View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
Friday, August 25, 1972
1:00 p.m., P.D.T. (4:00 p.m., E.D.T.)




MEMBER BANK BORROWING, PORTFOLIO STRATEGY,
AND THE
MANAGEMENT OF FEDERAL RESERVE DISCOUNT POLICY

A Paper
By
Andrew F. Brimmer
Member
Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System

Presented at the

47th Annual Conference
of the
Western Economic Association

University of Santa Clara
Santa Clara, California

August 25, 1972

TABLE OF CONTENTS
Section

Page

Preface

i

I.

Introduction

1

II.

Federal Reserve Bank Adjusment to Discount Rate Changes

7

III.

Member Banking Borrowing at Federal Reserve Banks

21

Chart I -- Pattern of Member Bank Borrowing by District

27a

Market Interest Rates and Member Bank Borrowing

32

Chart II -- Money Market Rates and Borrowing from the Federal
Reserve

33a

V.

Bank Structure and Member Bank Borrowing

35

VI.

Portfolio Structure and Member Banking Borrowing

42

VII.

Member Bank Borrowing and Alternative Sources of Funds

44

VIII.

Concluding Observations

45

IV.

Tables 1 - 1 4
Appendix Table 1




PREFACE

The preparation of this paper required far more than the usual
amount and quality of staff support, and the contributions of particular
staff members should be identified fully.
Mr. James Pierce had overall staff responsibility for the
measurement of member bank borrowing from the Federal Reserve.
The actual task of relating borrowing to bank portfolio
strategy required a great deal of imagination and computer programming
skill, and several persons made an especially helpful contribution in
accomplishing this goal. Ms. Jacqueline McDaniel did the basic planning
and coordinated the programming effort to integrate three different
sources of data. The first requirement was to examine on a daily basis
each of roughly 5,800 member banks to determine their borrowing status
and reserve position during the 3-1/2 years from January 1, 1969 through
May 31, 1972. Mr. Stephen A. Nelick undertook this assignment—using
primarily the "Short-Run Banking System Reports11 (SBR) series.
The next task was to analyze the portfolio structure of borrowing
banks compared with nonborrowers. Mr, Thomas A. Orndorff did the
programming to retrieve data used for this purpose--using Call Reports
for each member bank as of December 31, 1969, 1970, and 1971. He and Steve
Nelick created the input data for the regression analysis described below.
A third task was to analyze bank borrowing from the Federal
Reserve compared with alternative sources of funds. Data used for this
purpose came from the reports submitted weekly by 330 large banks (of
which 315 are Federal Reserve member banks). However, the weekly data
had to be matched with statistics from the SBR series and from the Call
Report. This assignment was carried out by Mr. Charles L. Monts.
In each of these assignments, the objective was to generate
data for member banks distributed by size and Federal Reserve District.
A few member banks were excluded from the data because their heavy
borrowing from the Federal Reserve was related to supervisory
problems.
Member bank borrowing was also studied using econometric
techniques. Through the use of regression analysis, borrowing was
related to interest rate differentials» size of bank, and other factors.
Mr. John Austin carried out this task.
The study of the timing of discount rate changes at Federal
Reserve Banks also required considerable detailed examination of the
Board's records extending over the last 20 years. Mr. James Hilbanks
undertook this assignment. He also did the calculations to measure the
propensity of Federal Reserve Banks to lead or lag with respect to changes
in the discount rate.




- 4 Several other members of the Board's staff assisted the
project in various ways, Mrs, Virginia Timenes supplied the statistics
showing long-run trends in member banks1 use of Federal Reserve Banks
compared with other credit sources, and Hiss Donata Price sketched
the chart based on these data. Mrs. Dorothy Folsom prepared the
chart showing money market interest rates and member bank borrowing.
Also Miss Harriett Harper, Mrs. Tonsa Fuqua, and Mrs. Linda Zuk
worked on various statistical and other assignments which had to be done
in the preparation of the paper.
I have benefited immeasurably from numerous discussions of
discount rate policy with my colleagues--especially Governors J.L. Robertson
and George W. Mitchell. Much of this discussion focused on the making
of policy during the 1950's and early 1960fs. Governor Mitchell chaired
the Federal Reserve System study which in 1968 recommended a basic
revamping of the discount mechanism. Mr. Robert C* Holland (now Executive
Director at the Board) had overall staff responsibility for that study,
and he has been especially helpful in connection with the present
project.
I have also traced the evolution of discount policy during
this period in the Board's records and in the Minutes of the Federal
Open Market Committee (FOMC). As is generally known, while the meetings
of the latter are devoted primarily to the conduct of open market
operations in U.S. Government securities, the FGMC also serves as a
forum for the discussion and coordination of all of the instruments of
monetary policy--including discount policy.
I have also found it helpful to discuss discount policy with
Messrs. Howard H. Hackley and P.D. Ring. Mr. Hackley (formerly General
Counsel and now Assistant to the Board) probably knows more about the
evolution of Federal Reserve discount policy than anyone else currently
in the System (as exemplified by his authorship of the comprehensive
study, "A History of the Lending Functions of the Federal Reserve Banks,11
(mimeo.),(1961). Mr. Ring is the Board's staff officer who maintains
the closest continuing contact with the discount policy through his
day-to-day surveillance of the discount function in Reserve Banks.
Finally, while I am grateful for the staff's support in this
project, the conclusions reached in this paper are my own. Nor should
the views expressed be attributed to my colleagues on the Board.




Andrew F. Brimmer

MEMBER BANK BORROWING, PORTFOLIO STRATEGY,
AND THE
MANAGEMENT OF FEDERAL RESERVE DISCOUNT POLICY
By
Andrew F. Brimmer

I.

*

Introduction
For a number of years, discount rate policy as administered by

the Federal Reserve has rested heavily on a few key assumptions about
the behavior of commercial banks that are members of the System.

In

fact, the Federal Reserve Act itself visualized the establishment of
discount facilities by Federal Reserve Banks as the principal means
through which the latter were to provide for an "elastic" currency
for the United States.

In the more than half-century of the System's

life, the nature and functioning of the discount mechanism has probably
been criticized, studied, assessed, and reformed more than any other
1/
aspect of our central banking arrangement.Consequently, one might want to raise a question at the
outset:

why should one take up the matter again?

The answer is simple:

the Federal Reserve discount rate and the administrative arrangements
surrounding it are matters of importance--because of the nature of
the banking system in the United States.

From the point of view of most

member banks, access to the discount window represents a valuable means
* Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
1/

The latest of these is the comprehensive Reappraisal of the
Federal Reserve Discount Mechanism, published by the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Vols. 1 and 2
(1971) and Vol.3 (1972).




- 2 of making temporary adjustments in their asset and liability position—and
thus strengthens their ability to serve their customers.

From the

perspective of the Federal Reserve System, borrowing by member banks
provides an additional

channel

management of monetary policy.

that can be used to enhance the
Moreover, the discount rate is an

important star in the constellation of short-term interest rates—and
thus casts a great deal of light on current credit conditions.
Yet, despite the importance of the Federal Reserve discount
mechanism—and despite the considerable amount of effort that has been
devoted to its illumination—numerous aspects of its functioning remain
obscure to some.

For example, the principles which are supposed to

govern borrowing by member banks are clearly stated in both the Federal
2/
Reserve Act and in the Federal Reserve Board's regulations.—

However,

the ways in which these principles actually work out in practice—under
varying monetary and credit conditions and among different classes of
member banks in different regions of the country--are only partially
understood by economists and other observers outside the System.
The foundation of the Federal Reserve discount mechanism has been
the presumption that member banks are reluctant to borrow.

On this

base, the strategy of discount policy determination and the rules for
its administration have been erected. The broad outlines for both were embodied
in the last major revision of the Federal Reserve Board's regulation covering
3/
member bank borrowing adopted in 1955
2?
3/

Section 13 of the Act and Regulation A.
For a discussion of the 1955 revision see Bernard Shull, "Rationale
and Objectives of the 1955 Revision of Regulation A," Reappraisal,
Vol. 1, pp. 119-131.




- 3 —While recognizing that access to Federal Reserve
credit facilities is a privilege of membership,
Reserve Banks must give due regard to the effect
of any extension of credit upon the maintenance
of sound credit conditions.
--Normally, Reserve Bank credit should be extended
to member banks for short periods of time to
meet temporary credit needs (including seasonal
requirements).
— T o meet unusual and exigent situations, Federal
Reserve credit may be extended for as long as
seems necessary.
--Continuous use of Federal Reserve credit under
ordinary conditions would not be appropriate.
--Federal Reserve Banks, in deciding whether to grant
or refuse credit, must consider the general character
and amount of the loans and investments of the
particular member bank and whether the latter is
extending an undue amount of credit for speculative
purposes.
—Where it appears that a member bank's principal
purpose is to profit from interest rate differentials
or to obtain a tax advantage, Federal Reserve Bank
credit should not be extended.

Given this conception of member bank borrowing, the Federal
Reserve Banks1 discount rate traditionally has been viewed as an
instrument to regulate—but not penalize—borrowing by member banks.
Thus, it generally has not been considered desirable to maintain the
discount rate significantly above market rates to discourage borrowing—
as has been the case in a number of foreign countries.

Instead, a

view seems to have emerged which holds that any problems of excess
use of Federal Reserve credit can be handled by administrative




decisions.

Moreover, in administering the discount function, efforts

have been made to achieve reasonable uniformity among differentFederal
Reserve Districts.
Uniformity in the level of discount rates among Districts
is not required.

Nevertheless, most officials within the System

apparently have felt that monetary and credit conditions in various parts
of the Nation ordinarily are so similar that differential discount rates
among Federal Reserve

Banks would not be justified*

On the other hand,

under the Federal Reserve Act and by earlier prevailing traditions, the
Boards of Directors of each Reserve Bank were expected to give dominant
weight to economic conditions in their respective Districts when they
establish the discount rate roughly every 14 days.
this view has changed considerably.

Over time, however,

Currently, many Directors place

significantly more stress on national and international developments.
While many of the detailed features have been set aside, these
are the broad principles within which the Federal Reserve discount
mechanism is expected to function.
in recent years?

How—in fact—have they been working

For a number of months, I have been engaged in a study

of several aspects of Federal Reserve discount policy, and some of the
results of that inquiry are presented in this paper.

Some of the •

highlights of those findings can be summarized here:




—Once a discount rate change has been approved, most
other Federal Reserve Banks seem to act more quickly
to bring their own rates into line whfen the rate
is increased than when it is reduced. But among
individual Banks, some are more likely to lead in
making rate reductions than they are in making rate
increases.

- 5 — I n recent years, for a variety of reasons, the
Federal Reserve Board seems to have exercised an
increased degree of leadership in the determination
of the discount rate. A number of Reserve Bank
Directors have become much more willing to vote
rate changes. But in some of these cases, the
timing or size of the planned change has been
unacceptable to the Board, and several proposals
have been disapproved in the last few years.
—The traditional reluctance of most member banks to
borrow from the Federal Reserve Banks seems to
remain in force. Even during the most recent period
of severe monetary restraint, barely more than onequarter of all member banks borrowed from the Federal
Reserve. In fact, the reluctance to borrow may have
become somewhat stronger. Over the last decade, an
increasing proportion of member banks which had to
borrow turned to sources other than the Federal
Reserve Banks.
— I n general, among the banks which do borrow from the
Federal Reserve, only a small part of their required
reserves is obtained from the central bank—for example,
just over 5 per cent at the height of credit restraint
in 1969.
— T h e volume of borrowing seems to be closely related to
the differential between the discount rate and interest
rates in the money market. In other words, banks seem
to borrow from the Federal Reserve when the benefits
of doing so are clearly evident.
— T h e propensity to borrow from Reserve Banks is particularly
strong among the largest institutions, of whom 90 per cent
use such credit compared with only 10 per cent of the
smallest member banks§
--However, the extent to which the borrowing banks rely
on the Reserve Banks for assistance varies both by
size of institution and prevailing credit conditions.
Under normal circumstances, the small "borrowing" banks
borrow more frequently and for longer periods of time than
do the large "boir towing" banks in the System. The smaller banks
also normally obtain through Reserve Bank borrowing a
larger proportion of their required reserves (about
4-1/2 per cent vs. 2 per cent).




- 6 — B u t during periods of severe monetary restraint,
the normal pattern appears to be reversed: Putting
aside the biggest institutions (about 50 in number),
the other large banks tend to borrow more frequently-and to obtain a greater proportion of their required
reserves (about 8 per cent vs. 6 per cent)--from
Reserve Banks than is true of the smaller units.
The very largest banks also become more dependent
on Federal Reserve credit during periods of
monetary restraint. Yet, the degree of such
reliance is restricted significantly by close
Reserve Bank surveillance of their borrowing
activity (which represented about 4-1/2 per cent
of the largest banks1 required reserves in 1969).
--Large member banks which borrow from Reserve Banks
tend to rely somewhat less than large nonborrowers
on some of the alternative means available to adjust
their reserve positions. For example, those large
borrowers using Reserve Bank credit raise a smaller
proportion of their funds through sales of largedenomination certificates of deposit--especially
those sold to individuals and other private investors.
Perhaps surprisingly, with the exception of the very
largest banks, large borrowers as a group rely on
purchases of federal funds somewhat more than large
nonborrowers.
—Finally, banks which borrow from the Federal Reserve
carry a much larger proportion of higher-yielding
assets (e.g., loans rather than U.S. Government
securities) in their portfolios than do banks which
do not rely on Federal Reserve credit. Thus, while
borrowing banks are able to supply a relatively greater
volume of funds to the economy, they also seem better
able to concentrate on lending activities yielding
the highest rates of return.




- 7 These conclusions are amplified in the remainder of this
paper.

In Section II, the pattern of Federal Reserve Bank adjustment

to discount rate changes is sketched.

In Section III, the trend and

magnitude of member bank borrowing are traced.

The relationship between

market interest rates and member bank borrowing is discussed in Section IV.
In Section V, the banking structure and member bank borrowing are
examined.

In Sections VI and VII, the banks1 portfolio strategy and

alternative sources of funds are analyzed.

Some concluding observations

are presented in Section VIII.

II.

Federal Reserve Bank Adjustment to Discount Rate Changes
It will be recalled that, under the Federal Reserve Act,

the Boards of Directors of each Federal Reserve Bank are required
"... to establish from time to time, subject to review and determination
of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, rates of discount
to be charged... for each class of paper, which shall be fixed with a
view of accommodating commerce and business....11

Such rates must be

established every 14 days—or more frequently if thought necessary by
the Federal Reserve Board.

In implementing this part of the Act, the

normal situation involves the re-establishment of the existing discount
rates which the Board dimply allows to stand.

For example, the present
4/
rate of 4-1/2 per cent has been in effect since December 13, 1971.—
47
~

This is the rate of interest charged on loans to member banks
under Sees. 13 and 13a—most widely referred to as "the" discount
rate.




- 8 At times, however, prospective changes in economic and
financial conditions will force the question of the discount rate
to the forefront of monetary policy discussions.

In fact, on a number

of occasions, the question of changing the discount rate has become
a burning issue—not only in the Federal Reserve System but also
among other Government officials, within the financial community, and
among the public at l a r g e . B u t under normal circumstances, the
Directors of Reserve Banks (occasionally through an executive committee)
will propose

a change in the rate when they become convinced that

changing economic conditions (mainly in their respective Districts)
require it.

In reaching that decision, they are undoubtedly influenced

substantially by the recommendations of the Reserve Bank Presidents.
Discount rate setting is a product of Board-Reserve Bank
interaction, and both the form and the substance of that interaction
have changed over time.

In a few cases, the Board has formally requested

the Reserve Bank Directors to assess the currently prevailing rate with
a view toward changing it if the judgment were reached that such a

5/

The most dramatic instance in recent years arose in December, 1965,
when the Federal Reserve Board (on a 4-3 vote) raised the rate by
1/2 per cent to 4-1/2 per cent over the opposition of the Administration.
A less dramatic—but still important—example of a similar reaction
occurred in April, 1956, following an increase in the discount rate
by 1/4 per cent to 2-3/4 per cent by 3 Banks and by 1/2 per cent to 3
per cent by 1 Bank. Apparently some of the key members of the
Administration (but not the President himself) also opposed those
actions—especially the 1/2 per cent increase. See FOMC Minutes,
1956, pp. 224-227.




- 9 move was desirable.-

But the most frequently used approach is the

encouragement of an informal discussion of possible discount rate
changes at regular meetings of the FOMC.

Within the last year or so,

Reserve Bank Presidents have been asked informally by the Federal
Reserve Board to encourage a full discussion at regular meetings of
their Directors Of those factors which might influence the decision
to change the discount rate.

To a considerable extent, the Board's

action was a by-product of the decision to experiment with making
small and fairly frequent changes in the discount rate.

Such a policy

was recommended by the System Committee which conducted the Fundamental
Reappraisal of the Discount mechanism in the mid-1960's.

The System

tried that technique rather extensively from late 1970 through late 1971.
6/

Perhaps the most explicit example of the exercise of such Board
leadership is provided by the telegram which Chairman William McC. Martin
sent to Presidents of Federal Reserve Banks on "... November 9, 1955
suggesting that, without implying that action should be taken on
the matter, there be a full review of the discount rate by the
directors of the Reserve Bank at their next meeting....11 (FOMC
Minutes, 1955, p. 604). The reactions to the wire were discussed
at the FOMC meeting of November 16. It is both interesting and
instructive to contrast the views of Board Members and Bank
Presidents regarding a discount rate change which were expressed
at the November 16 meeting with those expressed at .the previous
meeting on October 25. At the earlier meeting 9 of the 12 Presidents
did not favor an increase in the discount rate. (The remaining 3
did not comment on the question.) Of the 6 Board Members who spoke
on the issue, 2 favored an increase and 4 did not. At the November 16
meeting, 11 of the Presidents were present, and 9 now said that they
were prepared to recommend a rate increase in the near future; only
& were still opposed. All 6 of the Board Members present now favored
an increase. The next day—November 17, 1955—the Board approved
an increase of 1/4 per cent to 2-1/2 per cent in the discount rate
for Reserve Banks. Within 5 days, the remaining 6 Banks had moved
to the higher rate. On the day prior to the Board's action, no
Reserve Bank had actually recommended a change in the discount rate.
FOMC Minutes, 1955, pp. 597-623, and Board Records, 1955.




- 10 Record of Discount Rate Adjustment:

1953-71

Given these developments affecting the environment in
which discount rate policy is administered, what does the record show
with respect to Federal Reserve Bank adjustment to discount rate
changes?

To answer this question, all changes in the rate from

January, 1953, through December, 1971, were examined in some detail.
During that period, the discount rate was changed 39 times.
were increases, and 17 were rate reductions.

Twenty-two

In examining the changes,

answers were sought to several subsidiary questions:
— H o w long did it take the Federal Reserve System
to effect a rate change--from the point at which
the first Reserve Bank Directors voted a change
through approval by the Board until the last
Bank comes into line with the new rate?
— I s the adjustment time required the same for both
rate increases and rate reductions?
— D o adjustment patterns differ appreciably among
Reserve Banks—depending on whether the change is
an increase or a decrease?
— C a n one detect a differential propensity among
Reserve Banks to lead or lag in making rate changes?

The data used in answering these questions are summarized
in a number of statistical tables (attached at the end of the text).
Selected information on each of the 39 rate changes is presented in
Appendix I.

The adjustment time for the Federal Reserve System as a

whole is shown in Table 1.

Data relating to individual Reserve Banks

are shown in Tables 2, 3 and 4.




In assessing the adjustment pattern

- 11 of Reserve Banks, the rate changes were classified according to whether
they were increases or decreases, and the time required for each Reserve
Bank to complete the change was calculated.

For the System as a

whole, "adjustment time11 represents the weighted averages of days
involved in the process, using as weights the number^of Federal
Reserve Banks posting a change on a given day.

"Lead time11 is the

number of days elapsed between action by the first Reserve Bank Board
proposing a rate change and approval by the Federal Reserve Board.
"Coincident action" describes those cases in which the Reserve Bank
Directors and the Federal Reserve Board took action on the same day.
"Time lag" is the number of days elapsed between approval action by
the Federal Reserve Board and the adjustment of the rate by the last
Reserve Bank.

"Duration" is the time elapsed between the beginning and

the end of the rate adjustment process.
From an examination of the statistics, several conclusions
emerge:
Adjustment Time for the Federal Reserve System
With respect to the System as a whole, it took an average of
5.3 days to effect a discount rate change during the 1953-71 period. (Table 1)
Once rate changes were voted by Reserve Banks, the Federal Reserve Board
typically approved the proposals rather quickly—since lead time averaged
only 1.1 days.

However, the remaining Banks took somewhat longer to

bring their rates into line—since the time lag for all Banks averaged
4.1 days.

Within the period, there was considerable variation in the




- 12 duration of the rate adjustment process.

In general, the adjustment

period was much longer in the 1950's than it was in later years—for
example, 6.1 days in 1953-60;
and 4.0 days in 1970-71.

1.9 days in 1963-65;

4.7 days in 1967-69,

In general, over the period as a whole,

the lead time increased while the time lag became shorter.
Reductions in the discount rate required somewhat mo.re time
than did increases—5.7 days vs. 4.9 days for the 1953-71 period.
The lead time was about the same for both increases and decreases
(1.2 days and 1.0 days, respectively).

However, the time lag was

longer for the rate decreases than it was for rate increases (4.7 days
vs. 3.7 days).
Adjustment Time for Federal Reserve Banks
Individual Federal Reserve Banks displayed considerable
diversity in adjusting to discount rate changes.
disparity shows up in a variety of ways.

The extent of this

In Table 2, the average

adjustment time for each Bank is shown for the period 1953-71.

From

these data, it is evident that some banks took a great deal more time to
adjust to discount rate changes than did
required 5.3 days).

the System as a whole (which

For example, the Dallas Bank had the longest average

duration (9.2 days) for any phase of the adjustment process, and New York
had the shortest (2.1 days).
When the adjustment process is divided more sharply to distinguish
among lead, coincident and lag positions and between increases and
decreases, the variation in behavior among Reserve Banks becomes even
more evident.




For this purpose, the information in Table 3 is especially

- 13 helpful.

This table shows the number of times a particular Reserve

Bank was among the lead banks, coincident banks, or lag

banks, when

the discount rate was increased compared with its position when the
rate was reduced.

It will be noted that, of the 22 instances of an

increase in the rate, the typical Reserve Bank was among the
leaders 3.8 times;
it was in the lag

it was in the coincident group about 6.8 times, and
category about 11.4 times.

These figures represented

17.3 per cent, 30.1 per cent, and 51.8 per cent, respectively, of the
22 cases of rate increases.

Of the 17 instances of discount rate

decreases, the average Reserve Bank was among the leaders 2.8 times;
it was in the coincident group about 4.7 times, and it was in the lag
category about 9.5 times.

Again, these instances represented 16.5 per

cent, 27.7 per cent, and 55.9 per cent, respectively, of the 17 cases
of rate reductions.

So, relative lead-lag position of the typical

Reserve Bank in the System was pretty much the same whether the discount
rate was increased or decreased.
However, among individual Reserve Banks, this pattern varied
considerably.

For example, the New York Bank was never among the leaders

in the 17 cases when discount rates were reduced, and the Richmond and
Atlanta Banks were among the leaders only one time each when rates were
lowered.

In contrast, when discount rates were increased, all three

of these Banks were among the leaders approximately the average number
of times (roughly 4 times).

On the other hand, the Boston Bank (which

was also among the leaders about the average number of times) was




- 14 far in the lead when discount rates were reduced (7 out of 17 times—or
41 per cent).

At the other end of the spectrum, three Banks (Atlanta,

Kansas City, and Dallas) lagged considerably behind the System as a
whole when discount rates were lowered.

They were in the delayed

adjustment category 12 of the 17 times—or in 71 per cent of the cases.
Still other contrasts could be drawn, but enough has been
said to provide the general flavor of the diversity of discount rate
adjustment patterns among Federal Reserve Banks.

To reduce the

scattering of experience and to see whether a generalized pattern can
be discerned in the data, each Bank was ranked according to its
average lead-lag position with respect to the total number (39) of
discount rate changes during the years 1953-71.
shown in Table 4.

The results are

Here, the St. Louis Bank (with a lead of 3.1 days)

turns out to hold the top rank as the Reserve Bank most likely to lead
in the upward adjustment of discount rates.
closely behind (with a lead of 3.0 days).

The Dallas Bank follows
The Minneapolis Bank is

at the bottom of the list (with a lead of only 0.2 days).

Again, the

top position as the institution most likely to lag when discount rates
are increased is held by the Boston Bank (with a lag of 5.2 days).
The Richmond Bank is second (at 5.1 days), and the remaining 10 Banks
follow in descending order with only modest differences between them
with the 12th Bank (Minneapolis) at 2.7 days.




- 15 With respect to discount rate decreases, the Boston Bank
is the institution most likely to lead a downward adjustment in the
rate level.
close second.

Its average lead was 5.2 days.

No other Bank was even a

The latter spot was held by the Philadelphia Bank where

the average lead was 1.5 days.

As already indicated, the New York Bank

was at the bottom of this ranking—since it was never among the leaders
when discount rates were decreased.
Finally, the Dallas Reserve Bank continues to emerge as
the Bank most likely to lag behind when discount rates are reduced.
Its time-lag averaged 8.8 days. It was followed by Richmond (5.6 days)
and Atlanta (5.1 days).

Again, the New York Bank (with 2.1 days)

was in the bottom spot.
Assessment of Federal Reserve Bank Adjustment Pattern
Several comments can be made which might illuminate further
the observed pattern of adjustment to discount rate changes.

In

general, when discount rates are increased, most Reserve Banks apparently
move as expeditiously as possible to bring their own rate into line.
In large part, this action is designed to minimize the chance of
member banks shifting a disproportionate amount of their borrowing to
the Federal Reserve discount window where the cost of funds might otherwise
be noticeably below market interest rates.

In the case of the New

York Federal Reserve Bank, that institution has traditionally assigned
considerable weight to economic and financial developments in the
international arena.




Reflecting this concern, it has frequently stressed

- 16 the advantage of having

short-term interest rates in the United

States in reasonable relationship to those in Western Europe—which are
typically higher than similar rates in this country.

This perception

of the role of interest rates seems to have often caused the New York
Bank to be more reluctant than the average Bank to take the lead
in reducing the discount rate.
The Dallas Federal Reserve Bank appears to feel that it is
operating in an environment that is usually much more ebullient than
that prevailing in most other parts of the country.

In that Bank's

view, a somewhat stronger posture to discourage member bank borrowing
might generally be desirable.

In the case of the Boston Bank, somewhat

more than the average amount of emphasis seems to have been placed
on the role of interest rates in stimulating economic growth.

This

concern has been as much national in scope as it has had regional
dimensions.
Finally, several of the Reserve Banks have tended to cluster
around the average behavior of the System as a whole.

The Philadelphia,

Chicago, and San Francisco Banks seem to fall into this category.

No

obvious reasons can be advanced to explain the observed tendency, but
its persistence over time is clearly evident.
Disapproval of Discount Rate Proposals
As indicated above, the Federal Reserve Board has turned down
a number of discount rate proposals voted by Directors of Reserve Banks.




Through 1965, no such formal disapprovals had been recorded.—

However,

from July, 1966, through August, 1971, the Board disapproved 24 discount
rate changes put forward by Reserve Bank Directors*

The proposed

changes--all of which were increases—are summarized in Table 5.
Of the 24 rejections, 11 occurred in 1966;
and 5 occurred in 1971.

8 occurred in 1969,

In each of the first two years, the disapprovals

occurred at the peak of monetary restraint.

In 1971, the disapprovals

also occurred in those months when money market interest rates were
at or near their peaks for the year.

In 1966, nine of the proposals

were for 1/2 per cent to raise the rate from 4-1/2 to 5 per cent.
Two (Chicago and Minneapolis) were for 1 per cent to raise the rate
to 5-1/2 per cent.

In 1969, two proposals were for 1/2 per cent—one

(St. Louis) would have raised the rate from 5-1/2 to 6 per cent, and
the other (Boston) would have raised the rate from 6 to 6-1/2 per cent.
All other proposals disapproved in 1969 were for 1 per cent to raise
the rate from 6 to 7 per cent.

In 1971, two proposals (Philadelphia

and St. Louis) were for 1/4 per cent to raise the rate to 5 per cent.
Three proposals were for 1/2 per cent—one (New York) to raise the rate
from 4-3/4 to 5-1/4, and two (Dallas and St. Louis) to raise the rate
from 5 to 5-1/2 per cent.
It will also be noted that three of the Reserve Banks (Richmond,
Atlanta, and San Francisco) were not among those whose rate proposals
were disapproved.

On the other hand, two of the Banks (St. Louis

7_/ Actually, the Board disapproved some of the rate proposals when discount
rates were fixed for the first time in the closing months of 1914.
The structure of rates submitted by the different Banks was quite
diverse. To bring about some degree of order (but not uniformity) the
Board disapproved some of the initial proposals and left it to the
affected Banks to submit new rates that were more acceptable. See Henry
Parker
Willis, The Federal Reserve System, New York: The Ronald Press

http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
Company, 1923, Ch. XLI, pp. 886-904.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

- 18 and Chicago) each accounted for about one-quarter of the turndowns.
Two of the Banks (Cleveland and Minneapolis) had rates rejected in 1966—
but none in the other two years.
While the Board disapproved 24 separate rate proposals,
a number of the cases represented reaffirmations

of a decision which

had been reached previously on the basis of facts similar to those
stressed by the Directors of a particular Reserve Bank.

By this

standard, the 24 increases that were disapproved can be regrouped into
six basic decisions.

The reasons for their actions advanced by the

Directors and the Board, respectively, can be summarized:

1.

July 15, 1966

Reserve Bank: Market rates had been moving upward, and
widespread expectations of a discount rate increase had contributed to
market uncertainties. The Banks, therefore, reasoned that an adjustment
in the rate would serve as a stabilizing influence. They also believed
that a rate increase could be helpful in symbolizing continued concern
about the balance of payments deficit. Use of the discount rate
instrument, along with other instruments of Federal Reserve policy, was
called for to maximize the effectiveness of monetary policy to limit
excessive credit expansion.
Federal Reserve Board: On the preceding day, the Bank of
England had raised the Bank rate from 6 to 7 per cent, and the Board
was reluctant to weaken that action with an offsetting action here.
On the domestic side, doubt was expressed as to whether an increase
of 1/2 per cent would be sufficient to quiet prevailing uncertainties,
or whether such an increase might simply promote speculation concerning
the possibility of additional rate increases. There was also concerti
that in view of the many strains and cross-currents prevailing in the
financial and credit markets, a rate increase might be exaggerated and
misconstrued, with resulting ramifications extending beyond the intended
scope of the action. Further, it was not evident that the existing rate
was hampering the pursuit of a policy of monetary restraint or that it
was causing unmanageable problems at the discount windows. Another
factor contributing to the Board's decision was the widespread desire
to avoid further escalation of interest rates.




- 19 2.

January 27, 1969

Reserve Bank: The St. Louis Bank believed that a rate increase
would place the rate closer to its historical relationship with other
money market rates and would reduce the incentive for member banks to
come to the discount window. Further, the Bank felt that the recent
slowing that had occurred in the rate of growth of commercial bank
credit reflected a rechanneling of funds around the banks, with little
net effect on total credit extended in the economy, more than it
provided evidence of monetary restraint. It was their view that a
rate increase would indicate to the public that the System was seriously
interested in combating prevailing strong inflationary expectations.
Federal Reserve Board: The Board concluded that a rate
increase at this time would not be appropriate in light of the imminent
Treasury refinancing. Also, apart from the refinancing, the Board had
reservations as to whether a rate increase, particularly one of as
much as 1/2 per cent, was called for by prevailing and prospective
economic and financial conditions.
3.

May 28, 1969

Reserve Bank: The St. Louis Bank proposed the rate increase
on the grounds that it would bring the rate into better alignment
with relevant market rates, and would reduce the incentive for member
banks to make excessive use of the discount window. The Bank also
believed that a rate increase might help to convince the public that
the System was serious about resisting inflationary pressures and
might therefore help to reduce inflationary expectations and hasten
a turnaround in interest rates.
Federal Reserve Board: The Board felt that a rate increase
at the present time would be untimely in light of the prevailing conditions
and uncertainties in financial markets. It was also noted that while
the present rate was out of line with market rates, there had been no
evidence that there had been unmanageable difficulties at the discount
windows.
4.

May 7, 1971

Reserve Bank: The New York Bank proposed the rate
increase out of concern over the current unsettlement in foreign
exchange markets and the attendant massive flows of dollars into
foreign currencies. They felt that the rate action would serve as an
important signal that the U.S. intended to defend the value of the dollar.
While the Bank realized this action posed risks of an increase in domestic
interest rates, they felt these risks were outweighed by the need to
maintain international confidence in the dollar, particularly against the
background of rapid growth in monetary and credit aggregates in recent
months.




- 20 Federal Reserve Board: While the Board agreed that arguments
could be made in favor of a rate increase on international grounds,
it was not convinced that such action would have any significant
effect on European currency decisions. The Board believed that in
the existing circumstances, a rate increase might be considered to
be precipitate and hence would present problems both domestically
and internationally. The Board also believed that the sensitive state of
domestic debt markets argued strongly against an increase, and that such
an action could prove damaging to general confidence at a time when the
economic recovery was still fragile. The Board felt that any sharp
increase in interest rates might have severely adverse effects on flows
of funds to key sectors of the economy.

5.

June 22, 1971

Reserve Bank: The Philadelphia Bank felt that a rate
increase would be a desirable way to signal concern over persistent
inflationary pressures, particularly in view of the recent rapid expansion
in the monetary aggregates. They also noted that a rate increase could
be justified as a move toVmaintain general alignment between the discount
rate and the short-term market rates and that it will be in keeping with
their preference for a policy of flexibility in adjusting the discount
rate to changes in market rates.

Federal Reserve Board: The Board believed that a rate increase
at this time would not prove to be a constructive step in dealing with
inflation. The Board did not think that the current levels of shortterm rates called for a rate increase. An additional consideration at
this time was the desirability of avoiding a change in monetary policy
during the period when a Treasury financing was in progress.
6.

August 16, 1971

Reserve Bank: The St. Louis and Dallas Banks proposed the
rate increase against a background of continuing rapid growth in the
monetary aggregates and persisting concern about the rates of advance
in wages and prices. Most market interest rates had risen somewhat
further since the announcement of the rate increase on July 15.
Federal Reserve Board: The Board's decision not to approve
the proposed rate increase was made in light of the President's major
economic policy announcements on August 15. The Government's new
economic program was thought likely to help moderate the rise in prices
and wages while stimulating economic activity, and early reactions to
the President's announcements suggested that a downward adjustment in
market interest rates was developing. In these newly emerging
circumstances the Board concluded that an increase in the discount
rate would not be appropriate.
A central conclusion emerges from the experience summarized
here:

The Directors of a number of the Federal Reserve Banks have


become much


more willing to vote discount rate changes based on

economic developments as they see the situation unfolding.

The Federal

Reserve Board has encouraged the Directors to take more of an active role
in this regard.

At the same time, however, it is clear that many of the

Directors base their decisions on factors other than economic trends in
their own Districts.

In fact, an increasing number of Reserve Bank

Directors are stressing national and international developments as the
main reasons supporting their recommendations for rate changes.

(The

Directors of the New York Bank have traditionally followed that course.)
On the other hand, the Federal Reserve Board has demonstrated an
increasing willingness to disapprove formally those Reserve Bank proposals
for rate changes that do not accord ^ith its judgment as to appropriate
timing or amount.

Given the diversity of factors which must be considered

from the point of view of the country as a whole, the Board is the only
body within the System which has the overall perspective necessary to
orchestrate the instruments of monetary policy with other tools of
national economic policy.

III.

Member Bank Borrowing at Federal Reserve Banks
As mentioned at the outset, member banks as a group have

typically borrowed only infrequently and in modest amounts from Federal
Reserve Banks.

However, at times—such as during periods of substantial

monetary restraint—the banks have relied somewhat more heavily on
Reserve Bank credit.

Reliance by member banks on the Federal Reserve

System also varies significantly by class of bank and among Federal
Reserve Districts.




- 22 Record of Member Bank Borrowing
The record of member bank borrowing from Federal Reserve
Banks is shown in Table 6.

Borrowing in relation to member banks1

required reserves is also indicated.

In terms of the level of

borrowing, four periods stand out sharply:

1952-53;

1955-59;

1966,

and 1969-70.
In the early 1950's, a substantial part of the sharp jump
in credit outstanding at the discount window was related to the freeing
of the Government securities market from

pegged rates at a time

when private credit demands were strong.

But tax advantages rather

than credit conditions also played a significant part.

Such borrowing

climbed from about $300 million in 1951 to the neighborhood of $800
million in 1952-53.

This represented a rise from 1.5 per cent to 4.0

per cent of the banks1 required reserves.

Tax-related borrowing played

a significant role because of the profitability of such borrowing under
the provisions of the excess profits tax temporarily in effect during
8/
the Korean War.
The sizable volume of member bank borrowing in the remaining
years of the 1950*s was related more directly to the generally strong
private demands for credit in the face of severe monetary restraint.
8/

See Report of the System Committee on "Reappraisal of the Federal
Reserve Discount Mechanism,11 1968, p. 3.
In passing, it should be noted that this experience with taxmotivated borrowing by member banks was one of the main reasons (and
perhaps the most important one) why the Board undertook the basic
revision of Regulation A adopted in 1955.




- 23 From a level of around $200 million in 1954 (when monetary policy had
been eased to counter the recession), borrowing rose to $666 million
in 1955 and climbed further to an average of $840 million in 1956-57.
In attempting to cope with these demands, the Federal Reserve made
a number of increases in the discount rate.

For example, of the 22

rate increases in the 1953-71 period examined earlier, 9 occurred
between April, 1955, and August, 1957.

These moves took the discount

rate from 1-1/2 per cent (set in April, 1954) to 3-1/2 per cent (set
in August, 1 9 5 7 ) ^

_9/

During the 1957-58 recession borrowing by member

During this period, the System engaged in the only debate which
I have been able to find over whether the discount rate should
be a penalty rate. At the FOMC meeting of August 23, 1955,
Chairman Martin advanced such a proposal and asked the Board
Members and Reserve Bank Presidents to consider it. His proposal
was based on an analytical and historical analysis presented
by Messrs. Winfield W. Riefler and Ralph A. Young. At the
time the question at issue focused on a possible increase in
the discount rate of 1/4 per cent. Chairman Martin thought that
was the minimum increase required and argued strongly for a
general revamping of the conception and administration of the
discount rate--although he did not indicate exactly what the
penalty ought to be. The general reaction to the proposal was
overwhelmingly negative. Of the five Board Members present at
the meeting, Chairman Martin was the only one to support the
idea. Of the nine Reserve Bank Presidents present, two supported
the proposal, and six opposed it. Moreover, at the next meeting
of the FOMC, two Reserve Banks (after studying the Riefler-Young
papers which had not been distributed prior to the August 23 meeting)
returned to the issue and again came out against the transformation
of the discount rate into a penalty rate. The 1/4 per cent increase
was adopted on August 25, 1955, and the matter was never raised again
in a formal way. FOMC Minutes, 1955, pp. 466-497, and 520-525.




- 24 banks again declined substantially and averaged just under $300 million
in 1958.

But with the revival of economic activity, the level

spurted to $811 million in 1959.

With the shrinkage of credit demands

during the 1960-61 recession—and the easing of Federal Reserve
credit policy to stimulate economic activity—the level of borrowing
dropped to only $83 million in 1961.

Over the following three years,

it remained below $300 million.
As the pace of economic activity quickened in 1965--partly
under the impact of rising defense spending related to the Vietnam
War--member bank borrowing also rose.

It reached $492 million in that

year and advanced further to $650 million in 1966.

In this episode,

however, the Board took an entirely different view of the use of the
discount rate.

In fact, after the increase in the discount rate from

4 to 4-1/2 per cent in December, 1965 (adopted on a 4-3 vote), the
rate was not raised again until November, 1967—and it was reduced only
once, i.e., in April, 1967.

As indicated above, however, some of the

Reserve Banks did make rate proposals in 1966 that were disapproved.
Rather than relying more heavily on discount rate changes to moderate
credit demands, the Federal Reserve System adopted a variety of other
techniques in the pursuit of its goals.

Through open market operations,

the FGMC generated considerable pressure on bank reserves.

The Board

.raised member bank reserve requirements twice to achieve the same effect.
The maximum rates of interest which member banks could pay on time and




- 25 savings deposits were restricted.

Finally, on September 1, 1966,

at the Board's instruction, Federal Reserve Banks sent a letter to
all member banks indicating the desirability of the banks1 reducing
the expansion of business loans while avoiding further sizable
liquidations of municipal securities.

At the same time, it was

recognized that banks which followed this course might require

10/
accommodation at the discount window for longer periods than usual.
With the return of monetary restraint in 1969, member bank
borrowing again rose substantially—and averaged $1.1 billion in that
year.

The discount rate reached 6 per cent, and—as indicated above—

some Reserve Bank Directors wanted to raise it to 7 per cent.

Instead,

to restrict the availability of bank credit, the Board again relied
on a combination of other instruments--including higher reserve
requirements, the imposition of reserves against Euro-dollar borrowings,
and restriction on the use of funds obtained through sales of commercial

11/

paper.—

As credit conditions eased somewhat in 1970, member bank
borrowing also declined—to an average of $835 million.

In fact, the

decrease would have been even larger except for the special borrowing
by some banks necessitated by pressures in the commercial paper market which
were evident in June of that year.

As part of its effort to cope with

the situation, member banks were told that they could borrow from

TO?
U/

See Board of Governors, Anrm]^Re£ort, 1966, p. 32.
See Board's Annual Report, 1969, pp. 69-93.




- 26 Reserve Banks outside the normal standards if this were needed to
enable them to meet the credit needs of businesses unable to roll
12/
over maturing commercial paper.—

Borrowing under this facility

extended for about two months (from the first week in July into early
September).

The amounts outstanding reached a peak of just under $500

million (in the third week of July) and had dropped to less than $70
million by the time the facility was no longer needed in early September,
At the peak, these special Federal Reserve credits represented just
under two-fifths of total member bank borrowing—and they averaged
about one-third of the total during the weeks of most active use.
As monetary conditions eased through 1971, the volume of
borrowing declined to about $400 million, and it dropped further
to an average of only $80 million during the first seven months of
this year.
District Variation in Member Bank Reliance
on the Federal Reserve System
The extent to which member banks rely on the Federal Reserve
for assistance varies considerably.

Documentation to illustrate — and

above all explain--this diversity is hard to obtain.

However, by drawing

on a variety of statistical sources and oral discussions with officials
and staff members within the System and with numerous officials in
member banks, I have gotten a broad overview of what seems to

H7

See Board's Annual Report, 1970, p. 74.




be the

- 27 currently prevailing situation.
in Table 7 and Chart I.

The first piece of evidence is presented

This table shows Federal Reserve member banks

which borrowed from the Federal Reserve Bank in their District as a
percentage of all member banks which borrowed from any source.
These sources of member bank borrowing include the following:
(1) borrowing from Federal Reserve Banks;
funds;

(2) purchases of federal

(3) sales of participations in loan pools;

correspondent banks.

and (4) borrowing from

They do not include Euro-dollar borrowings and
13/

sales of capital notes and debentures.
In December, 1959, there were 6,227 banks that were members
of the Federal Reserve System.

During the course of that year, 2,339

banks borrowed from a variety of sources—including Federal Reserve
Banks.

The number which borrowed from the Federal Reserve was 1,967.

So in 1959, the proportion of members which borrowed from any source
was 38 per cent (2,339 out of 6,227); the proportion of all members
which borrowed from Reserve Banks was 32 per cent (1,967 out of 6,233).
The proportion of members borrowing from any source which also borrowed
from the Reserve Banks was 84 per cent (1,967 out of 2,339).
the situation had changed noticeably.
13/

By 1971,

In December, 1971, there were

Information on these sources of member bank borrowing was
obtained from the following: 1959-1968, Federal Reserve
Board Questionnaire completed by Reserve Banks. 1969-1971,
Income and Dividend Reports completed by member banks.




CHART 1

MEMBER BANKS BORROWING FROM THE RESERVE BANKS AS A PERCENTAGE
OF MEMBER BANKS BORROWING FROM ANY SOURCE, 1959-1971




PER CENT

- 33 5,727 member banks in the Federal Reserve System.

During the course

of that year, 2,584 banks borrowed from numerous sources--including
Reserve Banks.
was 900.

The number which borrowed from the Federal Reserve

So in 1971, the proportion of members which borrowed from

any source was 45 per cent (2,584 out of 5,728); the proportion of all
members which borrowed from Reserve Banks was 16 per cent (900 out
of 5,727).

The proportion of members borrowing from any source which

also borrowed from Reserve Banks was 35 per cent (900 out of 2,584).
Since 1959 was a year of monetary restraint--and 1971 was a year of
monetary ease--it might be helpful to look at 1969 as well—which was
also a year of restraint.

In 1969, there were 5,870 member banks.

Some 2,707 (46 per cent) of these borrowed from a variety of sources.
However, only 1,714 (29 per cent) of all member banks borrowed from
Federal Reserve Banks.

So in 1969, about 62 per cent of the banks which

borrowed from any source also borrowed from Reserve Banks (1,714 out
of 2,707).
In Table 7, the Reserve Bank-any source percentages are
recorded.

These were:

35 per cent.
years.

1959, 84 per cent; 1969, 62 per cent; and 1971,

Percentages are also recorded for each of the intervening

The same percentages are shown separately for each Federal Reserve

District for each of the years.

The same statistics are plotted in

Chart I for the System as a whole and for each of the 12 Federal
Reserve Districts.

The dotted line shows the percentages year by year

for all member banks combined—or for the System as a whole.

This System

profile is reproduced in each of the District panels—whose own experience i s
described by the solid line.




- 34 Several observations can be made on the basis of the
information presented here.

Turning back to the statistics on Federal

Reserve membership and borrowing, it will be noted that between 1959
and 1969, the number of banks in the Federal Reserve System declined
by 6 per cent, and between 1959 and 1971 the decrease was 8 per cent.
However, the number of member banks borrowing from any source rose by
16 per cent between 1959 and 1969.

Even after allowing for the

decline in the number of all borrowers between 1969 and 1971 (with the
easing of monetary restraint), the number of all member bank borrowers
still rose by 10 per cent between 1959 and 1971.

In contrast, the

number of member banks borrowing from Federal Reserve Banks dropped
by 12 per cent between 1959 and 1969 and by 54 per cent between 1959
and 1971.

In other words, the number of member banks depending on

the Federal Reserve for some part of their credit resources declined
substantially while the number turning to other sources registered a
noticeable rise*

This is due, at least in part, to the increased

development of the Federal funds market during the period.
Aside from the decline in the actual number of banks borrowing
from Reserve Banks, the proportion using the latter compared with all
sources of borrowing also recorded a persistent decline—except for
the period of severe monetary restraint in 1966 and 1969.
is clearly evident in Chart I.

This downtrend

But an equally striking feature of the

experience is the great diversity among Federal Reserve Banks.




- 35 For instance, the percentage of member banks which borrowed
from any source—but which also relied on Reserve Banks—was generally
above the System average in three Districts—Boston, New York, and
Kansas City.

The proportion was roughly the same as the System

average in four Districts—Philadelphia, Richmond, Chicago, and
Minneapolis.

It was below the System average in five Districts—Cleveland,

Atlanta, St. Louis, Dallas, and San Francisco.
The factors accounting for this diversity of experience among
Districts are not readily evident.

However, several considerations

seem to have a bearing on the situation.

First, the structure of banking

within each District must exert some influence.

Those Districts with

a disproportionate number of small member banks would probably see
only a small proportion of such members coming to the discount window.
Secondly, some of the Districts have a significant number of banks
whose deposit flows are subject to considerable variation.

These

banks might normally find it necessary to borrow fairly frequently, and
in so doing they might rely somewhat more than the average on Reserve
Banks.

In addition, the extent to which large city correspondent

banks compete for the balances—and to meet the credit needs—of
smaller member banks varies greatly from one District to another.

Such

correspondent banks apparently are particularly active in seeking
business in all of the five Districts where member banks seem to have
a below-average tendency to rely on Reserve Banks.

But correspondent

banks are also reportedly active in three of the four Districts where




- 36 the experience was about in line with average situations in the System
as a whole.

Thus, the role of correspondent banks might not be

especially decisive.

Finally, member banks in some Districts have

traditionally displayed a high degree of readiness to rely on their
Reserve Banks.

This seems to have been the case in the Boston and

New York Districts.
In the end, however, one must simply lay the observed
experience on the record and to encourage others to reflect on i t —
and hopefully join in the quest for explanations.
Borrowing By Class of Bank
Under ordinary conditions, the large money market banks
account for about one-fifth to one-quarter of total member bank
borrowing, and the remainder is divided about evenly between other
reserve city and country banks.
the situation in 1968.

As shown in Table 8, this was roughly

However, as credit conditions tighten--and as

the level of borrowing rises—the growth in such borrowing is likely
to be centered mainly in other reserve city banks.
was the pattern in 1969.

This too

In that year, the money market banks1 share

of total borrowings declined to 15 per cent, and the country banks1
share remained about unchanged—at 39 per cent.

In contrast, the share

of other reserve city banks climbed from 38 per cent to 46 per cent.
In 1970 and 1971, however, as monetary policy became less
severe, the distribution of borrowing did not return to the previous
pattern.

For example, in 1971, the proportion of total borrowings taken




- 37 by the money market banks did tend to converge toward the earlier
percentage—20 per cent compared with 25 per cent in 1968.

But for

other reserve city banks, the proportion of total borrowing outstanding
rose even further—to 56 per cent.

This experience was related to

the situation of a few large banks whose behavior was not directly
related to general credit conditions.

IV.

Market Interest Rates and Member Bank Borrowing
As noted above, one of the questions raised persistently

in the Federal Reserve has been concerned with the relationship between
the discount rate and short-term interest rates prevailing in the
money market.

On numerous occasions when proposals were made to

change the discount rate, among the reasons given was the desire to
keep the discount rate better aligned with other market rates.
logic of this argument appears to be straightforward:

The

if market rates

exceed the discount rate by a sizable margin, member banks would have
an incentive to turn to the discount window to meet a somewhat greater
share of their short-term credit needs.

If market rates were substantially

below the discount rate, member banks might be unduly inhibited from
using Reserve Bank resources.
What can be said about the reasonableness of this view?
While the evidence is mixed, it appears that member banks generally do
make somewhat greater use of the discount window when the structure of
interest rates suggests that it is to their benefit to do so.




- 38 Interest Rate Differentials and the Pattern
of Borrowing
This general pattern of behavior is illustrated in Chart II.
The upper panel of the chart shows (1) the discount rate at the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, (2) the federal funds rate, and (3) the
market yield on 90-day U.S. Treasury bills.

The lower panel shows

(1) the differential between the federal funds rate and the discount
rate, and (2) the volume of member bank borrowing outstanding.

The

time period covered is the 3-1/2 years extending from January, 1969
through July, 1972.
In general, the volume of borrowing does seem to vary directly
with the size of the interest rate differential.

When one allows for

those special events other than basic economic conditions which had a
direct bearing on the volume of borrowing, the suggested relationship
becomes even more evident.

For example, in mid-1970, the special

borrowing at the discount window that was related to the Penn Central
situation stands out sharply.
It will be noted that in 1969, the discount rate remained
unchanged until early April.

As monetary policy became increasingly

restrictive, market interest rates rose, and the spread between the
federal funds rate and the discount rate widened somewhat.
level of borrowing also rose slightly.

The average

However, the rise in the discount

rate was followed by a sharp spurt in market yields, and the differential
between the rates became substantially wider.
bank borrowing also rose considerably.




The volume of member

CHART 2

MONEY MARKET RATES AND BORROWING
FROM THE FEDERAL RESERVE
PER CENT
—110

FEDERAL FUNDS

I 1 1 I I I I I I I I 1 I I I I I I I I I I I 1 I I I I l*<
BASIS POINTS

8ILLI0NS OF DOLLARS

2

4oor~

BORROWINGS AT F.R. BANKS
200
FEDERAL FUNDS RATE LESS
F.R. DISCOUNT RATE
— LEFT SCALE

I I1IIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIIII I
1969



1970

I IIIII1 0
1971

1972

- 34 Moreover, throughout 1969 and well into 1970, the volume of
member bank borrowing subject to administrative review at the discount
window also increased somewhat.

In the process, an increasing number

of borrowing banks were questioned by Reserve Bank officers
concerning the frequency and duration of their use of Reserve Bank
credit.

These consultations undoubtedly had a

restraining influence

on the volume of borrowing.
Statistical Analysis of Member Bank Borrowing
The relationship between market interest rates and member
bank borrowing was also studied with the use of commonly employed
econometric techniques.

For this purpose, a preliminary regression was

run, which related the relative size of borrowings to interest rates
and the size of banks.
14/

The statistical results are described below.—

The regression relates the relative size of borrowings to interest rates
and the size of banks. The estimated relation is:
B/RR
**

= .1924 + .01299 ( r _
(18.996) (53.8093) "

-r ) D

.0003815-S
(-2.1309)

R

2

=

.0335

where B / r r is the ratio of borrowings to required reserves, r ^ is the
federal fund rate, r^ is the discount rate, and S is the size code for the
bank—where 1 is the largest class and 9 is the smallest. Data were available
for 40 months on banks that borrowed at least once during the period. Thus, a
total of 8 3 , 6 7 6 observations were used. These preliminary results do indicate
that banks
borrow more as the spread in interest rates increases, and that
larger banks (represented by the smaller status code) borrow relative more
than do small banks.
This equation is indeed preliminary to further study. There are
many zero values for the dependent variable in the data used. This Implies that
the normal distribution does not apply to the disturbance term, and thus the t
values are unreliable. Secondly, the size variable should be replaced by a
more appropriate variable such as total deposits or total assets. We will
also test the significance of portfolio variables such as loan to asset
ratios.




As is the case with all

findings of this character, these results

must be interpreted with caution.

But they do indicate in a general

way that banks tend to borrow more as the spread between market
interest rates and the discount rate increases.

The results also

suggest that the larger banks--at least during the period studiedtended to borrow more in relation to their share of reserves than did
the smaller banks.

Bank Structure and Member Bank Borrowing
As I mentioned at the outset, aside from tracing the broad
trends in member bank borrowing, I also wanted to probe the ways in
which banks which borrowed from the Federal Reserve

managed their

assets and liabilities compared with those member banks which did not
rely on credit from the Federal Reserve discount window.
In approaching this part of the assignment, I wanted to
examine the member banks primarily according to size and location in
particular Districts.

For this purpose,three primary sources of data

had to be integrated.

The first task was to identify in a systematic

fashion those banks which borrowed and those which did not.

So the first

requirement was to examine on a daily basis each of the roughly 5,800
member banks to determine their borrowing status and reserve position
during the 3-1/2 years from January 1, 1969, through May 31, 1972.

This

project was carried out by a member of the Board's staff with the aid
of the Board's computer and using primarily statistics from the "ShortRun Banking System Reports" (SBR).




- 36 The next task was to analyze the portfolio structures of
borrowing banks compared with nonborrowers.

For this purpose,use was

made of the Call Reports for each member bank, as of December 31, 1969,
1970, and 1971.

The third task was to analyze bank borrowing from

the Federal Reserve compared with alternative sources of short-term
funds.

Data for this purpose came from the reports submitted weekly

by 330 large banks (of which 315 are Federal Reserve member
banks).

However, the weekly data had to be matched with statistics

from the SBR series and the Call Report.
In each of these assignments, the objective was to generate
data for member hanks distributed by size and Federal Reserve District,
(A few member banks were excluded from the data because their heavy
borrowing from the Federal Reserve was related to supervisory problems.)
The examination of member bank borrowing using econometric techniques,
which was described above, was also based on the same set of data.
The statistical data relating to member bank borrowing
by size and Federal Reserve District obtained

as a result the projects

described above and are summarized in Tables 9 through 14.
contain the Call Report data.

Tables 9 and 10

Table 11-a shows the distribution of

member banks, required reserves, and amount borrowed (by size and
Federal Reserve District) during the 3-1/2 years January, 1969 through
May, 1972.

Tables11-b through 11-e show the same data for each year

taken separately.

Table 12-a shows member bank borrowing in relation

to required reserves by size of bank and Federal Reserve District for




the 3-1/2 years combined.

Tables 12-b through 12-e present the same data

for each of the years taken separately.

Tables 13 and 14 show selected

assets and liabilities, respectively, for weekly reporting banks--identifying
borrowers and nonborrowers separately by size of bank—for the three
years 1969, 1970 and 1971.
Borrowing By Size of Bank
As shown in Table 9, 5,877 member banks were included in
the borrowing study for 1969.
and to 5,730 in 1971.

The number decreased to 5,776 in 1970

Of these members, 1,695 borrowed from the

Federal Reserve Banks in 1969;

the number of borrowers totaled

1,391 in 1970 and 900 in 1971.

Thus, in 1969, 29 per cent of

the member banks included in the study bor-owed from the Federal Reserve.
The proportion was 24 per cent in 1970 and 16 per cent in 1971.

However,

as indicated earlier, the degree of reliance by member banks on
the Federal Reserve varied directly with size.

Among the member banks

with total deposits of $1.0 billion and over, 90 per cent borrowed from
the Federal Reserve in 1969.

The corresponding figure was 91 per cent

in 1970 and 84 per cent in 1971.

In contrast, among the member banks

with total deposits of under $3.0 million, only 10 per cent borrowed during
each of the 3 years.

In all 3 years, the percentage of member banks

which borrowed from the Federal Reserve decreased steadily throughout
the size spectrum—except for banks with deposits under $3 million.
The reasons underlying this observed pattern of borrowing are
easily understood.

The larger institutions — especially those located

in Reserve cities--typically experience considerable variation




in

- 38 deposit flows.

While some of these are seasonal in nature, to a

considerable extent

this somewhat unstable deposit behavior

is inherent in the character of their business.

On the

other hand, many of the smaller member banks are located outside
of metropolitan areas, and the composition of their deposits is such
that they can predict fairly accurately the timing of deposit and
withdrawal of funds.

Although their accounts may be subject to

considerable seasonal variations, they typically do not have the
types of short-term credit needs which can normally be satisfied at
Reserve Banks.
Borrowing By Federal Reserve District
The extent to which member banks in particular Districts
borrowed from their respective Reserve Banks is shown in Table 10.
In each of the 3 years, the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston had the
highest proportion of borrowers.
borrowed in 1969.

Over three-fifths of the members

Although the proportion declined to just over one-

half in 1970 and to roughly two-fifths in 1971, these were still the
highest fractions for any of the Districts.

The New York Federal

Reserve District ranked second in each of the 3 years.

Borrowers

as a proportion of all members amounted to 50 per cent in 1969;
per cent in 1970, and 37 per cent in 1971.

44

In both of these Districts,

member banks have a long-standing tradition of reliance on the Federal
Reserve.




- 39 At the opposite end of the spectrum, the District with the lowest
percentage of borrowing members changed over the 3 years.

In 1969, the

Cleveland District was at the bottom— as borrowers represented 16
per cent of all member banks.

In both 1970 and 1971, Dallas was in the

last position—with 12 per cent of its banks borrowing in 1970 and only 4
per cent in 1971.

Again, in looking for an explanation of the observed

experience, one is thrown back on the kind of considerations mentioned
above in connection with the discussion of diversity among District borrowing
patterns.
play

The characteristics of the intra-District banking structure undoubtedly

a role.

Beyond that, the different ways in which member banks

view themselves with respect to access to the discount window may
also have a bearing on the behavior noted.
Other detailed comparisons of borrowing patterns among
Reserve Districts could also be made.

However, the mosaic sketched

in Chart I seems to be generally reproduced in the detailed statistics.
Time Span of Borrowings and Required Reserves
When member banks do borrow from the Federal Reserve, they
must do so within specified guidelines governing the frequency and
duration of borrowing.

Moreover, the typical member bank seeks Reserve

Bank accommodation with an eye toward meeting its required reserves
during a given reserve accounting period.

By 1969, all member banks

were on a one-week reserve period basis.

(Prior to September, 1968,

country banks had a two-week reserve computation period.)




- 40 In an attempt to identify the time span of borrowing by
the typical bank from the System, the approach in the present study
was to focus on the average number of days during a given period on
which a member bank

was indebted to a Federal Reserve Bank.

As

already indicated, each member bank was examined on a daily basis
during the entire 3-1/2-year period covered by this study.
follows:

The results were as

during the whole 3-1/2-year period the member banks which

borrowed were indebted to Reserve Banks for an average of 78 days.
Since these 3-1/2 years were composed of 1,278 days, this meant that
member banks borrowing from Reserve Banks were indebted to the
System for about 6 per cent of the total time covered.

The average

number of borrowing days varied directly with size of bank.

Among

the largest group, the average number of borrowing days equaled 108-or approximately 8 per cent of the time.

At the smaller end of the

size spectrum, the average number of banks in the $3-7 million class
averaged 66 borrowing days—or only 5 per cent of the time.

On the

other hand, the average number of borrowing days among banks in different
size categories varied considerably with credit conditions.

During 1969--

a year of considerable monetary restraint—the banks with total
deposits of $1.0 billion and over averaged 57 borrowing days; this
represented 16 per cent of the days of that year.

But in 1971, banks

in the $1 billion and over class had 18 borrowing days, or an average




- 41 of only 5 per cent of the time.

In contrast, banks at the lower

end of the spectrum averaged about 40 borrowing days in 1969 (just
over 10 per cent of the time), and in 1971 they averaged 45 days
of indebtedness to Reserve Banks (more than 12 per cent of the time).
Over the 3-1/2 year period, all member banks which borrowed
from the Federal Reserve had average required reserves of $11.2 million.
However, as one would expect, the amount of required reserves varied
considerably with respect to size of bank.

For example, borrowing

banks with $1.0 billion and over of total deposits had average required
reserves of $225 million, while those in the smaller size group had
average required reserves of only $134,000-

In this analysis,the

interest is not so much in the amount of reserves but rather in the
proportion of their requirement which member banks
from Reserve Banks.

borrowed

For the 3-1/2 years as a whole, those member banks

which did borrow from the Federal Reserve obtained about 2-1/2 per
cent of their required reserves from this source.
varied sharply with credit conditions.
were

This proportion

Thus, in 1969, borrowings

5 per cent of required reserves for all of the borrowing member

banks—but only 1-1/2 per cent in 1971.

The situation also varied

noticeably during these years when the borrowing banks are examined
by size.

In general, the smaller banks obtained a larger proportion of

their required reserves (about 4-1/2 per cent vs. 2 per cent) through
Reserve Bank borrowing than did the borrowing institutions at the top
of the size scale.

Again, however, the relative position varied with

credit conditions.

In 1969, the largest banks obtained about 3-1/2 per




- 42 cent of their required reserves by borrowing from the Federal Reserve
Banks, but in 1971 the proportion had dropped to 1 per cent.

In

contrast, the smallest member banks borrowed about 6-1/2 per
cent of their required reserves from the System in 1969, but the
fraction rose to 7 per cent in 1971.

This general tendency for the

banks to rely less on the Federal Reserve as their size class increased—
and as credit conditions eased--is dlso evident in fche data.

VI^

Portfolio Structure

and Member Bank Borrowings

In this study, we were interested in the type of bank likely to
be a borrower from the Federal Reserve.

As mentioned earlier, borrowing

does tend to be positively related to size.

We also expected to find a

relationship between willingness to borrow and the borrowing banks1 general
portfolio strategy.

The data do indicate some rather pronounced tendencies.

A look at Table 9 reveals that large banks tend to keep a
higher proportion of their assets in loans.

The $1 billion and

over borrowing banks in 1969 had a loan to asset ratio of 56.6 per cent,
whereas the banks in the smallest category had only 51.9 per cent.

In

periods of less stringent credit conditions than 1969, the ratio for all
banks tended to be lower.
Note that the average loan to asset ratio for total borrowing
banks is higher than the total for the nonborrowers.

The difference is

especially pronounced in 1969—55.4 per cent contrasted to 50.6 per cent.
In the tw6 latter years,the deficiency

is not as great- but still apparent.

Borrowing banks tend to be more aggressive lenders.
with our expectations.



This was in accord

Banks that seek profits through a greater volume

-43of loans are likely to be aggressive in the management of the liability
side of the balance sheet as well.

This aggressiveness is also illustrated

in holdings of U.S. Government securities.
hold Governments is decidely less.

The borrowing banks desire to

Looking at Table 9 again, we see that

in 1969 nonborrowers held 13.7 per cent of their assets in these securities
and borrowers held only 7.7 per cent.

The difference is also pronounced

in the two latter years. The borrowing group also had a higher propensity
to buy more-- and to sell less—federal funds.

Table 10 presents the data by Federal Reserve District rather
than size.

Loan to asset ratios differ greatly among the Districts.

Among borrowing banks, San Francisco member banks had the highest ratio
(59.2) in 1969 and the Kansas City banks had the lowest (49.4).

In each year, the

San Francisco District had the highest ratio in both the borrowing and nonborrowing category.

This probably reflects the greater deposit predictability

(and the resulting greater willingness to tie up money in loans) that large
branch banks enjoy.
The greater aggressiveness of borrowers is also shown in the
weekly reported data in Tables 13 and 14.

Borrowers hold far more

commercial and industrial loans than do nonborrowers.
represent the most illiquid portion of total loans.

These, of course,
Although borrowers hold

fewer Government securities, the proportion of Treasury bills held Is very
similar.

Need for Treasury bills may be uniform because these securities

are used primarily to meet pledging requirements, and this need is not
greatly different for borrowers or nonborrowers.




- 44 VII.

Member Bank Borrowing and Alternative Sources of Funds
It was not a priori obvious whether borrowers at the

Federal Reserve would be more or less likely to be aggressive
bidders for alternative sources of funds.

One could have reasoned

that greater borrowing causes a lesser need for other funds.
Alternatively, we could have reasoned that banks feeling in need of
funds would tap all sources simultaneously.
The evidence developed here (Table 14) suggests that the
use of alternative sources of short-term funds does differ slightly
between borrowers and nonborrowers.

For example, borrowing banks

obtain a lesser proportion of their liabilities through issues of
large denomination certificates of deposit.

On average, Federal

Reserve borrowers1 purchases of federal funds is slightly greater.
There is an interesting disparity by size of bank, however.

In the

$1 billion or over class, non-Federal Reserve borrowers have a ratio
of funds purchases to liabilities of 11.7 per cent (1969 data).
compares to only 6.0 per cent for borrowers.
class, the disparity is in the other direction.
of the 3 years analyzed.

This

In every other size
This occurs in eqch

Note that "other borrowing" is about the same

for the users and non-users of the discount window.

This category

includes nonfederal funds borrowing from security dealers and other
commercial banks, and repurchase agreements with non-financial
corporations.




-45-

VIII.

Concluding Observations
The main results obtained in this study of discount policy

and borrowing by Federal Reserve member banks were sunmarized in
Section I.
made.

Before closing, several additional observations can be

First, the analysis suggests that smaller borrowers do rely

on the Reserve Banks to meet a somewhat larger proportion of their
required reserves than do the biggest institutions.

Yet, it Is

the changing behavior of the latter which determines the most prominent
features in the landscape of total member bank borrowing.
Over the 3-1/2 years covered in the study, banks with $1 billion
and over in total deposits, on the average, represented 1 per cent of
all member banks and 3 per cent of all the members which borrowed
from Reserve Banks.

The largest groups' required reserves averaged

58 per cent of the total, and they accounted for just under half of total
borrowings.

During 1969—a year of severe monetary restraint--the

largest groups1 share of required reserves remained essentially unchanged
at 59 per cent of the total, while their share of borrowing declined
to 41 per cent.

In 1971, partly under the influence of easier credit

conditions, the biggest banks' share of required reserves rose to 70
per cent, and their share of total borrowing climbed to 56 per cent.
In contrast, the share of required reserves and borrowings accounted
for by the smallest banks (less than 0.2 per cent) remained essentially
unchanged.




While borrowing banks in the middle of the size spectrum

-46-

showed modest changes in their proportions of required reserves and
borrowings during the 3-1/2 years, they also contributed very little
to the overall variation

in member bank borrowing

from the Federal

Reserve.
If the volume of borrowing is taken as a rough approximation
of the benefits associated with the privilege of discounting at
Reserve Banks, the data examined in this study also suggest that the
largest banks (with total deposits of $1 billion and over) obtain
benefits that are somewhat tess than their relative position in the
System would imply.

However, the large banks just below those in

the top size category receive a somewhat larger share of the benefits.
This tendency for the share of borrowing to exceed the respective
share of required reserves extends down through the size spectrum
including member banks with total deposits between $20 million and
$50 million. (See Tables 12-a through 12- e .)
This general profile is not altogether surprising.
mentioned several times above

As

(despite the noticeable variability

of their deposits), the very largest banks are normally under close
and continuous surveillance by the Federal Reserve.

Thus, their

indebtedness to the System is likely to be held under fairly firm
restraint at all times.

On the other hand, many of the large member

banks just below the top size category also have deposits on their
books that are normally quite volatile.

Yet, they frequently are

more able to turn to the Federal Reserve—among other sources




to

-47-

obtain the short-term credit needed to adjust their positions.

In

so doing, they become beneficiaries of Federal Reserve credit extended
through the discount window to a degree somewhat in excess of their
proportionate share of total member bank required reserves.
The evidence presented in this paper also suggests that
borrowing by member banks is somewhat sensitive to money market
interest rates.

While the statistical foundation for this observation

is less firm than one would wish, the general conclusion does seem
to be supported.
clear:

The inference to be drawn from these facts also seems

member banks which borrow from the Federal Reserve do seem

to have at least a modest incentive to use the discount window at
times when the discount rate diverges appreciably from interest rates
in the money market.
Finally, as I reflect on the principal features of member
bank borrowing which emerged from this study, several questions are
raised in my own mind:




--Should borrowing by member banks continue to be
viewed as a "privilege11 rather than as a "right"
of Federal Reserve membership?
--Should the discount rate be kept more closely in line
with market rates? In fact, should the discount rate
take on more of the characteristics of a penalty
rate—and thus subject member bank borrowing to the
price mechanism to a greater degree than has normally
been the case?
--Should the administrative posture at the discount
window in the different Reserve Banks be re-examined
with the idea of enhancing uniformity of conditions
affecting borrowing throughout the System?

Table 1.

Increase
Time Lag

Adjustment Time for Federal Reserve System
Discount Rate Changes, 1953-1971
(Number of Days)

Lead Time

Decrease
Time Lag

Duration

5.4

0.1

6.6

6.7

0.3

5.8

6.1

2.6

3.7

0.0 1/

0.0 1/

0.0 1/

0.6

1.3

1.9

3.4

1.1

4.5

0.1

4.8

4.9

1.8

3.0

4,7

1970-71

0.6

2.6

3.2

2.2

2.4

4.7

1.4

2.5

4.0

1953-71

1.2

3.7

4.9

1.0

4.7

5.7

1.1

4.1

5.3

Period

Lead Time

1953-60

0.4

5.0

1963-65

1.1

1967-69

If

Duration

Total Adjustment Time
Lead Time
Time Lag

No rate decreases occurred during this period.

Note:

"Adjustment Time" represents the weighted averages of days involved in the adjustment
of discount rate changes, using as weights the number of Federal Reserve Banks posting
the change on a given day. "Lead Time" is the number of days elapsed between action by
the first Reserve Bank Board proposing a rate change and approval action by the Federal
Reserve Board. "Time Lag" is the number of days elapsed between approval action of the
Federal Reserve Board and the adjustment of the rate by the last Reserve Bank. "Duration"
is the time elapsed between the beginning and end of the rate adjustment process.




-48-

Still other questions are raised in my mind, but I think
these few raise enough substantive questions to keep those of us who
work in the Federal Reserve System busy for a long time.

I personally

have not arrived at a firm position with respect to any of these
issues, and I look forward to weighing them with my colleagues within
the System.




- 0 -

Table 3. Behavior of Federal Reserve Banks in the
Discount Rate Adjustment Process, 1953-1971

Number of
Cases
I

Boston

Per cent of
Cases

Coincident Bank
Number of
Per cent of
Cases
Cases

Number of
Cases

Per cent of
Cases

Lead Bank
Number of
Per cent of
Cases
Cases

Decrease
Coincident Bank
Number of
Per cent of
Cases
Cases

Lag Bank
Number of
Per cent of
Cases
Cases

Total Adjustment Process
Lead Bank
Coincident Bank
Number of Per cent of Number of Per cent of
Cases
Cases
Cases
Cases

Las Bank
Number of Per cent
Cases ^ q f Cases

» 4M p . O

4

18. 2

3

13. 6

15

6fc.2

41..2

2

11,.8

8

47.1

11

28,>2

5

12,.8

11

50, 0

7

31.8

0,.0

7

41,.2

10

58.8

4

10,,3

18

46,.2

17

43.6

AO. 9

10

45.5

11,.8

8

47,,1

7

41.2

5

12..8

17

43,,6

17

43.6

7

2

New York

4

18.,2

3

Philadelphia

3

13.,6

4

Cleveland

6

27.,3

4

18.,2

12

54.6

11,,8

8

47..1

41.2

8

20,,5

12

30,.8

19

48.7

5

Richmond

3

13.,6

6

27..3

13

59.1

5,,9

5

29,,4

U

64.7

4

10..3

11

28.2

24

61.5

6

Atlanta

5

22.J

4

18.,2

13

59.1

5.,9

4

23..5

12

70.6

6

15.,4

8

20..5

25

64.1

45.,5

8

36.4

17,.6

4

23..5

10

58.8

7

17..9

14

35,,9

18

46.2

7

Chicago

4

18. 2

10

8

St. Louis

5

22,,7

7

31..8

10

45.5

23,.5

4

23.,5

9

52.9

9

23,.1

11

28..2

19

48.7

3

13,,6

8

36.>4

11

50.0

23,,5

6

35,,3

7

41.2

7

17.,9

14

35,.9

18

46.2

9

Minneapolis

10

Kansas City

I

4,.5

6

27,.3

15

68.2

17.,6

2

11..8

12

70.6

4

10,

8

20,,5

27

69.2

It

Dallas

4

16.,2

6

27,.3

12

54.6

17.,6

2

11,.8

12

70.6

7

17.,9

8

20..5

24

61.5

12

San Francisco

4

18,,2

7

31,.8

11

50.0

23..5

4

23.,5

9

52.9

8

20.5

11

28,,2

20

51.3

Average Position
(All Banks)

3.8

17,.3

6.8

30,,1

11.4

51.8

16.,5

4.7

27..7

9.5

55.9

6.7

17.,2

11.4

29..2

20.9

53.6

Total (Number of
Actions)
Note:

22

22

See Note on

ppendlx Table 1.




-

22

-

2.8
17

17

17

—

39

-

39

--

39

Table 2.

District

Reserve Bank

Adjustment Time for Federal Reserve Banks
Discount Rate Changes, 1953-1971
(Number of Days)

Lead Time

Increase
Time Lag

Duration

Lead Time

Decrease
Time Lag

Duration

1

Boston

0.6

5.2

5.8

5.2

3.7

8.9

2

New York

0.5

3.5

4.0

0.0

2.1

2.1

3

Philadelphia

0.9

3.4

4.3

1.5

4.1

5.6

4

Cleveland

1.0

4.2

5.2

0.3

3.9

4.2

5

Richmond

0.7

5.1

5.8

0.1

5.6

5.7

6

Atlanta

1.9

2.9

4.8

0.2

5.1

5.3

7

Chicago

0.6

3.3

3.9

0.4

3.5

3.9

8

St. Louis

3.1

3.3

6.4

1.0

4.3

5.3

9

Minneapolis

0.2

2.7

2.9

1.0

4.2

5.2

10

Kansas City

0.3

4.5

4.8

0.1

4.4

4.5

11

Dallas

3.0

2.9

5.9

0.4

8.8

9.2

12

San Francisco

0.8

3.3

4.1

0.9

4.4

5.3

Total System

1.2

3.7

4.9

1.0

4.7

5.7

Note:

Weighted averages of days.




(See note to Table 1.)

Table 5.

District
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12

Discount Rate Proposals Disapproved by the Federal Reserve
Board, 1966, 1969, and 1971

Reserve Bank
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total

Note:

1966

1969

1971

3-Year
Total

2
1
2
2
0
0
2
1
1
0
0
0

1
0
0
0
0
0
3
3
0
1
0
0

0
1
1
0
0
0
0
2
0
0
1
0

3
2
3
2
0
0
5
6
1
1
1
0

11

8

5

24

Rates Proposed
(Per Cent)
1966
1969
1971
5, 5
4-1/2
5, 5
5, 5

6-1/2
-

5-1/4
5

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

5,5-1/2
5
5-1/2

7,7,7
6,7,7

-

5,5-1)
-

-

-

7

-

-

-

-

-

5-1/2

(1) All proposals involved rate increases.
(2) In 1966, 9 of the proposals were for 1/2 per cent to raise the
rate from 4-1/2 to 5 per cent; 2 (Chicago and Minneapolis)
were for 1 per cent to raise the rate to 5-1/2 per cent.
In 1969, 2 proposals were for 1/2 per cent- 1 (St. Louis) to
raise the rate from 5-1/2 to 6 per cent and 1 (Boston) to
raise the rate from 6 to 6-1/2 per cent. All other proposals
were for 1 per cent to raise the rate from 6 to 7 per cent.
In 1971, 2 proposals (Philadelphia and St. Louis) were for
1/4 per cent to raise the rate to 5 per cent; 3 proposals
were for 1/2 per cent - 1 (New York) to raise the rate from
4-3/4 to 5-1/4 and 2 (Dallas and St. Louis) to raise the
rate from 5 to 5-1/2 per cent.




-

Table 4. Relative Position of Federal Reaerve Banks Ranked by
Size of Average Lead-Lag Position in Discount Rate Changes, 1953-1971
(Lead*Lag in Days)
Increases
Rank

Reserve Bank

Lead
Position

Rank

Reserve Bank

Lag
Position

Rank

Reserve Bank

Decreases
Lead
Rank
Position

Reserve Bank

Lag
Position

3.1

1

Boston

5.2

1

Boston

5.2

1

Dallas

8.8

2

Dallas

3.0

2

Richmond

5.1

2

Philadelphia

1.5

2

Richmond

5.6

3

Atlanta

1.9

3

Kansas City

4.5

3

St. Louis

1.0

3

Atlanta

5.1

4

Cleveland

1.0

4

Cleveland

4.2

4

Minneapolis

1.0

4

Kansas City

4.4

5

Philadelphia

0.9

5

New York

3.5

5

San Francisco

0.9

5

San Francisco

4.4

6

San Francisco

0.8

6

Philadelphia

3.4

6

Chicago

0.4

6

St. Louis

4.3

7

Richmond

0.7

7

Chicago

3.3

7

Dallas

0.4

7

Minneapolis

4.2

8

Boston

0.6

8

St. Louis

3.3

8

Cleveland

0.3

8

Philadelphia

4.1

9

Chicago

0.6

9

San Francisco

3.3

9

Atlanta

0.2

9

Cleveland

3.9

10

New York

0.5

10

Atlanta

2.9

10

Richmond

0.1

10

Boston

3.7

11

Kansas City

0.3

11

Dallas

2.9

11

Kansas City

0.1

11

Chicago

3.5

12

Minneapolis

0.2

12.

Minneapolis

12.

New York

0

12

New York

2.1

System Average
Adjustment Time

1.2




--J

u>

to

St. Louis

-sj

1

1.0

4.7

Table 7.

Year |

All
Districts!

Member Banks Borrowing from the Federal Reserve Banks as a Percentage
of Member Banks Borrowing From Any Source, 1959-1971

1

2

3

4

5

Districts """"
6
1 7

8

9

10

1

XI

1

12

1959
1960
1961
1962

84
80
71
64

90
90
81
77

83
82
77
66

95
89
84
71

84
78
66
55

79
77
70
60

70
63
48
46

85
86
77
73

72
72
40
44

91
85
68
49

91
90
86
83

80
78
46
52

65
54
36
32

1963
1964
1965
1966

65
56
45
63

76
69
56
78

68
65
64
74

69
62
57
60

68
46
35
51

54
50
48
57

49
39
40
51

74
60
58
69

40
42
34
49

68
56
59
66

80
77
71
81

53
43
31
50

37
24
22
33

1967
1968
1969
1970
1971

44
51
62
52
35

57
69
91
73
52

64
67
71
71
58

38
47
52
48
33

27
37
38
31
21

39
45
61
51
37

29
31
45
28
24

48
54
62
60
43

34
38
55
47
20

40
58
69
52
27

65
60
80
63
48

30
47
56
36
12

27
34
39
39
23

Source:

Division of Federal Reserve Bank Operations, Federal Reserve Board.




Table 6,




Member Bank Borrowing and Required Reserves, 1951 - 1972
(Amounts in Millions of Dollars)

Borrowing from
Federal Reserve Banks
Per Cent of
Required Reserves
Amount

YEAR

Required
Reserves

1951
1952
1953
1954
1955

19,667
20,520
19,397
18,618
18,903

293
801
777
217
666

1.5
3.9
4.0
1.2
3.5

1956
1957
1958
1959
1960

19,089
19,091
18,574
18,619
18,988

833
850
295
811
436

4.4
4.5
1.6
4.4
2.3

1961
1962
1963
1964
1965

20,114
20,071
20,677
21,663
22,848

83
137
269
294
492

0.4
0.7
1.3
1.4
2.2

1966
1967
1968
1969
1970

24,321
25,905
27,439
28,173
30,033

650
178
569
1,103
835

2.7
0.7
2.1
3.9
2.8

1971
1972 (July)

32,496
32,820

412
202

1.3
0.6

Table 9. Selected Portfolio Characteristic* of Federal Reserve Heather Banks,
Borrowers vs. Nonborrowers, By Sire of Bank, 1969, 1970 and 1971

Six* of Bank
(Total deposits In
adlllons of dollars)

lumber of Banks
Total

FED
Borrowers

Bon-FED
Borrowers

FED
Borrowers
as Per Cent
of Total

FED
Borrowers

Percentage of Total Assets
U.S. Gov't. Securities
Federal Funds Sold
Non-FED
FED
Ron-FED
FED
Non-FED
Borrowers Borrowers
Borrowers
Borrowers
Borrowers

Percentage of Total Liabilities
Total Borrowings
Federal Panda Purchased
Non-FED
FED
Non-FED
FED
Borrowers
Borrowers
Borrowers
Borrowers

1969
1.000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
Total

49
55
336
336
1,063
942
lt260
1.353
463
5.877

44
48
271
207
409
241
235
196
44
1,695

5
7
65
129
654
701
1,025
1,157
439
4,182

89.8
87.3
80.7
61.6
38,5
25.6
18.7
14.5
9.1
28.8

56.6
54.3
54.0
53.4
53.3
51.2
50.9
51.2
51.9
55.4

54.2
56.7
51.0
51.3
50.9
49.1
48.0
46.1
43.6
50.6

1,000 and user
500-1,000
100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
local

56
59
349
367
1,129
980
1,233
1,205
398
5,776

51
44
226
167
318
204
205
138
38
1,391

5
15
123
200
811
776
1,028
1,067
360
4,385

91.1
74.6
64.8
45.5
28.2
20.8
16.6
11.5
9.6
24.1

53.4
52.0
51.8
51.4
51.1
50.7
51.6
51.5
50.0
52.7

53.7
54.0
49.4
49.7
49.1
47.5
46.7
45.7
42.3
49.5

6.1
7.4
9.3
11.9
12.6
13.7
14.5
16.9
20.9
7.7

7.7
8.0
12.3
12.6
13.3
15.8
17.4
20.2
23.8
13.7

1.2
2.2
1.6
1.4
1.5

7.2
9.2
10.3
12.4
12.9
15.4
17.0
19.9
24.0
12.5

1.9
3.7
3.0
3.0
2.6
2.2
2.3
1.9
1.3
2.3

4.1

7.6
8.7
9.8
11.6
12.6
15.2
16.0
18.9
22.3
11.4

2.4
3.2

4.0
4.6
4.0
3.6
3.8
4.5
4.5
5.0
6.1
4.1

1.6
1.5
2.3
2.3
2.8
3.6
3.4
4.1
3.6
2.7

1.0
1.4
0.5
0.2
0.3
0.2
0.4
0.3
0.6
0.9

3.6
*

0.2
•
0.1
*
*
*
*

0.4

5.1
6.1
2.7
1.0
0.5

0.4
0.3
OA
0.1
4.2

7.7
1.4
1.6
0.7
#

0.1
*

1.2

1970
6.8
8.3
9.4
11.8
12.9
14.4
15.4
18.0
21.5
8.0

2.6

0.7

3.7
3.3
3.9
4.3
4.1
4.4
4.5
3.8

0.6

l.l

0.2

0.7
0.3
0.2
*

0.2
0.1

0.2
0.5
0.3
0.7

0.1

5.5

6.0
2.7
1.2
0.4
0.4
0.3
0.4
0.4
4.7

6.3
2.7
2.3
0.4
0.3
0.1
0.1

0*.1
1.4

1971
1,000 and ovtr

500-1,000

100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-12
Under 3
Total

Soqrte: Call

53
10
63
44
26
70
155
221
376
107
307
414
1,031
to*
1,216
958
lit
1,069
1,170
1,037
133
1,034
81
953
318
287
31
5, 730
900
4,830
Exports,,Decndter 31 of each year.




84.1
62.9
41.2
25.9
15.2
10.4
11.4
7.8
9.8
15.7

53.1
51.5
52.0
52.9
50.5
52.1
5K8
52.0
48.4
52.7

•less than 0.05 per cent.

51.8
50.7
48.7
49.4
49.1
47.1
46.6
45.3
42.1
49.0

6.6
7.9
9.0
11,7
12.7
15.1
16.0
17.7
23.5
7.4

2.0

1.9

1.8
2.3
2.1
1.5

1.8

2.4

0.3
0.7
0.2
*
0.2
0.3
0.5
0.4
1.4
0.3

0.1
0.3
0.5

0.1
0,
*1
0.1
*

0.1
0.2

7.4
6.1
3.4
1.2
0.7
0.9
0.4
0.3
0.3
6.4

9.0

6.1

3.4
0.8
0.4

«
0.2

0.2
.2

Table 8.

All
Banks

Member Bank Borrowing By Class of Bank, 1968 - 1972
Total Borrowing
(millions of dollars)!'
Money
Other
Market .
Reserve
Banks^/
City Banks

Country
Banks

Percentage Distribution
Money
Other
Market .
Reserve
Country
Banks^-'
City Banks
Banks

1968
January
February
March
April
May
June
July
August
September
October
November
December
Average (Estimated)

237
361
671
683
746
692
525
565
515
427
569
765
562

51
110
165
171
144
107
99
194
177
74
79
315
140

111
126
288
283
262
258
152
161
194
186
274
270
214

75
125
218
229
340
327
274
210
144
167
216
180
208

21.5
30.5
24.6
25.0
19.3
15.5
18.9
34.3
34.4
17.3
13.9
41.2
24.9

46.8
34.9
42.9
41.4
35.1
37.3
29.0
28.5
37.7
43.6
48.2
35.3
38.1

31.7
34.6
32.5
33.6
45.6
47.2
52.1
37.2
27.9
39.1
38.0
23.5
37.0

697
824
918
996
1,402
1,407
1,190
1,249
1,067
1,135
1,241
1,086
1,105

113
102
163
227
273
123
91
132
138
157
226
286
169

321
420
449
512
618
713
517
480
461
531
572
479
506

263
302
306
257
511
571
582
637
468
447
443
321
430

16.2
12.4
17.8
22.8
19.5
8.7
7.7
10.6
12.9
13.8
18.2
26.3
15.3

46.1
51.0
48.9
51.4
44.1
50.7
43.4
38.4
43.2
46.8
46.1
44.1
45.8

37.7
36.6
33.3
25.8
36.4
40.6
48.9
51.0
43.8
39.4
35.7
29.6
38.9

965
1,092
896
822
976
888
1,358
827
607
462
425
321
802

227
157
184
288
199
132
138
220
131
23
71
29
172

455
535
436
372
477
489
682
424
369
338
301
264
428

283
400
276
162
300
267
278
183
107
101
53
28
202

23.5
14.4
20.5
35.0
20.4
14.9
10.2
26.6
21.6
5.0
16.7
9.0
21.4

47.2
49.0
48.7
45.3
48.9
55.1
50.2
51.3
60.8
73.2
70.8
82.2
53.4

29.3
36.6
30.8
19.7
30.7
30.0
20.6
22.1
17.6
21.8
12.5
8.8
25.2

370
328
319
148
330
453
820
804
501
360
407
107
414

41
33
67
19
126
111
114
171
42
82
129
43
82

294
268
236
119
136
181
441
425
318
163
177
22
232

35
27
16
10
68
161
265
208
141
115
101
42
100

11.1
10.1
21.0
12.8
38.2
24.5
13.9
21.3
8.4
22.8
31.7
40.2
19.8

79.5
81.7
74.0
80.4
41.2
40.0
53.8
52.9
63.5
45.3
43.5
20.6
56.0

9.4
8.2
5.0
6.8
20.6
35.5
32.3
25.8
28.1
31.9
24.8
39.2
24.2

20
33
99
109
119
94
79

5
75
53
62
6
34

12
9
22
31
40
19

16
15
34
26
48
26

15.2
75.8
48.6
52.1
6.4
43.0

36.4
9.1
20.2
26.0
42.6
24.0

1969
January
February
March
April
May
June
July
August
September
October
November
December
Average (Estimated)
1970
January
February
March
April
May
June
July
August
September
October
November
December
Average
1971
January
February
March
April
May
June
July
August
September
October
November
December
Average
1972
January
February
March
April
May
JuneE/
Average (Estimated)

It Monthly averages of daily figures.
2/ New York and Chicago banks only.
]>/ Preliminary.




20

100.0

48.4
15.1
31.2
21.9
51.0
33.0

Table 11-a. Member Bank Borrowing in Relation to Required
Reserves, By Size of Bank and Federal Reserve District, January 1, 1969 through May 31, 1972
(Amounts in thousands of dollars')

Category

Number of Banks
FED
FED
Borrowers
Borrowers
Total
As Per Cent
(Average
(Average
of Total
during
during
period)
period)

Average Number
of Borrowing
Days during
Period

Average Amount
of Required
Reserves

Average Amount
Borrowed

Borrowing as Per
Cent of Required
Reserves

Size of
Bank
(millions of dollars)
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
Total

58
64
359
383
1,157
1,016
1,207
1,153
378
5,775

50
45
203
144
277
175
180
132
37
1,243

86.2
70.3
56.6
37.6
23.9
17.2
14.9
11.5
9.8
21.5

108
109
102
80
71
70
69
66
86
78

225,445
49,099
13,530
3,952
1,763
830
502
263
134
11,151

229
348
319
470
362
554
946
454
491
813
635
154
5,775

110
152
56
56
86
75
246
64
111
186
65
36
1,243

48.0
43.7
17.6
11.9
23.8
13.5

84
86
45
47
68
73
87

6,748
30,533
9,025
14,326
9,593
9,068
8,048
5,943
2,495
2,787
7,655
78,440
11,151

4,813
1,581
450
103
44
21
13
8
6
284

2.1
3.2
3.3
2.6
2.5
2.6
2.6
3.0
4.4
2.5

306

4.5
2.4

District
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total




26.0

14.1

80

22.9

57
103

23.4
21.5

84
78

22.6
10.2

l i

742
176
255
238
281

266

139

80

98
202
1,229
284

2.0
1.8

2.5
3.1
3.3
2.4
3.2
3.5

2.6
1.6

2.5

Table 10. Selected Portfolio Characteristics of Federal Reserve Member Banks,
Borrowers vs. Nonborrowers, By Federal Reserve District, 1969, 1970 and 1971

Federal Reserve District
Total

Number of Banks
FED
Non-FED
Borrowers
Borrowers

FED
Borrowers
as Per Cent
of Total

Loans
FED
Non-FED
Borrowers
Borrowers

Percentage of Total Assets
U.S. Gov't. Securities
Federal Funds Sold
FED
Non-FED
FED
Non-FED
Borrowers
Borrowers
Borrowers
Borrowers

Percentage of Total Liabilities
Total Borrowings
Federal Funds Purchased
TED
Non-FED
FED
Non-FED
Borrowers
Borrowers Borrowers
Borrowers

1969
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.

Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total

146
180
83
76
109
120
332
103
161
224
116
45

90
184
262
400
258
418
622
363
330
605
524
126

61.9
49.5
24.1
16.0
29.7
22.3
34.8
22.1
32.8
27.0
18.1
26.3

56.6
54.6
57.7
54.5
55.9
52.2
55.9
51.4
54.7
49.4
51.5
59.2

54.9
53.9
54.4
52.3
48.6
46.6
50.2
44.7
50.9
48.3
49.6
57.4

7.5
6.2
18.1
9.5
8.4
8.7
9.5
9.7
9.1
9.7
7.7
7.0

10.5
11.0
11.8
14.3
17.4
13.0
15.1
18.1
16.8
16.1
10.8
9.4

1.9
0.9
2.0
2.6
1.2
2.5
1.5
2.3
0.8
2.5
1.8
1.2

5.6
3.6
3.7
2.7
3.6
3.2
2.2
2.4
1.5
3.3
2.3
1.6

0.9

1.1

5,877

1,695

4,182

28.8

55.4

50.6

7.7

13.7

1.4

2.7

232
352
321
470
361
547
945
460
489
809
634
156

126
154
60
66
92
71
286
T8
130
211
77
40

106
198
261
404
269
476
659
382
359
598
557
116

54.3
43.8
18.7
14.0
25.5
13.0
30.3
17.0
26.5
26.1
12.2
25.6

53.7
52.6
53.2
50.4
53.5
49.7
53.5
49.6
53.2
47.1
49.6
55.2

53.5
53.8
55.3
50.5
47.9
45.3
48.0
45.2
51.0
48.2
46.5
54.6

8.1
6.3
8.6
9.7
8.1
8.9
9.6
9.9
10.1
10.4
7.0
8.1

10.2
10.0
10.1
14.4
14.3
11.9
14.4
15.1
15.8
12.9
10.6
9.2

1.7
l.l
3.2
4.0
2.3
4.4
2.0
3.7
5.7
5.4
2.7

5.8
2.5
3.0
2.8
4.8
4.2
4,4
4.6
2.4
4.3
4.3
3.0

8.0

12.5

2.3

3.6

236
364
345
476
36 7
538
954
466
491
829
640
171

*

0.3

5.2
4.5
4.4
4.1
2.4
3.9
3.4
4.6
4.1
3.6
5.5
4.5

0.7
0.7
0.3
0.7
2.5
0.5
0.4
0.3
2.9
1.5

0.9

0.4

4.2

1.2

0.4
1.1

*

0.2

0.7
0*9
1.8
1.2
0.7
1.5
1.8

0.6

1.2
0,6
0.6
1.9
1.2
0.4
2.1
0.8
0.5

0.1
*
0.6
*
*

0.9
0.1
*
0.1
1.1

1970
1. Boston
2. New York
3. Philadelphia
4. Cleveland
5. Richmond
6. Atlanta
7. Chicago
8. St. Louis
9. Minneapolis
10. Kansas City
11. Dallas
12. San Francisco
Total

5,776

1,391

4,385

24.1

52.7

49.5

1.1

0.1

0.4

6.1
4.1
5.3
4.5
2.3
4.4
5.1
7.1
4.9
4.0
9.2
4.3

0.7

0.1

4.7

0.6

0.1
0.4
0.8
1.2
0.1
0.5
0.4

0.8

0.2
0.1
*

0.1
0.2

oa
•
0.3
*

1.2
0.4
1.8
1.2

4

1971

1. Boston

227

2
I:
A
5
6
1
i
«

340
306
468
360
562
943
458
490

in*

New York
XuSlfphi.
rieveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chlc"go
is
Minneapolis

Citl

U . Dallas

796

C U y

38.3

53 8
53.8

55,5
52 1
52 I
'
50 9

649

i, i
13.1
M
8.6
10.1
19.6
'
13.9

« 8
55 8

147

266
423
293
505
758
427
422

18.5

49.9

47.5

24

609

J.8

47.3

46;4

900

4,830

15.7

52.7

87
126

40
45
67
57
185
31
68

140
214

53.1
49.7
53.8
45.7
53.0

12. San Francisco
Total

6.5
^
7.3
^
7

5

8.9
^
10.8
^
1Q 8

^

Source: Call Reports, December 31 of each year.
* Less than 0.05 per cent.




1.5
^
2 5

^

4.9
^
3.0
^
3<6

^

2 2

48.4
« 3

8
^

^
1 Q 9

^
5,730

2.0
^

+

*
^
*
#

0.1

#

#

^

0.1
0.2
QA

^

0 .3

0.2

2

^

^

^

0.4
0.3
^
0.6

*
^

0.6
0.6

3<3
4

0.2
^

^

^

6.5
^
7.2

0.6
? Q

1.3
fi1>9

4.0
^
6.3
^
6.0
5.6

6.4

1.4

^
2.8
^
2.6
4.1

Tsble 11-c. Member Bank Borrowing in Relation to Required
Reserves, By Size of Bank and Federal Reserve District, 1970
(Amounts in thousands of dollars)

Category

Number of Banks
FED
FED
Total
Borrowers
Borrowers
As Per Cent
of Total

Average Number
of Borrowing
Days during
Period

Average Amount
of Required
Reserves

Average Amount
Borrowed

Borrowing as Per
Cent of Required
Reserves

Si-e of
Bank,
(millions of dollars)
1,000 and over
500-1,000
1Q0-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
Total

56
59
349
367
1,129
980
1,233
1,205
398
5,776

51
44
226
167
318
204
205
138
38
4,385

91.0
74.6
64.8
45.5
28.2
20.8
16.6
11.5
9.6
24.1

43
36
38
32
35
38
41
46
49
38

234,670
50,918
13,661
3,913
1,743
824
503
274
142
14,874

6,650
1,751
580
130
71
37
26
18
10
478

2.8
3.4
4.3
3.3
4.1
4. 5
5.1
6.5
7.0
3.2

232
352
321
470
361
547
945
460
489
809
634
156
5,776

126
154
60
66
92
71
286
78
130
211
7.7
40

54.3
43.8
18.7
14.0
25.5
13.0
30.2
17.0
26.5
26.1
12.2
25.6
24.1

33
38
24
29
29
39
39
34
36
52
42
33
38

8,417
41,602
14,667
18,507
12,484
12,315
10,028
6,906
3,082
2,791
10,462
94,655
14,874

477
1,313
372
573
348
469
384
162
172
147
450
1,725
478

5.3
3.2
2.5
3.1
2.8
3.8
3.8
2.4
5.6
5.3
4.3
1.8
3.2

District
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
Sc. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total



1,391

Table 11 -b. Member Bank Borrowing in Relation to Required
Reserves, By Size of Bank and Federal Reserve District, 1969
(Amounts in thousands of dollars)

Category

Number of Banks
FED
FED
Total
Borrowers Borrowers
As Per Cent
of Total

Size of
Bank
(millions of dollars)
1,000 and over
49
500-1,000
55
100-500
336
50-100
336
20-50
1,063
942
12-20
7-12
1,260
3-7
1,353
Under 3
483
Total
5,877

Average Number
of Borrowing
Days during
Period

Average Amount
of Required
Reserves

Average Amount
Borrowed

Borrowing as Per
Cent of Required
Reserves

44
48
271
207
409
241
235
196
44
1,695

89.8
87.2
80.7
61.6
38.4
25.6
18.7
14.5
9.1
28.8

57
71
67
55
48
44
41
40
37
51

231,129
47,531
13,296
3,919
1,750
811
510
276
146
12,674

8,201
3,648
1,008
249
102
47
27
15
9
640

3.6
7.7
7.6
6.3
5.8
5.7
5.4
5.6
6.5
5.1

146
180
83
76
109
120
332
103
161
224
116
45
1,695

61.9
49.5
24.1
16.0
29.7
22.3
34.8
22.1
32.8
27.1
18.1
26.3
28.8

54
54
35
33
42
50
58
57
38
59
54
57
51

7,358
35,423
10,513
16,503
10,377
9,199
9,010
6,098
2,932
3,449
7,425
85,454
12,674

597
1,407
403
569
504
666
659
395
210
289
454
2,673
640

8.1
4.0
3.8
3.5
4.9
7.2
7.3
6.5
7.2
8.4
6.1
3.1
5.1

District
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total

236
364
345
476
367
538
954
466
491
829
640
171
5,877




Table 11-e. Member Bank Borrowing in Relation to Required
Reserves, By Size of Bank and Federal Reserve District,
January 1 through May 31, 1972
(Amounts in thousands of dollars)

Category

Number of Banks
FED
FED
Total
Borrowers
Borrowers
As Per Cent
of Total

Average Number
of Borrowing
Days during
Period

Average Amount
of Required
Reserves

Average Amount
Borrowed

Borrowing as Per
Cent of Required
Reserves

Size of
Bank
(millions of dollars)
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
Total

63
71
377
415
1,219
1,072
1,165
1,020
313
5,715

32
23
58
23
56
55
56
46
17
366

50.8
32.4
15.4
5.5
4.6
5.1
4.8
4.5
5.4
6.4

3
4
3
9
9
19
18
20
27
12

317,804
60,646
19,627
4,515
1,955
956
583
330
153
35,572

1,485
341
112
114
63
46
31
25
19
201

0.5
0.6
0.6
2.5
3.2
4.8
5.3
7.6
12.6
0.6

222
335
303
466
359
568
942
433
494
817
632
144
5,715

26
73
13
10
33
13
60
11
29
70
11
17
366

11.7
21.8
4.3
2.2
9.2
2.3
6.4
2.5
5.9
8.6
1.7
11.8
6.4

5
12
14
3
11
7
8
7
8
26
17
4
12

21,392
89,270
12,935
51,935
24,706
25,803
19,932
7,874
6,671
3,977
22,580
123,847
35,572

162
615
79
64
119
158
113
64
26
60
84
213
201

0.8
0.7
0.6
0.1
0.5
0.6
0.6
0.8
0.4
1.5
0.4
0.2
0.6

District
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total

Number of banks for size breakdown estimated from 1970-71 change.


Number of banks for Districts based on June 30, 1972 Call Report.


Table 11-d. Member Bank Borrowing In Relation to Required
Reserves, By Size of Bank and Federal Reserve District, 1971
(Amounts in thousands of dollars)

Category

1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
Total

Total

Number of Banks
FED
FED
Borrowers
Borrowers
as Per Cent
of Total

Average Number
of Borrowing
Days during
Period

Average Amount
of Required
Reserves

Average Amount
Borrowed

Borrowing as Per
Cent of Required
Reserves

1.2

63
70
376
414
1,216
1,069
1,170
1,034
318
5,730

53
44
155
107
185
111
133
81
31
900

84.1
62.9
41.2
25.9
15.2
10.4
11.4
7.8
9.8
15.7

18
24
22
24
22
29
29
36
45
26

261,639
r
*
55,008
15,210
4,301
1,971
879
532
287
152
21,755

3,046
1,068
334
109
49
32
18
15

227
340
306
468
360
562
943
458
490
796
633
147
5,730

87
126
40
45
67
57
185
31
68
147
24
23
900

38.3
37.1
13.1
9.6

25
23
14
14
23

12,111
51,804
17,961
22,899
17,948
13,692
14,633
6,499
3,866
2,437

376
768

3.1
1.5
1.7

277
297
401

1.2

49
27
46
342

0.8

11

319

1.9

2.2
2.5
2.5
3.7
3.4
5.2
7.1
1.5

District
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total




18.6
10.1
19.6

6.8
13.9
18.5
3.8
15.7
15.7

28
28
21
16
40
29
17
26

23,110
175,420
21,755

302

230

1,188

319

1.7
2.9

1.6

0.7
1.9
1.5
0.7
1.5

Table 12-b. Percentage Distribution of Member Banks* Required Reserves*
and Amount Borrowed* By Size of Bank and Federal Reserve District* 1969

Size of
Bank
lions of dollars)
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
Total

Total Number
of Banks

Number of
FED Borrowers

Required
Reserves

Amount
Borrowed

59.4
13.1
18.1
4.3
3.5
0.9
0.5
0.2

41.1
19.6
26.8
6.6
4.0
1.0
0.6
0.2

0.8
0.9
5.7
5.7
18.1
16.0
21.4
23.0
8.2
100.0

2.6
2.8
16.0
12.2
24.1
14.2
13.9
11.6
2.6
100.0

100.0

100.0

4.0
6.2
5.9
8.1
6.2
9.2
16.2
7.9
8.4
14.1
10.9
2.9
100.0

8.6
10.6
4.9
4.5
6.4
7.1
19.6
6.1
9.5
13.2
6.8
2.7
100.0

5.1
30.1
4.1
5.8
5.4
5.1
13.8
3.0
2.2
3.6
4.0
18.0
100.0

8.2
23.7
3.1
3.9
5.2
7.3
20.0
3.8
3.1
5.9
4.8
11.1
100.0

*

*

District
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total

* Less than 0.1 per cent.
Note:

Totals may not add to 100.0 dua to rounding.




Table 12-a. Percentage Distribution of Member Banks, Required Reserves,
and Amount Borrowed, By Size of Bank'and Federal Reserve District,
January 1, 1969 through May 31, 1972

Size of
Total Number
of Banks
Bank
Llions of dollars)(Average during
period)
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
Total

Number of
FED Borrowers

Required
Reserves

Amount
Borrowed

1.0
1.1
6.2
6.6
20.0
17.6
20.9
20.0
6.6
100.0

2.9
3.1
14.9
12.7
24.3
15.0
15.1
9.6
2.5
100.0

57.9
13.6
18.1
4.5
3.8
1.1
0.7
0.2
*
100.0

48.6
17.3
23.6
4.6
3.8
1.1
0.7
0.3
0.1
100.0

4.0
6.0
5.5
8.1
6.3
9.6
16.4
7.9
8.5
14.1
11.0
2.7
100.0

8.0
10.7
5.5
5.0
6.4
6.6
19.0
5.5
9.8
14.6
6. 5
2.5
100.0

4.9
29.2
4.4
6.5
5.5
5.4
13.7
2.9
2.2
3.6
4.4
17.2
100.0

8.7
27.9
3.4
4.5
5.4
6.6
17.9
2.7
2.8
5.0
4.6
10.6
100.0

District
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total

* Less than 0.1 per cent.
Note:

Totals may not add to 100.0 due to rounding.




Table 12-d. Percentage Distribution of Member Banks, Required Reserves,
and Amount Borrowed, By Size of Bank and Federal Reserve District, 1971

Size of
Total Number
Bank
of Banks
(millions of dollars)
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
Total

Number of
FED Borrowers

Required
Reserves
70.4
12.3
12.1
2.4
1.9
0.5
0.4
0.1

Amount
Borrowed

1.1
1.2
6.6
7.2
21.2
18.7
20.4
18.0
5.6
100.0

5.9
4.9
17.2
11.9
20.6
12.3
14.8
9.0
3.4
100.0

100.0

55.9
16.3
18.0
4.1
3.2
1.2
0.8
0.4
0.1
100.0

4.0
5.9
5.3
8.2
6.3
9.8
16.5
8.0
8.6
13.9
11.1
2.6
100.0

9.7
14.0
4.4
5.0
7.4
6.3
20.6
3.4
7.6
16.3
2.7
2.6
100.0

5.4
34.5
3.7
5.2
6.1
4.0
13.7
1.0
1.3
1.8
2.8
20.5
100.0

11.5
34.8
4.2
4.3
6.9
7.9
14.6
0.5
0.6
2.3
2.8
9.5
100.0

*

District
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total

*Less

than 0.1 per cent.

Note:

Totals may not add to 100.0 due to rounding.




Table 12-c. Percentage Distribution of Member Banks, Required Reserves,
and Amount Borrowed* By Size of Bank and Federal Reserve District, 1970

Size of
Bank
(millions of dollars)
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
Total

Number of
FED Borrowers

Required
Reserves

Amount
Borrowed

1.0
1.0
6.0
6.4
19.6
17.0
21.4
20.9
6.9
100.0

3.7
3.2
16.3
12.0
22.9
14.7
14.7
9.9
2.7
100.0

63.7
12.9
15.8
3.5
2.8
0.8
0.5
0.1
100.0

56.5
13.9
20.9
3.6
3.5
1.1
0.1
0.3
0.1
100.0

4.0
6.1
5.6
8.1
6.3
9.5
16.4
8.0
8.5
14.0
11.0
2.7
100.0

9.1
11.1
4.3
4.7
6.6
5.1
20.6
5.6
9.4
15.2
5.5
2.9
100.0

5.1
31.1
4.5
6.0
5.7
4.2
13.6
2.6
1.9
2.9
3.9
18.5
100.0

8.4
30.5
3.6
5.8
4.9
5.0
16.2
1.9
3.3
4.7
5.3
10.5
100.0

Total Number
of Banks

*

District
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total

* Less than 0.1 per cent.
Note:

Totals may not add to 100.0 due to rounding.




Table 13. Selected Assets of Weekly Reporting Member Banks,
Borrowers vs. Nonborrovers, By Sire of Bank, 1969, 1970 and 1971

Size of Deposits
(millions of dollars)

Number of Banks
FED
Non-FED
Total
Borrowers Borrower

FED
Borrowing
as
Per Cent
of Total

Total Loans
FED
Non-FED
Borrowers Borrowers

Percentage of Total Assets
C&I Loans
U.S. Gov*t Securities U.S. Treasury Bills
FED
FED
Non-FED
Non-FED
Non-FED
FEE
Borrowers Borrowers Borrowers Borrowers Borrowers Borrowers

Federal Funds Sold
FED
Non-FED
Borrowers Borrowers

1969
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
Total

43
54
218
315

39
47
183
269

4
7
35
46

90.7

48
55
210
313

43
42
145
230

56
63
192
311

47
47
129
223

27.0

8.8

1.0

8.9
14.2

0.7
0.5

83.9
85.4

55.2
56.1
54.0
55.1

52.4
57.3
50.7
53.0

29.0
22.2
19.0

26.0

15.2
20.7

10.0

7.4

11.0

5
13
65
83

89.6
76.4
69.1
73.5

55.0
55.5
53.7
54.9

56.7
55.4
50.4
53.4

28.2
21.7
18.3
25.7

25.0
20.6
18.3
20.6

6.9
7.8
9.4
7.4

8.2
8.4
11.1
9.6

9
16
63
88

83.9
74.6
67.2
71.7

52.9
52.8
51.0
52.6

53.3
53.1
48.2
51.3

26.1

22.9

7.1
8.0
9.3
7.6

7.1
8.7
10.8
8.9

87.0

21.6

6.5
7.8

1.4

0.2

2.0
1.6
1.9
1.9

4.1
0.9
2.5

0.8

0.9
0.9

1.3
0.8
0.7

1.1
0.5
0.9

2.0
2.5
2.6
2.2

4.0
2.2
3.6
3.3

1.2

1.1

0.B
1.1
1.1

0.8
1.4
1.1

2.3
3.0
2.9
2.5

4.0
3.0
3.5
3.6

2.6

1970
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
Total

1.1

0.8

1971
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
Total

Source:
Note:

Weekly Reporting Banks Series.

(Annual Averages)

There are 330 banks in the Weekly Reporting sample.




20.6

17.4
24.0

20.8

17.2
20.2

Table 12-e. Percentage Distribution of Member Banks, Required Reserves,
and Amount Borrowed, By Size of Bank and Federal Reserve District,
January 1 through May 31, 1972
Size of
Total Number
Bank
of Banks
(millions of dollars)
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
50-100
20-50
12-20
7-12
3-7
Under 3
Total

Number of
FED Borrowers

Required
Reserves

Amount
Borrowed

78.1
10.7
8.7
0.8
0.8
0.4
0.3
0.1

1.1
1.2
6.6
7.3
21.3
18.8
20.4
17.9
5.5
100.0

8.7
6.3
15.9
6.3
15.3
15.0
15.3
12.6
4.7
100.0

100.0

64.4
10.6
8.8
3.6
4.8
3.4
2.4
1.6
0.4
100.0

3.9
5.9
5.3
8.2
6.3
9.9
16.5
7.6
8.6
14.3
11.1
2.5
100.0

7.1
20.0
3.6
2.7
9.0
3.6
16.4
3.0
7.9
19.1
3.0
4.6
100.0

4.3
50.0
1.3
4.0
6.3
2.7
9.2
0.7
1.5
2.1
1.9
16.2
100.0

5.7
60.9
1.4
0.9
5.3
2.8
9.2
1.0
1.0
5.7
1.3
4.9
100.0

*

District
Boston
New York
Philadelphia
Cleveland
Richmond
Atlanta
Chicago
St. Louis
Minneapolis
Kansas City
Dallas
San Francisco
Total

* Less than 0.1 per cent.
Note:

Totals may not add to 100.0 due to rounding.




Page 1

Appendix Table I
Federal Reserve
Board Action

1. January 15, 1953

2. February 4, 1954

Rate
Change
(Per
Cent)
+1/4

-1/4

Lead Banks
Number of Number of
Banks
Days
4

Coincident
Banks
Number of
Banks

Lag Banks
Number of Number of
Days
Banks
4
2
2

2
1
1
1
1

1-3/4
6

1
3, April 13, 1954

5
U
2
3

-1/4

1
1
1
2
4 . April 13, 1955

1
U

+1/4

6. August 25, 1955

7
5

1

1
1

2
8
2-1/4

10

+1/4

5

1
1

8. April 12, 1956

+1/4

+1/4

1-3/4
7
8
15

1
1
1

7. November 17, 1955

10

13
15
31
37

1

+1/2

6
2
3

0

3

10

1
1
1

2-1/4
4
7
13
14
15
18
4
5

+1/4

7

6

+1/2

0

1

4

4
7

8
3

1
1
1

2
11. November 14, 1957
Divided Board
Yes
4
No
1
12. January 21, 1958

Divided Board
Yes
No




-1/2

8

1
3
3

-1/4

3

1
1

10. August 8, 1957

2-3/4

3

+1/2

1

2-1/2

1

7
3

9. August 23, 1956

1-1/2

2
9

1

1
+1/4

4
7

7
2
5. August 3, 1955

New Rate
Level
(Per Cent)

1
10
6
2

1
1

3-1/2

4
6
8
11
14
4
7
13
15
2-3/4
2
6
16
23

Table 14. Selected Liabilities of Weekly Reporting Member Bank*,
Borrowers vs. Nonborrowers, By Size of Bank, 1969, 1970, and 1971

FED
Borrowers

Non-FED
Borrowers

FED
Borrowing
as
Per Cent
of Total

39
47
183
269

4
7
35
46

90.7
87.0
83.9
85.4

0.2
0.5
0.4
0.3

1.0
1.2
0.6
1.0

2.3
0.1
0.4
0.9

5
13
65
83

89.6
76.4
69.1
73.5

0.2
0.2
0.2
0.2

0.8

313

43
42
145
230

1.0
0.4
0.7

56
63
192
311

47
47
129
223

16
63
88

9

83.9
74.6
67.2
71.7

0.2

0.3
0.5
0.3
0.3

Number of Banks
Size of Deposits
(millions of dollars)

Total

FED Borrowings
Borrowers

Other Borrowings
Non-FED
FED
Borrowers Borrowers

Percentage of Total Liabilities
Federal Funds Purchased Total CD's (over $100,000) CD's issued to others (over $100.0001
FED
Non-FED
Non-FED
FED
FED
Non-FED
Borrowers Borrowers
Borrowers
Borrowers Borrowers
Borrowers

1969
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
Total

43
54
218

315

2.0

3.6
5.6

11.7
2.3
2.1
5.3

3.9
4.9
4.8
4.2

4.7
5.1
5.1
5.0

2.0
1.8
2.0

0.7
1.9
1.5
1.4

1.2
0.4
0.3
0.5

6.6
6.6
3.9
6.1

9.0
3.3
4.0
5.0

6.2
6.2
5.7
6.1

7.2
7.6
6.7
7.1

3.0
2.5
2.3
2.8

3.2
3.3
2.4
2.9

0.2
0.5
0.2
0.3

7.3
7.7
3.9
6.8

9.9
4.8
3.9
6.3

10.2
9.2
6.8
9.6

9.8
10.6
7.8
9.3

3.7
4.0
3.0
3.7

4.6
4.0
3.3
4.0

6.0

6.2

1970
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
Total

48
55
210

1971
1,000 and over
500-1,000
100-500
Total

Source: Weekly Reporting Banks Series.

(Annual Averages)

Note: There are 330 banks in the Weekly Reporting sample.




0.1
0.1
0.2

Page 3

Appendix Table I (continued)
Federal Reserve
Board Action

Rate
Change
(Per
Cent)

26. November 18, 1967

+1/2

27- March 14, 1968

+1/2

Lead Banks
Number of Number of
Banks
Days

Coincident
Banks
Number of
Banks

Lag Banks
Number of
Number of
Banks
Days
7
3
3

New Rate
Level
(Per Cent)

4-1/2

1
2

1
1
28* April 18, 1968

6

+1/2

5-1/2

1
29. August 15, 1968

5
U

-1/4

5-1/4

1

30. December 17, 1968

31. April 3, 1969

+1/4

+1/2

7
4
3
8
3

1
32. November 10, 1970

-1/4

2
2
2

1
1
33. November 30, 1970

-1/4

2

1
34. January 1, 1971

-1/4

36. February 12, 1971

-1/4

3

-1/4

1
1
1
10
1
1
1
1
6

37. July 15, 1971

38. November 10, 1971

+1/4

-1/4

1
1
3

1
2
39. December 10, 1971

Note:

-1/4

3
3

5-1/2

21
16
6

1
4
8

1
0
14
6
5
3

3

1
1
1
35. January 18, 1971

5
4

5

1
1

4
2
4
2
2

24
8

6
4
2
7
3

1
3

5-3/4
2
3
5-1/2
3
9
10

2

5-1/4

1
1

1
6
7
4
3

1
2
3

2
3
10

1

4-3/4

22
15
8
4

1
8
3
5
5

5

1
7

5
1
1

2
8

1

4-3/4

8
4
2
2

6
12
13

4-1/2

"Lead Banks" Include those Federal Reserve Banks whose Boards proposed discount
rate changes at least one (1) day prior to the date on which the Federal Reserve
Board approved a rate change. "Coincident Banks'1 are those whose Boards acted on
the same day the Federal Reserve Board approved a rate change. "Lag Banks" include
those whose Boards acted at least one (1) day after the Federal Reserve Board
approved a rate change.




Appendix Table I (continued)
Federal Reserve
Board Action

13. ttarch 6, 1958

Rate
Change
(Per
Cent)
-1/2

-3/4
14. April 17, 1958

15. August 14, 1958

16. October 23, 1958

17. March 5, 1959

18. Hay 28, 1959

-1/2

+1/4

21. August 11, 1960

22. July 16, 1963
Divided Board
Yes
3

Ifo

+1/2

+1/2

-1/2

-1/2

+1/2

1

23. November 23, 1964
Divided Board
Yes
5
No
1
24. December 3, 1965
Divided Board
Yes
4
No
3

+1/2

25. April 6, 1967

-1/2




0
0

1
1

+1/2

19. September 10, 1959 +1/2

20. June 2, 1960

Lead Banks
Number of Number of
Banks
Days

0

0

0

0

0

Coincident
Banks
Number of
Banks

Page 2

Lag Banks
Number of
Number
Banks
Days
8
1
1
5
1
1
1
7
2
3
1
1
11
I
1
1
2
4
1
1
7
1
1
1
2
1
1
8
1
1
4
2
7
2
2
1
2
4
3
1
10
8
1
1
8
1
1
3
1
1
1
5
3
1
1
7
1
4
2

New Rate
Level

2-1/4
1
4
7
14
2-/4
6
1-3/4
4
7
13
21
7
11
14
21
28
35
39
2-1/2
4
6
7
11
13
14
4
6
7
8
3-1/2
4
7
13
14
4
1
7
3-1/2
7
8
11
1
4
7
10
21
28
3-1/2
2
7
9
1
2
4
4-1/2

+1/2
10
2
7
1

3
6
7

2
1
1

1
7