View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

release on delivery
•m., Eastern Daylight Time
lursday, June 25, 1970

JOt 1 0 -

The Economic Contest Between Freedom and Authoritarianism

Address by Arthur F, Burns,
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve S ^

Chungang University
Seoul, Korea
June 26, 1970

The Economic Contest Between Freedom
and Authoritarianism

Dr# Yim, distinguished guests, and ladies and gentlemen,

I am

deeply moved by the honor that Chungang University has seen fit to
bestow upon me today*

I am also happy to have the opportunity to visit

the Republic of Korea at this moment in history.

It is just twenty years

since the armies to the north swept across the 38th parallel in their
effort to bring all the people of Korea under the yoke of tyranny*
Because of the valor of your own people and the support of
the United States and the other countries that rallied to the aid of
the Republic of Korea, you conquered adversity and succeeded in preserving the right to live in dignity as free men and women*
As we think back to those days of struggle, we can give
thanks that there were men of indomitable will and courage who recognised
the vital importance to Asia and the civilized world of the preservation
of freedom for 20 million Koreans,
There were, to be sure, those in the West who described the
desperate struggle for the survival of the free Republic of Korea as a
quarrel in which other nations had no right to intervene. There were
those who said that the Republic of Korea was not really a democratic
country and that it made little difference whether it was ruled by
Syngman Rhee or Kim II Sung*

There were even those who told us that

poor people cared nothing about abstract concepts such as freedom and
democracy, that the Koreans were mainly interested in material wellbeing, and that they could achieve this more quickly under communism
than under the free market economy that prevailed in the Republic of
Korea•

r3-

At the same time, Mr* Khrushchev began to make the point that
a similar contest was underway between the United States and the U,S*S,R.
He boasted that the Soviet system was vastly superior and that the Soviet
Union would surpass the United States in production per capita and in
the standard of living by 1970*

It may be worth recalling Khrushchev's

wordst
"the superiority of the U*S«S,R« in the speed of
growth of production will create a real basis for
insuring that within a period of, say, five years
following 1965, the level of U.S, production per
capita should be equalled and overtaken* Thus by
that time, perhaps even sooner, the U.S*S,R» will
have captured first place in the world both in
absolute volume of production and per capita production, which will insure the world's highest standard
of living,19
Such claims were taken seriously by many people in the West
and in the East, Some came to doubt that the free market system was
the most efficient and equitable instrumentality for increasing the
national wealth. They took the view that freedom wa$ a luxury that
poor nations could ill afford. They argued that the underdeveloped
countries had to resort to authoritarian control of economic activity,
if not also to outright governmental ownership of the productive resources
in the economy. And, in fact, a number of countries in Asia did adopt
in varying degrees the policy of turning over to the government the
decision-making functions that are performed by private citizens in
countries that practice free enterprise*
Those who adopted this approach overlooked the fact that
Adam Smith, the father of the Idea that freedom was more conducive to

economic growth than governmental control, had addressed himself to the
problems of a nation that was then very poor and very underdeveloped -that is, to the England of 1776*

Two hundred years ago, English peasants,

living at a subsistence level without any of the benefits of modern
industry or science to ameliorate their condition, were probably worse
off than their counterparts in most of free Asia today#

And the French

peasants lived in even greater poverty than the English*
Adam Smith examined the results of governmental intervention
into economic activity in 18th century England and France with a perceptive eye. He came to the conclusion that the inefficient use of
resources that he observed could be remedied and that wealth could be
augmented if individuals had greater freedom to manage their economic
affairs as they saw fit, instead of being tied down by minute and exacting regulations prescribed by bureaucrats*

Smith saw that detailed

economic regulations, often laid down by authorities far removed from
the actual operations or needs of industry and commerce, produced
undesirable results even though they may have been or actually were
well-intentioned.

In time, as the force of Smith's logic and evidence

won adherents among men of authority, his revolutionary ideas proved
instrumental in sweeping away much of the regulatory complex that had
retarded economic progress and in paving the way for the extraordinary
increase in living standards that has occurred in the West during the
past two centuries.
It has been said that those who will not learn from the errors
of the past are doomed to repeat them. This has been the fate of much

-5of Asia in the period following World War II. Fortunately, the Republic
of Korea escaped falling under the control of the Marxists and chose to
enter the economic contest on the side of freedom*
In addition to being the twentieth anniversary of the invasion
of the Republic of Korea, 1970 was also to be the year when the U.S.S«R»
would overtake the United States economically, according to Khrushchev's
boast.

It is fitting, therefore, that we look back over recent years

and examine the results of that contest between economic freedom and
authoritarianism*

The Contest Between the United States and the Soviet Union
The economic contest between the U«S.S*R« and the United States
enters the year 1970 with the United States holding a commanding lead.
In 1969 the gross national product per person in our country was nearly
$4,600.

This was two-and-a-half times the corresponding Soviet figure.

Measured in real terms, the gap between the per capita GWP of the
United States and the Soviet Union was more than 25 per cent higher in
1969 than in I960,

While the Soviet growth rate was slightly higher

than the American rate, the difference was so slight that if the same
growth rates were maintained over the next 50 years, the per capita
GNP of the United States would still be about twice that of the Soviet
Union in the year 2020,
The persisting wide difference between the living standards
of the Soviet Union and the United States is vividly portrayed by
comparisons of the cost of goods and services and average wages in the

two countries,*

If the prices of goods and services are expressed in

terms of the number of working hours required to earn enough to buy
them, the difference in living standards appears to be even larger
than the crude comparison of per capita GNP figures suggests.
It turns out, for example, that the average worker in Moscow
in April 1969 had to work nearly seven times as long as his counterpart in New York to earn enough to buy an identical supply of food
sufficient to feed a family of four for one week*

The difference for

xmny non-*food items was even larger. The following are the multiples
by which the cost of certain goods in Moscow exceeded the cost in New
York, when cost is measured in terms of working time:

for bath soap -

1215 times, for nylon stockings - 14 times, for a man*s shirt - 12
times, for a refrigerator - 12 times.
These comparisons are based on official prices in Moscow,
not black market prices, which are, in many cases, far higher. For
example, a Volga sedan costing the equivalent of $7^700 reportedly
sells for 2,5 times that amount on the Moscow black market.
The inability of the Soviet Union to approach the economic
performance of the United States has not been as widely publicized
as the dramatic earlier forecasts by the Soviet leaders. Nevertheless, this failure provides valuable economic lessons.

The rather

high rates of economic growth that were recorded for the Soviet Union
in the early postwar years have not been sustained because of deficiencies

inherent in the Soviet system, as their own economists have begun to
realize*

In a free economy, the relative strength of the demand for

goods and services determines the allocation of productive resources.
In the Soviet system, on the other hand, the path that production takes
is basically determined by the decisions of economic planners in Moscow*
Important economic decisions in the Soviet Union have therefore
not been guided by sensitive economic signals such as are constantly
being transmitted by costs and prices in a free market economy. To make
matters worse, until recently, they were not even subject to correction
by public criticism.

Thus, economic success in the Soviet system came

to be measured, traditionally, in terms of meeting targets set by the
government, rather than in meeting the wants of consumers. This sometimes led to production of equipment that failed to work or to the output
of some consumer goods far in excess of demand while other goods continued
to be in critically short supply.

Such production might be expressed in

a high rate of growth of GNP, but it did not bring progress in the elevation of living standards.

In time the waste involved in this process

became a matter of grave concern to Soviet officials, particularly to
economists and engineers*
As early as 1959, a Soviet econometrician, L. V. Kantorovich,
pointed out that it might be advantageous if prices were allowed to
play a bigger role in guiding the allocation of resources in the Soviet
economy«

Another Soviet economist, Professor Y, Libertnan proposed that

profitability rather than achievement of planned targets be used as the
measure of success or failure of productive enterprise.

Although the Soviet Union has tried some experiments with
reforms along these lines, there has been no correction of the fundamental flaws of the communist economic system either in the Soviet Union
or in its satellite countries*

In Gzechoslovakia the frustration with

the results of centralized decision-making, which reached a climax during
the industrial recession of the sixties, was an important factor in the
reform movement in 1967-68, but the courageous effort to rationalize
the economy by giving greater play to individual decision-making was
brought to an abrupt end by Soviet troops and tanks in the summer of
1969,
This result was nc great surprise to those who recognized
that the reforms required to rationalize the Soviet-style economic system
would weaken, if not totally destroy, the political control wielded by
the Communist party#

Two observers of the Eastern European scene pointed

this out a year and a half before the Czech liberalization movement was
crushed.

They said:
"Some variations of a limited free-price system
are being introduced requiring enterprises to pay
some attention to what the market, i.e., the consumer,
wants* But there is small sign that the central
planners are ready to make these valid by yielding or
reducing their arbitrary rule over production costs
and profit. They cling to their power to fix prices
of raw materials, semi-finished products, fuel and
power, the size of total payroll and individual
wages, the wholesale and retail prices of finished
goods • * . • Surrender of production and investment
controls deprives the party faithful of jobs and
strips the party of influence • * . • Confronted by
such a menace, the Red regimes are marking time with
half-measures .

SSG

-9Faced with a choice between introducing economic rationality
and the maintenance of their political power, the Russian rulers chose
power, Unless and until they are willing to change their approach, it
seems likely that their own economy and that of their satellites will
continue to lag far behind the United States and other advanced countries
of the free world*

The Failure of Communist China*s Great Leap Forward
Even before it appeared that the Soviet Union was not going
to be successful in challenging the economic pre-eminence of the United
States in the 1960fs, it became clear that Communist China was not going
to demonstrate to the free countries of Asia a better way to augment
their wealth and income•
The year 1958 was hailed as Communist China's ngreat leap
forward/1

It was claimed that food output had been doubled in a single

year, and that final victory had been achieved over hunger*

These

claims were soon exposed as wild exaggerations, as it became evident
in 1959 and 1960 that serious food shortages had begun to reappear*
Far from developing self-sufficiency in food and eliminating hunger,
Communist China experienced critical food shortages in the early 1960's
and was compelled to import huge quantities of grain from abroad to
meet her requirements. The agricultural communes which had been so
widely acclaimed as the realization of true communism were quietly
abandoned or radically modified. Agriculture in China appears to have
remained virtually stagnant throughout the 1960fs* Although production

-10-

figures have been withheld, the available evidence suggests that output
may not even have kept pace with the increase in population.

In the

early 1960's, the food shortages were attributed by government officials
to bad weather, but this excuse was soon dropped as food imports continued to be required year after year.
The failures of agriculture had serious effects throughout the
Communist Chinese economy.

It soon became necessary to retrench dras-

tically the plans for industry and transportation.

Resources were

simply not available to push forward the grandiose schemes that were
supposed to show the rest of Asia hoxtf a country could rise from agricultural poverty to industrial affluence by purusing the Communist path.
Official statistics on economic performance of Communist China became
very scarce as the boasted

!f

great leap forward11 failed to materialize.

Talk of competition between Communist China and free Asia dropped to a
whisper once it became evident that the free countries were well ahead
in the contest*

Economic Success in Free Asia
The countries of Asia that have relied basically on the free
market system and have avoided centralization of economic decisions in
the hands of the government have clearly been winning the economic
contest. They are the countries that have been most successful in
increasing the wealth of their people and in raising their standard of
livings

The countries that have done the least well have tended to be

the ones that either rejected the free market or severely limited it by
governmental controls.

-11Notth Korea, to be sure, has been claiming a high growth rate,
as have other Communist countries in the earlier stages of their development • There is, however, good reason to believe that North Korea suffers
from the same serious difficulty that the other Communist economies have
encountered —

namely, a tendency to sacrifice quality and serviceability

in order to achieve quantitative production targets* Also, as one of
the top North Korean leaders recently noted, there are serious deficiencies in the supply of consumer goods. Here is what he saids

ff

The

problem is that leading cadres are irresponsible and unconcerned about
the working peoples1 problems of food, clothing, and housing/1
The great economic success stories of Asia in the 1960*s are
found in countries like the Republic of Korea, Japan, Nationalist China,
Thailand, Hong Kong, and Malaysia. These countries, in the 10 years
ending in 1968, have all recorded average increases in real output of
6 per cent a year or more. Hong Kong and Japan led the way with average
annual growth rates of 10 per cent or higher in this period.

South

Korea had a very respectable average rate of growth of 7.5 per cent for
the entire decade; but for the last five years, after important economic
reforms were implemented, Korea's average rate has also been in excess
of 10 per cent a year.
Rates of growth of GNP can be misleading, especially in
countries where the underlying statistical data are inadequate and of
doubtful validity. There are also problems with the proper valuation
of output in different countries. The over-valuation of goods of dubious
serviceability undoubtedly tends to exaggerate the value of output in

-12the Communist countries. For example, the inferior iron that was
produced in the famous backyard blast furnaces of Communist China back
in the late 1950's was included in the output totals even though it
served no useful purpose*
It is therefore desirable to check the growth figures of GNF
against other records*

One useful indicator of underlying growth is

the trend of exports,., since it measures the ability to compete abroad
and thus tests a country1s efficiency in keeping up with the standards
being set elsewhere.
Professor Ota Sik, the architect of the short-lived economic
reform in Czechoslovakia, called attention to the fact that Communist
economies have great difficulty in meeting the test of economic efficiency posed by exports* As he put it;

ff

0n the foreign markets,

Czechoslovak production is absolutely unable to adjust to changes in
demand*15

This difficulty has in practice been compounded by production

of shoddy quality, poor pricing, and ineffective marketing*
Applying the export test, we find that the countries in Asia
that had high rates of overall economic growth in the 1958-68 period,
also did very well in expanding their exports. The Republic of Korea
recorded a phenomenal increase in exports, averaging 40 per cent a year
over the decade. Next came Nationalist China, with an annual rate of
export growth of nearly 19 per cent, followed by Japan with a rate of
over 15 per cent and Hong Kong with 13 per cent*
There are fascinating stories behind these statistics* The
amazing record of Korea in expanding exports from almost nothing a

decade ago to over $600 million last year is a modern miracle.

I am

also impressed by the fact that tiny Hong Kong, with a population of
only 4 million, exported about as much in 1969 as all of India*
The export experience of South Korea illustrates how difficult
it is for any economist, no matter how farsighted he may be, to chart
the future course of a nation1s development.

In 1969, two of the largest

export earners of the Republic of Korea were plywood and wigs -- items
that were not even listed in the export statistics of 1958. It would
have taken an inspired prophet to foresee a decade ago the role that
these goods would come to play in providing foreign exchange resources
to Korea,
One of the great virtues of a free economy is that it permits
the development of the unexpected»

Given proper incentives, the private

entrepreneurs of South Korea found many new uses for labor, utilizing
raw materials, such as wood, that had to be imported from distant lands•
There were failures as well as successes, but the end result has been
a rapid development of production and exports that had not been previously
dreamed of, much less planned.
The lesson behind Korea's experience is an old one. Where
men are given the opportunity and incentives to make and sell the
products of their labor in free markets, they will tend to act in ways
that increase productive efficiency and thereby raise the living standards
of the country as a whole. To be sure, freedom of entrepreneurs, workers,
and consumers to make their own decisions is by no means the sole determinant of how well a country will perform economically.

A nation must

-14also pursue sound monetary, fiscal, and trade policies in order to
achieve the economic growth of which it is capable*

But there can not

be the slightest doubt, in view of the experience accumulated over
centuries, that free and competitive markets are a major determinant
of economic growth and widespread prosperity.
It is no accident that the Asian countries that experienced
the slowest rates of growth in 1958-68 were also the countries that
leaned most heavily on centralized economic controls. The countries at
the bottom of the scale in terms of growth of real GNP include Ceylon,
Burma, India, and Indonesia.

Each of these countries has experimented

extensively with government ownership or control over economic activities.
Burma in particular has gone far toward economic authoritarianism.
Its government has exercised far-reaching controls over production, trade,
and finance, with the result that both production and distribution have
been hampered*

The output of Burma's main crop, rice, has been adversely

affected by pricing policies that have denied producers adequate incentives.

Over the past decade, neighboring Thailand has increased rice

exports by 28 per cent, while Burma's exports of rice have fallen nearly
two-thirds. The result is that Burma's total exports are now running
at less than half the 1963 level. The ability to import has fallen
correspondingly, and the Burmese people have found it increasingly
difficult to buy consumer goods that are found in abundance in neighboring countries,
Indonesia under President Sukarno followed economic policies
that were in some respects more harmful than those of Burma. In addition

-15to establishing stifling controls over production and trade, Sukarno's
government borrowed heavily abroad, largely to build up a military
machine, but partly also to finance ambitious projects that in the
end yielded little or no economic return. The productive capital of
the country was therefore badly eroded, exports fell sharply, living
standards declined, and the country found itself saddled with huge
foreign debts and with diminished ability to produce the exports needed
to service the debt*

Fortunately, Indonesia is now in process of liber*

alizing her economy and dismantling the pervasive fegulations that were
imposed on her economic structure*

However, the country will require

many years to recuperate from the damage wrought by the Sukarno policies•
The adverse impact of authoritarian economic policies has
also been felt in India, though to a much lesser degree than in either
Burma or Indonesia.

India over the past decade and a half has emphasized

strong centralized control over investment, backed by extensive restrictions on imports and foreign exchange expenditures•

Fortunately, there

is a growing recognition in India that mistakes large enough to retard
significantly the rate of economic growth have been made*

The earlier

decisions to emphasize heavy industry at the expense of light industry
and agriculture are now being questioned*

The low rates of return on

many government industrial investments have also raised serious doubts
both about the original decisions and the management of the resulting
public enterprises^

The failure to provide incentives to exports has

left India lagging far behind many other countries, and has contributed
to balance-of-payments difficulties which necessitated ever tighter

import restrictions• As a result, India has passed through a difficult
period during which many of her industrial enterprises were deprived
of the supplies and equipment required to keep operating at reasonable
rates.
Division of labor, territorial specialization, freedom of
trade, and decentralisation of economic decision-making —

these were

key elements in the thinking of the founder of classical economics,
Adam Smith,

It is gratifying to see that the practical statesmen of

the world are gradually rediscovering these essential truths. In this
rediscovery of truth, we owe a great deal to countries like the Republic
of Korea, Japan, Nationalist China, Hong Kong, and Thailand that have
most recently demonstrated how men operating in free markets can outperform authoritarianism in the economic contest*
I see in the economic experience of both the countries that
have lately succeeded and those that have failed a basis for optimism
about the future*

What has gone wrong, after all, is not something

immutable. As the case of South Korea shows, a country can change its
future by changing its policies. The countries that have lagged in
the economic contest have the opportunity to learn from experience and
to alter their course.
The desire for economic development is a strong force in the
modern world, and it deserves every encouragement,

I have concentrated

today on the economic framework that is conducive to rational economic
growth and on the policies that are within the control of the developing
countries themselves. These are of vital importance.

However, I am not unmindful of the responsibilities that fall
on the large industrialized countries, including my own? to help the
development process*
contribution*

We have, at times, overestimated our potential

There has been a tendency at times to think that external

technical assistance, or external capital, could of itself provide sufficient impetus to generate rapid growth all over the world*

We now

appreciate that the solutions are more complex,, Nevertheless, technical
assistance, capital flows, whether governmental or private, and liberal
trade policies on the part of the industrialized countries can contribute
significantly to the process of economic development.

It is by no means

clear that the rich industrial countries are doing all that they might
along these lines*
And yet I think that the export of technology and management
is by far the most important contribution that the industrialized
countries can make to the developing nations. The world has never
known a period in whicih the technical means for increasing man's productive capacity have been so readily available*

The countries that

will profit most from these favorable conditions are those that eschew
authoritarianism, that base their economic policies on the moral concept that men can better themselves most effectively by practicing
free and competitive enterprise, and at the same time pursue overall
monetary and fiscal policies that guard the nation against possible
ravages of both recession and inflation*

-0-