9
Deviation: -17.0

0

0

-5

Asia

Australia

Indonesia
India

New Zealand

Non-Asia

-5

France
Colombia

China

US

Argentina
Philippines
Chile

-10

Euro area

-10

UK

Brazil
Japan
Germany

Korea

-15
Mexico

-15

Taiwan
Thailand

Malaysia

Singapore

-20

-25

-20

0

2

4

6

8

10

Financial openness**
*Growth relative to trend is the percentage point difference between the realized rate of growth during 2008Q4 and 2009Q1,
measured at an annual rate, and trend growth. Trend growth is the average annualized growth rate during 2006 and 2007
of smoothed gross domestic product (GDP) using the Hodrick-Prescott filter.
**(International Assets+Liabilities) / GDP in 2007.
Source: CEIC, Haver, and staff estimates. International investment position data are from Haver and the
U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis.

-25

Exhibit 4

Asian Industrial Production and Exports Relative to Pre-Crisis Peak

Ratio
1.10

Industrial production
Exports*

1.05

1.10
1.05

1.00

1.00

0.95

0.95

0.90

0.90

0.85

0.85

0.80

0.80

0.75

0.75

0.70

0.70

0.65

0.65

0.60

0.60

0.55

0.55

China

Indonesia
Korea
Singapore
Malaysia
Philippines
Japan
India
Australia
Thailand
New Zealand
Hong Kong
Taiwan

*Exports are measured in U.S. dollars. Industrial production and export data are through the second quarter.
Source: CEIC, Haver, and staff estimates.