View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

release on delivery

Statement by

Arthur F« Burns

Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Committee on Banking and Currency

House of Representatives

September 12, 1973

I appreciate the opportunity to discuss with you
the problems that have developed of late in the markets for
mortgage credit and housing.
Early this year, as the Committee is well aware,
building permits for private housing units began to decline,
and so did the number of new housing starts.

With mortgage

credit supplies shrinking, a significant further drop in residential
building activity may lie ahead.
Recent developments in housing finance are a
matter of concern to the Federal Reserve as well as to this
Committee.

A practical solution to the recurring problems of

housing finance will be found only if the forces presently operating to depress residential construction are clearly understood.
Let me therefore try to put recent events in perspective.
In the early months of 1970, activity in the residential
building industry began to recover from its slump in 1969.

This

upturn was the beginning of a surge in housing activity that lasted
three years, and proved to be the strongest home-building boom

-2-

of the postwar period.

In the year 1972 alone, construction

got under way on 2. 4 million conventional dwelling units;
in addition, nearly 60Q, 000 mobile homes were produced.
Both in 1971 and 1972, the total production of new dwelling
units exceeded by a substantial margin the national housing
goals established by the Congress in 1968.
The booming volume of residential construction
could not long be sustained by the basic demand for housing.
During the year ended last March, 1. 6 million new households
were established in the United States.

The number of new

housing units produced during that year, however, was nearly
twice as large.

Inventories of unsold houses began to rise as

early as 1971, and they are now almost twice as high, relative
to sales, as they were two years ago.

Vacancy rates for rental

units have also crept up in many sections of the country, and
they may well increase further as the completion of large apartment buildings now under construction adds to available rental
units.
Besides outstripping the basic demand for housing,
the boom in residential building played havoc with costs and
prices.

Prices of lumber, plywood, and other building materials

skyrocketed, land values soared, and wages in the construction
industry rose for a time at an annual rate of about 10 per
cent.
Of late, construction costs have come under better
control.

Thanks to the vigilance of the Construction Industry

Wage Stabilization Committee, increases of wage rates have
moderated appreciably.

Upward pressure on prices of building

materials, especially lumber and plywood, has also diminished
in recent months.

Nevertheless, the median price of new

single-family homes is now more than a third higher than in
October 1969.
By late 1972, overbuilding and high prices
had set the stage for a downturn in residential construction.
The ensuing decline in housing starts got underway long before
supplies of mortgage credit began to affect home building
adversely.
One factor that contributed to overbuilding during
the housing boom was the liberal supply of mortgage credit.
The specialized mortgage lending institutions--that is, the
savings and loan associations (S&L's) and the mutual savings
banks--were well supplied with loanable funds over a prolonged

-4-

period.

Their total deposits, which had risen 7 per cent in

1970, increased 17 per cent in 1971 and 17 per cent again in
1972.

Inflows of consumer savings deposits at commercial

banks also rose rapidly, from 11 per cent in 1970 to an
average of 15 per cent in 1971 and 1972.
These three classes of depository institutions
together added $11 billion to their residential mortgage portfolios in 1970. As their deposit inflows moved up, their net
acquisition of mortgages rose to $30 billion in 1971 and then
to $43 billion in 1972. In the second quarter of this year, these
institutions were still acquiring new residential mortgages at
an annual rate of $48 billion.
Mortgage credit supplies during this period were
so large that, despite soaring demands for mortgage credit,
interest rates on mortgages actually declined between the late
summer of 1970 and the spring of 1972, and then remained quite
stable over the rest of 1972.
Developments in other financial markets last year,
however, carried an ominous significance for housing finance.
In the spring of 1972, short-term market interest rates began to
rise, and their upward movement accelerated toward the clore

of the year.

By now, as this Committee knows, interest rates

on most short-term market securities have risen above the
previous high peaks of late 1969 or early 1970.

Long-term

interest rates have also advanced, but their rise has been less
pronounced.
The fundamental reasons for this rise in interest
rates should, I think, be evident to any thoughtful observer.
With economic expansion proceeding at a vigorous rate since
late 1971, the accompanying demand for credit has been very
strong.

The revival of fears that inflation has become

endemic served further to enhance the demand for credit.
These developments account for the mounting pace
of private credit demands.

Between the first half of 1972 and

the first half of 1973, the rate of private credit expansion
increased by more than a third, or about three times as fast
as the percentage increase in the gross national product.
Continuing large drains on the money and capital
markets by the Federal sector added, of course, to the upward
pressure on interest rates.

Total borrowing by the Federal

government--including the Federally-sponsored credit agenciesamounted to almost $33 billion in fiscal 1973. It is well to bear

-6-

in mind that Federal deficits augment private disposable
income, and thereby tend to increase private spending and borrowing.

The impact of Federal deficits on interest rates

therefore goes beyond the direct effects that stem from the
addition of Federal borrowing to other credit demands.

These

deficits have contributed powerfully to the mounting pressures
in financial markets since the spring of 1972.
During this period, monetary policy has tolerated
the higher

interest rates that resulted from the rapidly rising

demands for credit.

Supplies of money and credit were allowed

to expand, but not by enough to satisfy each and every demand
for credit at the going level of interest rates.

If a more

expansive monetary policy, aimed primarily at holding down
interest rates, had been followed, the resulting increase in
supplies of money and other liquid assets would have added
enormously to the potential for inflation.

Before long, as both

lenders and borrowers adjusted their behavior to the quickened
pace of inflation, interest rates would have risen sharply despite
the outpouring of newly created money, and by now they would
probably be even higher than they in fact are.
rising interest rates go together,

Inflation and

and both lead to

serious difficulties for the housing industry.

Signs of developing problems in housing finance
became evident early in 1973, when the inflow of consumer
savings to commercial banks began to shrink.

In the second

quarter of the year, savings inflows to nonbank thrift institutions also weakened, falling to an annual growth rate of
9 per cent, compared with 17 per cent in 1972. Mortgage
lenders, therefore, became less energetic in committing
funds for housing, and interest rates on mortgage loans began
to advance.
The threat to homebuilding activity posed by such
developments becomes all the more serious when residential
construction is already beginning to weaken as a result of
overbuilding, as was the case in early 1973. By the middle of
this year, housing production thus appeared to be on the verge
of yet another downswing in the feast and famine cycle that has
long characterized this industry.
These recurring cycles have been of great concern
to the Federal Reserve Board.

You may recall that in my

testimony before this Committee on February 7, 1970--my
first appearance before a Congressional Committee as Chairman
of the Federal Reserve Board--! indicated that the Federal

-8-

Rcserve staff would undertake a thorough search for ways of
moderating the short-term swings in the availability of
mortgage credit.

Upon completion of that study, the Federal

Reserve Board submitted its report to Congress on March 3,
1972.

Our most important recommendation was a proposal

for a m o r e flexible use of fiscal policy to smooth out the
fluctuations in business fixed investment, so that dependence
on credit restraint to achieve economic stability could be
reduced.

Other proposals v/ere aimed at stabilizing the flow

of funds to financial intermediaries.
While the Board's report was submitted at a time
when commercial banks and other thrift institutions were
enjoying strong deposit gains, it pointed out that these inflows
would probably shrink when yields on market securities again
rose.

The Board therefore urged the Congress to take the

opportunity afforded by conditions then existing in the mortgage
and housing fields to strengthen the ability of cur nation1 s
depository institutions to function .effectively in an environment
of fluctuating interest rates.

The fundamental reason why the stream of savings
into the specialized mortgage lending institutions - -especially
the S&L1 s--dries up periodically lies in the asymmetry
between their assets and liabilities.

Their assets consist

chiefly of mortgages with a long average life, and their
earnings rates are therefore rather inflexible.

Their lia-

bilities, on the other hand, consist of passbook accounts that
in practice are payable on demand, or of time deposits with
relatively short maturities.

These forms of savings are

rather close substitutes for short-term market securities,
on which yields are highly variable.

When yields on competing

market instruments rise, a strong tendency develops to divert
savings from the thrift institutions to market securities.
The Board's report set forth proposals to deal with
this problem.

To achieve greater flexibility in the earnings

of S&L's, so that they could compete more effectively against
market securities, the Board suggested that perhaps 10 per
cent of their earning assets might be placed in consumer loans.
More importantly, we recommended that consideration be
given to enabling all depository institutions to offer mortgages
with variable interest rates, subject to regulatory safeguards.

-10-

The Board hopes that its report will assist the
Congress in its search for ways to deal with the problem of
cyclical instability in housing finance.

But the necessary

ameliorative measures have not yet been adopted.

As a

result, the nation1 s housing industry may now have to bear
once again a disproportionate share of the burden of policies
to moderate the expansion of aggregate demand.

Fiscal

policy has not yet been made a flexible tool for economic
stabilization.

And monetary and credit policies are still

serving as the primary line of defense against excess
aggregate demand, although we know from experience that
general monetary restraints affect housing more than other
industries.
As recent experience again indicates, our depository institutions, particularly the S&L/s, have great difficulty
in coping with rising market interest rates.

Over the past

several years, the structure of deposits at the S&L's has
changed substantially.

Nearly alLof .the growth in their

savings capital has come from special deposits with a fixed
term to maturity.

A large part of these special deposits,

however, have rather short maturities.

By actively encouraging

-11-

growth of such accounts, it appears that the S&L!s have
attracted a substantial amount of interest-sensitive funds,
thereby aggravating their problem of deposit instability.
The Federal Reserve has been troubled by this
development for some time.

During the spring of this year,

some depository institutions began losing funds to market securities, on which interest rates were rising rapidly, and it
seemed likely that the diversion of individual savings to
market instruments would accelerate after the midyear
interest-crediting period.

More freedom for depository

institutions to bid for funds thus became urgent.

On July 5

the Federal Reserve joined with the other regulatory agencies
to allow commercial banks and other thrift institutions to
offer higher yields on consumer-type time and savings deposits.
The new ceilings on interest rates paid by commercial banks were again set at lower levels than for other
thrift institutions.

In the case of S&L's and mutual savings

banks, the largest increases in ceiling rates were made for
special accounts--that is, accounts other than passbook savings.
This approach was adopted to enable these institutions to utilize
the limited increase of their earnings in recent years to best
advantage in attracting or holding on to savings customers.

-12-

At the same time, ceiling rates on consumer-type
deposit certificates with maturities of four years or longer,
when sold in denominations of $1, 000 or more, were suspended
for all depository institutions.

The objective of this action was

to increase the ability of these institutions to compete with
market instruments, and at the same time achieve greater
stability of deposits.
In taking these several steps, the Board and the other
regulatory agencies kept in mind the need for greater equity for
savers.

Whatever advantages the housing industry and the

institutions that finance it may derive from rate ceilings, these
ceilings clearly discriminate against individuals who are able to
accumulate only modest amounts of savings or who lack sophistication with regard to investment alternatives.

In determining

rate ceilings and in related actions, such as establishing minimum
denominations in which Federal securities are sold, public policy
must balance the needs of housing finance against equity for the
small saver.

One result of deposit rate ceilings and large

minimum denominations of Treasury, issues has been to deny
small savers the opportunity of benefiting from competitive
rates of return on their funds.

This may help to sustain home-

building, but we need to explore other, more equitable* ways of

promoting that objective.

Suspension of deposit rate ceilings

in limited areas, subject to safeguards, is one such avenue of
exploration.
The precise details of the liberalized ceiling rates
that became effective on July 5 were designed with an eye to
minimizing shifts of funds among depository institutions.

We

soon discovered, however, that savings and loan associations
in a few metropolitan areas were losing funds to some commercial banks that were merchandising aggressively the new,
no-ceiling four-year certificate.

The Federal Reserve Board

and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation responded
promptly to this development, by limiting the amount of such
deposits that a commercial or mutual savings bank may accept
to 5 per cent of its total time and savings accounts.

A similar

restriction had previously been imposed on savings and loan
associations by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board.
Other steps have also been taken recently by the
regulatory agencies to achieve uniformity among competing
financial institutions with regard to penalties for early withdrawal of time deposits, and to ensure that savers who may
wish to switch into higher-yielding certificates of deposit
understand how such penalties will affect their interest earnings.

-14-

These regulatory actions have clearly improved the
ability of depository institutions to compete
securities for the savings of individuals.

with market

The further rise

of market interest

rates since early July has, however, blunted

this achievement.

With relatively short-term Treasury securities

or Federal agency issues now offering yields of 8 or 9 per cent,
the purchase of such securities by individuals has been rising
rapidly of late.
In July, deposit outflows amounted to about $300 million
at S&L's, and to about $600 million at mutual savings banks.
In August, mutual savings banks fared somewhat better.

On the

other hand, deposit outflows at S&L's accelerated, if we may judge
from the data now available.

The larger commercial banks, in

their turn, reported a loss of $200 million in consumer time and
savings deposits over the four weeks ended August 29, compared
with an increase of $300 million in the previous five weeks.
The contrasting experience of commercial banks and
S&L's since mid-year has suggested to some observers that
many banks may be attracting funds from S&L's through
aggressive marketing of the new certificates with a maturity of
4 years or longer.

The Federal Reserve has been investigating

this question carefully.

-15An overwhelming proportion of the banks appear to be
handling prudently the no-ceiling 4-year certificates.

Less than

40 per cent of all insured commercial banks were offering these
certificates at the end of July, and of those that did, only about
one out of twenty paid a rate in excess of 7-1/2,per cent.

The

rates offered by commercial banks were broadly similar to those
offered by S&L's and mutual savings banks.

In general, since

savers would not have gained interest income by switching funds
from nonbank thrift institutions to commercial banks, it appears
that the bulk of the funds lost by S&L's and savings banks during
July and August did not move to commercial banks, but that the
money went elsewhere--probably into market securities.
This, however, is not as yet a firm conclusion.

In any

event, even if valid on a nation-wide basis, it may not apply to
some individual communities.

The Federal Reserve Board,

working cooperatively with other regulatory agencies, will
therefore continue to give this problem close attention and draw
upon whatever new information becomes available.

A few days

ago the Federal Home Loan Bank Board and the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation liberalized their regulations, so that the
S&L's and mutual savings banks will be able to issue the noceiling 4-year certificates up to 10 per cent of their deposits.

-16If further regulatory actions offer promise of diminishing
turbulence in the markets for consumer savings and mortgage
credit, the Federal Reserve Board--and I'm sure also the other
regulatory agencies--will not hesitate to adopt them.
In all candor, however, I must acknowledge that I see no
easy way out of our current dilemma.

Competition among the

thrift institutions could be restrained by reverting entirely to
the former ceilings or by imposing a modest ceiling on the new
four-year certificates.

But in that event the loss of funds by

depository institutions to market instruments would probably
increase greatly.

Alternatively, ceilings could be liberalized

further, so as to give the thrift institutions more freedom to
compete with market securities.

But many savings and loan

associations are not in a position to pay appreciably higher rates,
and their future would be in jeopardy if they tried to do so. In
either case, the availability of mortgage credit might be affected
very adversely.
It thus appears that mortgage loans will remain in relatively
short supply in the months immediately ahead, particularly in
states with low usury ceilings, and that the volume of residential
construction will consequently suffer.

There is reason to believe,

however, that the contraction in housing activity that we now face
will be milder than the declines of 1966 or 1969.

-17-

A number of structural changes in housing finance
during recent years have reduced the dependence of the housing
industry on mortgage loans from nonbank thrift institutions.
For one thing, private sources of funds for mortgage credit
have been broadened.

Thus, the GNMA.-guaranteed mortgage

bonds now attract private pension funds and other investors
who previously stayed out of the mortgage market; at present,
some $10 billion of such bonds are outstanding.
investment trusts have also been growing.

Real estate

In the second quarter

of this year, they supplied mortgage credit at an annual rate
of $4 billion.

Commercial banks now furnish a larger share

of residential mortgage credit - - over 20 per cent in the first
half of this year, compared with about 15 per cent in the decade
of the 1960!s.

Moreover, mortgages have generally become more

attractive to private investors because of the growth of opportunities
to insure conventional mortgages and the enlargement of secondary
market facilities.
The capability of Federal agencies to come to the aid of
housing in times of difficulty has also been bolstered.

The

Federal National Mortgage Association and the Federal Home

-18-

Loan Mortgage Corporation are now authorized to buy
conventional mortgages as well as government-guaranteed
mortgages, so that their efforts to ^support housing activity
can be broadly based.

The financial position of FNMA has

become stronger in recent years, and its security issues are
widely regarded as an attractive investment medium.

So also

are the securities issued by the Federal Home Loan Banks to
obtain funds for lending to savings institutions.

Advances from

the Federal Home Loan Banks through August of this year
already total $5-1/2 billion, and they can be increased
substantially further, if that should be necessary.
The Federal Reserve, on its part, has made plans for
providing emergency credit to S&L!s and mutual savings banks
in the unlikely event that such a need arises.

We have also

sought to improve the market for the securities issued by the
Federal housing credit agencies.

Since September 1971, when

we began making outright purchases and sales of agency issues,
the spread between the yields on these obligations and those of
the Treasury has narrowed, particularly for the shorter
maturities.

Our acquisitions were not the only reason for the

lower spread, but I believe they made a constructive contribution.

-19Of greater importance, the Federal Reserve Board this
May raised from 5 to 8 per cent the reserve requirement applicable
to increases in the amount of large-denomination certificates of
deposit (CD's) outstanding at the larger banks.

This step increased

the cost to banks of the funds that they principally use to finance
business loans.

Last Friday, the incremental reserve require-

ment against CD's was raised again, this time to 11 per cent.
To the extent that this new reserve requirement restrains
bank lending to the business sector, it should help to relieve
pressures on residential mortgage credit.
In view of the structural changes in housing finance and
related developments, I believe that the housing industry is in
a better position now than it was a few years ago to weather
the pressures of financial restraint.

But additional actions

are needed to achieve an acceptable degree of stability in housing
finance and construction.
For the immediate future, the single most constructive
step that could be taken by the Congress would be to increase
the degree of fiscal restraint on aggregate demand.

I for one

would support stronger efforts to cut governmental expenditures,
or actions to increase taxes.

Particularly appropriate would

be fiscal measures that could be quickly reversed if economic

-20-

activity began to weaken.

Steps to increase fiscal restraint now

could have dramatic effects on financial markets, with substantial
benefits for the supply of mortgage credit and housing.
I would also urge the Congress to abolish altogether
the present ceiling rates of interest on FHA and VA loans.
True, these ceiling rates have not been a significant impediment
to mortgage credit supplies this year, but that is only because
HUD and the VA have acted rather promptly to keep the ceilings
in line with market rates of interest.

In some states, usury

ceilings have dried up the supply of mortgage credit almost
completely,

If the Congress acted decisively on FHA and VA

ceilings, State legislators would be more inclined to raise or
eliminate the usury ceilings that are presently curtailing
residential building in their area.
This Committee could also be of great service to the
housing industry by supporting reforms to moderate shortterm swings in the supply of mortgage credit ctnd home construction.

Some of the measures needed are relatively non-

controversial, could be acted on quickly, and would improve
the outlook for housing finance even in the short run.

The

-21-

Board's earlier recommendations to remove the legal restrictions
on real estate loans by national banks, and to permit the Federal
Reserve to lend to member banks on any sound collateral, including mortgages, fall into this category.

Other measures

will need to be debated at greater length, and it is therefore
all the more urgent that the Congress initiate constructive
deliberation of basic reforms.

The highest priority should

be given to making fiscal policy a more flexible tool for economic
stabilization.

A promising way to accomplish this, as the Board

indicated in its housing report in early 1972, would be to make
the investment tax credit variable over the business cycle.
If the tax credit for business investment were lowered
during economic booms and raised in periods of slack, the
rate of business capital spending would be more stable, and
so would interest rates and the flow of funds into housing.
The Board recommends again, therefore, that the President
be authorized to propose changes in the tax credit, within a
range of perhaps 3 to 12 or 15 per cent, subject to Congressional
approval or disapproval under special procedures to assure
prompt consideration.

-22-

Better control of the Federal budget would also be of
great value.

The Board welcomes the efforts of the Joint

Study Committee on Budget Control, the Rules Committee of
the House, and the Government Operations Committee of the
Senate to reform budgetary procedures by fixing firmly the
expenditure total for a fiscal year and then establishing
Congressional priorities within that total.
Reforms are also needed to improve the ability of
depository institutions to compete for individual savings in
periods of rising interest rates.

The Board would urge once

again the adoption of legislation to encourage a moderate amount
of investment by S&L's in consumer loans, so that their earnings
rates would be more flexible.

A more significant contribution

to this objective would come from the use by depository institutions
of mortgage loans with variable interest rates to finance the
purchase of homes and apartment buildings.
The thoughts I have put before this Committee today are
confined to the problem of cyclical swings in housing.
a critical current problem.

.This is

That is why I have emphasized not

only the desirability of changes in the structure of housing
finance, but also the importance of basic reforms in fiscal
policy.

Once fiscal reforms are carried out, there will be

less need to depend upon monetary restraint in the course of
a business-cycle expansion.