View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

^ ' 1_^"

For release on delivery

Statement by

Arthur F. Burns

Chairman* Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Committee on Banking* Currency and Housing

House of Representatives

July 24, 1975

I welcome this opportunity to discuss the condition of
the national economy and to convey the Federal Reserve's views
on monetary policy.
The performance of our economy during the past two
years has been disappointing.

We have suffered the most

damaging peacetime inflation in our nation1 s history, a critical
shortage of energy supplies, and the deepest decline in business
activity since the end of World War II.

Similar problems have

plagued practically every industrial country in the world.
The recession of 1974-75 in our country will, I believe*
be viewed by economic historians as the culminating phase of a
long cycle in economic activity that began in 1961. During the
industrial phase of the long upswing - - from 1961 through 1964 productivity grew rapidly, prices remained quite stable, and
real wages and profits kept advancing.

During the next ten years -

from 1965 through 1974 — the strength of the American economy
was gradually undermined.

A succession of interrelated, partly

overlapping, waves of speculation occurred - - first

in merging

business enterprises and organizing conglomerates; next in the
stock market; then in the real estate market; and finally in the
markets for industrial materials and other commodities.

During

-2-

this long speculative phase, productivity languished and expansion
in the physical volume of output decelerated, while the pace of
inflation kept quickening - - mainly, but by no means entirely,
in response to the lax financial practices of the Federal Government.

Bad harvests, extraordinary increases in the price of oil,

another devaluation of the dollar, and the coincidence of booming
business around the world played their part in the inflationary
process during 1973 and 1974.
As a result of these myriad developments, seeds of
recession were sown across the economy.

Inflation led to a

burgeoning of credit demands, both public and private, and
interest rates soared to unprecedented heights.

Rising consumer

prices eroded the purchasing power of workers' incomes and
savings.

The sharp rise in the price of oil caused a diversion

of purchasing power to foreign suppliers.

Corporate profits

diminished - - a fact that businessmen were slow to recognize
because of accounting techniques that failed to take account of
inflation.

Construction of new dwellings and office buildings

proceeded on a scale that greatly exceeded underlying demand.
And inventories of commodities piled up, often at a very rapid

pace, as businessmen reacted to fears of shortages and of
accelerating price increases.
By the spring of 1973, signs of faltering in the pace of
economic expansion had already emerged.

Homebuilding began

to turn down, and so too did sales of mobile homes, new autos,
and other big-ticket consumer items.

A declining trend in the

physical volume of other goods purchased by consumers soon
followed,

These developments, however, were largely over-

looked by a business community caught up in the euphoria created
by inflation.

New orders flowing to manufacturers continued to

rise, order backlogs generally increased, and stockpiles of
materials and other commodities mounted*

By the summer of

1974, the physical volume of business inventories was already
higher in relation to sales than at any time since the Korean War,
The stage was thus set for a significant economic adjustment*
The recession that ensued has cut deeply into the nation's
economic life.

Between September 1974 and May of this year,

industrial output fell by 12-1/2 per cent.

Total employment

dropped by 2-1/2 million from its peak in October 1974 to a
low in March of this year.

And the rate of unemployment rose

-4-

from under 5 per cent in late 1973 to perhaps 9 per cent at
the present time.
in view of the serious economic imbalances caused by
inflation, the recession has been performing a painful, but un^avoidable, function.

Corrective forces have been released and

they have helped lay the basis for a renewal of sound economic
expansion,
Thus9 business competition is now much keener than
it was a year or two ago.

Business managers are also devoting

more attention to cost control and improvements in efficiency.
Prices of industrial raw materials have fallen substantially.
Price increases at later stages of processing have also become
less extensive.

The rise of the general price level has therefore

slowed — from an annual rate of about 12 to 14 per cent late
last year to about half that rate recently e

Increases of wage rates,

moreover, have moderated, although they still are much higher
than the long-run rate of improvement in productivity.

Meanwhile,

stock prices - - a significant indicator of the state of confidence -have risen substantially.
The slowdown in the pace of inflation and the revived
stock market have bolstered the confidence of the general

-5-

public.

Early this year, as price concessions on autos and

other items became common, consumer purchases - - especially
of durable goods - - began to pick up.

In fact, consumer expendi-

tures during the first quarter rose in real terms as well as
in-dollars.

This strengthening continued in the second quarter,

as spendable incomes of consumers were augmented - - first
by tax rebate checks, later by extra social security checks.
With consumer buying expanding and production declining, the
efforts of business firms to work down their excess stocks have
been remarkably successful.

Inventories of most consumer goods

now seem to be in rather good balance with sales.
Significant progress has also been made in improving the
financial position of business firms.

Corporations have issued

exceptionally large amounts of longer-term securities this
year, and they have used much of the proceeds to repay shortterm debt or to acquire liquid assets.

The liquidity position

of consumers has likewise been strengthened; instalment debts
to banks and other lenders have been paid down, and many
millions of individuals have added substantially to their savings
deposits and other liquid assets.

Financial institutions, too, have improved their financial
condition.

Commercial banks have taken advantage of the reduced

demand for business and consumer loans to repay their borrowings
from Federal Reserve Banks, to reduce their reliance on volatile
sources of funds, and to rebuild liquid assets.

In their turn^

savings and loan associations and mutual savings banks reduced
their indebtedness and enlarged their holdings of Treasury
securities and other liquid assets, thus laying the basis for a
renewed expansion of mortgage lending in recent months.
These self-corrective forces have been aided powerfully
by fiscal and monetary policies that sought to cushion the effects
of economic adversity, moderate recessionary forces, and
provide some stimulus to economic recovery.

I need not dwell

on the fiscal measures that have been adopted to combat recessionary forces; these measures have already been widely discussed.
Let me note merely that I believe the Congress acted wisely in
providing only a temporary fiscal stimulus through the Tax
Reduction Act of 1975.

The confidence of our citizens in the

nation's economic future has been bolstered by evidence that
responsible members of both the executive and legislative
branches of our government are seeking ways to stimulate recovery
without releasing a new wave of inflation.

This principle has also guided monetary policy.

Last

summer, as signs of weakening in economic activity multiplied,
the Federal Reserve began taking steps to increase the availability
of money and credit.

Open market operations were oriented

toward a more liberal provision of reserves to the banking
system; later, these actions were reinforced by several reductions
in the discount rate and in reserve requirements.
During the fall and winter months the demand for credit
by businesses and consumers weakened on account of the recession,
and commercial banks used the more abundant supply of reserves
to repay their indebtedness to the Federal Reserve.

Growth in M,,

that is, currency plus demand deposits, was therefore slow to
reflect the easing of monetary policy.

We at the Federal Reserve

were concerned about this development, but we refused to run the
risk of releasing fresh inflationary forces and rekindling inflationary
expectations.

In any event, broader monetary aggregates displayed

a more vigorous response to our easing actions.

For example,

flows of individual savings into commercial banks and thrift
institutions began to pick up in the fourth quarter of 1974, and
by the first quarter of this year, these deposits were expanding
at a seasonally adjusted annual rate of over 13 per cent.

In fact,

-8-

recent rates of growth of the monetary aggregates have been
generally higher than during comparable periods of earlier
postwar recessions.
The efforts of the Federal Reserve to ease credit conditions,
together with the weakening of private credit demands, resulted
in a sharp decline of short-term rates of interest.

The Federal

funds rate - - that is, the interest rate banks pay when borrowing
reserves from one another - - fell from a high of 13-1/2 per cent
last summer to about 5-1/4 per cent in early June.

The commer-

cial paper rate declined from over 12 per cent last July to a low
of about 5-1/2 per cent.

And the prime rate of interest on bank

loans to businesses fell from 12 per cent to a low of 7 per cent.
In the markets for long-term securities, interest rates
also declined, although much less than short-term rates. Of
course, long-term rates typically fluctuate within a narrower
range than short-term rates; but in the present instance, other
powerful factors have also been at work.

Fears of inflation are

still widespread, and long-term interest rates therefore still
contain a sizable inflation premium.

Moreover, corporations

have issued an enormous volume of bonds in the first half of
this year; State and local governments have borrowed large sums

-9-

in the capital markets; and troublesome uncertainties have been
created by the financial problems of some borrowers in the
municipal bond market.

Also, the huge financing demands of

the Treasury have been a disturbing element in the money and
capital markets.
Despite these problems, conditions in financial markets
have greatly improved over the past six to nine months, and a
financial basis has been established for an upturn in business
activity.
Signs have multiplied in recent weeks that the economy
is moving through a turning zone from recession to recovery.
As already noted, retail sales have been gaining strength
progressively since early this year.

The appreciable pickup

in new auto sales over the past several months is continuing.
Sales of new houses started rising early this year, and as the
backlog of unsold units declined, building permits and new
housing starts also began to move up.
With excess inventories at retail, wholesale, and
manufacturing firms being worked off and the curve of consumer
sales still rising, businessmen have become more optimistic
about the future.

New orders for durable goods - - a n important

leading indicator of industrial activity *-- have of late been rising

-10-

agaln.

Moreover, industrial production, after declining for

eight consecutive months, registered its first advance in June.
In the labor market, too, there are numerous signs of
improvement.

The range of nonfarm industries adding to the

number on their payrolls has been widening steadily, from a
low of 17 per cent in February to about 50 per cent in May and
June; total employment has increased by 600, 000 over the past
three months; the average factory workweek has lengthened; and
of late, initial claims for unemployment insurance have dropped
sharply.
We may be reasonably confident, therefore, that a
recovery in business activity will develop soon, if it is not
already underway.

How strong the recovery will be, no one

can foresee with any assurance.

There are ample amounts

of idle labor and capital resources to permit rapid growth over
the next several quarters.

Past cyclical experience suggests,

moreover, that a steep decline in business activity such as we
have experienced is usually followed by a brisk recovery.
A central objective of Federal Reserve policy at the
present time is to contribute to a substantial expansion in output
and employment.

The vigor of economic recovery, however,

will depend less on the rate of expansion in money and credit

-11-

than on the confidence of the public - - in particular, the willingness of businesses and consumers to put the enormous volume
of existing money balances to work.
The turnover of money, or its velocity* varies widely
in the course of a business cycle.

During the first year of

earlier postwar recoveries, the velocity of M-, - - that is, the
ratio of the dollar value of the gross national product to the
narrowly defined money supply - - has usually risen about 5 or
6 per cent, compared with a rate of increase in M, of around 3
or 4 per cent.

As confidence in the economy improves in the

months ahead, the velocity of money - - which declined during
the past several quarters - - will probably increase significantly.
This factor is frequently neglected by economists and others,
but we at the Federal Reserve cannot afford to do so.
In conducting monetary policy, we will also have to
remain mindful of the urgency of dealing with the longer-run
problem of inflation as well as with the current problem of
unemployment.

Economic recovery is apparently beginning at

a time when the rate of inflation, while lower than a year ago, is
still well above a tolerable pace.

Our objective as a nation should

be to achieve further moderation in the advance of the general

-12-

price level over the months ahead, and we shall therefore need
to avoid actions that threaten an acceleration of inflation later
on - - a development that would create even more intractable
economic problems than we have yet encountered.

I was glad

to see the Senate Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban
Affairs recognize this basic truth in its recent report on
monetary policy, which states unequivocally that "if inflation
is rekindled, any recovery will be short-lived and will end in
another recession, one almost certain to be more virulent than
the present one, "
In testifying before that Committee on May 1 of this year,
I indicated that the course of monetary policy cannot be understood adequately by focusing on any single measure of money
balances.

Some observers believe that the Federal Reserve

should devote almost exclusive attention to the behavior of
M, - - that is, currency plus demand deposits.

We in the Federal

Reserve do not take so narrow a view of our responsibilities.
The public's demand for currency, for checking deposits,
for savings deposits, and for a host of other liquid assets is
constantly changing.

Financial technology in our country has

developed rapidly in the past 20 to 30 years.

As a rule, consumers

-13-

and business firms no longer hold all, or even most, of their
spendable funds in the form of currency or demand deposits.
More and more corporate treasurers have learned how to get
along with a minimum of deposits in their checking accounts.
Consumers, too, have learned to keep an increasing part of
their transactions and precautionary balances in the form of
savings deposits at commercial banks, or deposits in savings
and loan associations, or certificates of deposit, or Treasury
bills, or shares in money-market funds, or other income-earning
liquid instruments.

These trends are likely to continue.

Use

of so-called NOW accounts and other interest-bearing deposits
for transactions purposes is growing, and electronic funds transfer
systems may well revolutionize the payments mechanism and the
forms in which money is held.

In this day and age, no single

concept of money conveys adequately the spendable funds held
by the public.
Viewed in isolation, the behavior of the narrowly-defined
money supply, Mj, can actually be a misleading guide to the
degree of monetary ease or restraint*

For example, in periods

uf declining economic activity, both the transactions demand for
cash and the private demand for credit will tend to weaken and
thus slow the growth of M]^.

But during such periods market

-14-

rates of interest usually decline and thereby stimulate faster
rates of growth of consumer-type deposits at commercial banks
and other financial institutions.
During periods of economic expansion, the behavior of
Mj may again be misleading.

At such times, large demands

for credit and money are likely to strengthen the growth of Mj,
but open-market interest rates will tend to rise and thereby
curtail the flow of individual savings to banks and thrift institutions.
A monetary policy formulated on the basis of Mj alone would
ignore the pressures of disintermediation that develop in periods
of economic expansion, and thus threaten serious damage to the
mortgage market and to the homebuilding industry.
To avoid errors of this kind, the Federal Reserve takes
into account the behavior of numerous monetary and credit
aggregates in conducting monetary policy.

Among these is M2,

which includes - - besides currency and demand deposits - consumer-type time deposits at commercial banks; M3, a still
broader composite, which includes also the deposits at savings
banks, savings and loan associations, and credit unions; M4,
which starts with M2 and adds large certificates of deposit
issued by commercial banks; M5, which is more comprehensive

-15-

than any of the preceding aggregates, since it includes the
currency holdings of the public plus all deposits at all financial
institutions; and also the credit proxy, which indicates the funds
that Federal Reserve member banks have available for lending.
Besides following these and still other aggregates, we
pay careful attention to the condition of financial markets - that is, to movements in interest rates, lending terms, the
liquidity needs of businesses and financial institutions, and
other variables, including the foreign exchange value of the
dollar.

All of these must be given some weight in the conduct

of monetary policy.
On May 1 of this year, I informed the Senate Banking
Committee that the Federal Reserve was seeking a moderate
rate of expansion in the monetary and credit aggregates, and
that the course we are pursuing will promote an increase of Mj
between 5 and 7-1/2 per cent over the twelve months ending in
March 1976,

It was expected that the related growth rates of

other major aggregates would be somewhat higher - - with M£
increasing in a range of 8-1/2 to 10-1/2 per cent; M3, in a
10-12 per cent range, and the credit proxy in a range of 6-1/2
to 9-1/2 per cent.

-16-

Economic prospects now are not materially different
than the Federal Reserve anticipated two or three months ago,
and we therefore as yet see no reason to alter the general
course of monetary policy.

Accordingly, the Federal Open

Market Committee has reaffirmed its intent to seek the growth
ranges announced earlier.

In view of the erratic movements to

which monthly figures on money balances are subject, the projected growth ranges for the several aggregates now cover the
12-month span from the second quarter of 1975 to the second
quarter of 1976* In the future, we will generally express our
projected growth range of each monetary aggregate from a
quarterly base, since a three-month average is less subject
to erratic movements than is a single-month base.
We have recently experienced some extreme short-run
fluctuations in the growth rate of money balances.

Such move-

ments may give rise to confusion regarding the course of
monetary policy.

It may be helpful, therefore, to comment

on the huge bulge in the rate of growth of the monetary aggregates
during May and June.
This bulge was a direct result of the tax bill passed
earlier this year by the Congress.

The tax rebate checks and s

supplemental social security payments disbursed by the Treasury

-17-

were temporarily added to the public's holdings of currency,
demand deposits, and savings accounts.

Thus, Mj grew at an

average annual rate of over 14-1/2 per cent during the months
of May and June, and M2 increased at a rate of about 16 per
cent.

But by late June and early July, as individuals disposed

of their additional funds, the explosion of the monetary aggregates
subsided.
The May-June bulge in the monetary aggregates did not
come as a surprise, but it was larger than we had expected - and very much larger than we desired.

It must be clearly under-

stood that the Federal Reserve has no intention of permitting rates
of increase as high as those in the second quarter to continue.
The special Treasury disbursements have come to an end; and
the Federal Reserve has already set in motion forces that should,
in the near future, return the growth of the monetary aggregates
to the moderate path desired.

True, these recent actions have

left their mark on short-term market rates of interest.

But we

have succeeded in avoiding during the past two to three months
the severe and damaging effects on credit markets that would have
occurred if we had pursued a rigid money supply objective, such
as some economists keep urging on us.

-18-

As recent experience indicates, short-run variations
in the stock of money may not at all reflect the intent or the
underlying course of Federal Reserve policy.

My colleagues and I

have frequently noted that short-run movements of the monetary
stock have little significance, and it is good to have the opportunity
to state once again that far more attention is given to these shortrun fluctuations than is warranted.

Actually, our studies indicate

that large deviations in the growth of money from a long-run path
may occur for half a year or even longer and still have a negligible
effect on the workings of the real economy.

We must learn to

recognize that monthly fluctuations such as those in the rate of
growth of the money stock, however defined, are characteristic
of almost any series in which monthly changes are small relative
to the level of the series.
In view of considerations such as these, the Federal
Reserve focuses its attention principally on an appropriate
growth of money balances over periods running from six months
to a year.

Unfortunately, our ability to control this longer-run

rate of monetary expansion is less precise than it should or could
be.

Deficiencies in existing statistical data are part of the problem.

Steps have been taken by the Federal Reserve to speed the collection

-19-

of data and to improve its quality.

We have also been exploring,

with the cooperation of the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation,
methods to obtain better estimates of money balances held at
nonmember banks.

The information now available regarding

demand deposits at nonmember banks is entirely inadequate,
and at times has misled the Federal Reserve and the public
as to the actual course of monetary expansion.
Our control over the nation's money stock would be
imprecise, however, even with the best of statistical information.
The Federal Reserve's influence over the money stock is indirect.

The principal means we use to regulate the growth of

money and credit is to buy or sell government securities in the
open market.

These transactions are taken at our initiative,

and in such dollar amounts as we deem appropriate.

The size

of the Federal Reserve's portfolio of securities is thus under
our control.

The response of the money stock to an open market

purchase or sale, however, is determined by decisions of commercial banks and of the public at large - - decisions over which
we have no control.
For example, a purchase of securities by the Federal
Reserve would lead to little or no increase in the reserves of

-20-

member banks if there were an equivalent rise in the public's
holdings of currency, or if member banks used the additional
funds to repay indebtedness to their Federal Reserve Banks.
Alternatively, member banks might choose to add to their
excess reserves instead of employing the newly acquired funds
for lending or investing.

In that event, there would be no

multiplier effect of reserve expansion on deposit creation.
The choices made by the public as to the form in which
newly-created deposits are held, and the type of commercial
bank in which the funds are deposited, also influence the response
of the money stock, particularly Mj or M£* to a reserve injection.
The response of the narrowly-defined money supply would be
larger if the public increased its holding of demand deposits at
smaller member banks, since reserve requirements at these
banks are lower than those at the larger member banks* And,
of course, the freedom of the public, to choose between demand
and time deposits can alter materially the amount of aggregate
deposits that can be supported by a given volume of reserves.
Part of the imprecision in monetary control also arises
from the fact that a sizable fraction of money balances is held
at banks that are not subject to the reserve requirements set
by the Federal Reserve.

Once the Congress sees fit to adopt

-21-

the legislation on uniform reserve requirements that we have
been seducing for several years, the Federal Reserve's control
over the monetary aggregates will be improved, and financial
institutions offering similar deposit services will at the same
time be treated more equitably.
In closing, let me remind this distinguished Committee
that the growth ranges for the monetary aggregates that we have
projected for the next year may need to be adjusted one way or
another.

Clearly, the growth rates presently sought by the

Federal Reserve, while appropriate in the present environment
of high unemployment and unused industrial capacity, could not
be maintained indefinitely without rekindling inflationary forces.
As the economy returns to higher rates of resource utilization,
it will be necessary to reduce the rate of monetary and credit
expansion, so that the basis for a lasting prosperity is laid.
We must not lose sight of the fact that the principal
cause of the current recession is an inflation that got out of
control.

Our nation has paid a heavy price during the past

year for neglect of this serious problem.

All of us in government

must work to promote a good recovery in economic activity;
but all of us must also take great care lest the hard-won gains

-22-

of the past year are nullified by a new round of inflation., The
rise of the consumer price level in June at an annual rate of over
9 per cent is a warning that the menace of inflation i^/still very
much with us.

The task now facing our country,/'therefore, is

not only to hasten the process of economic recovery, but also
to unwind the inflation and thus lay the basis for a lasting
prosperity.

>\< %. %< >Jc ^< $: