View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
Thursday, October 25, 1973
8:00 p . m . E.D.T.




INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MARKETS
and the
FINANCING OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
Paper by
Andrew F c Brimmer
Member
Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System
Presented as the
Inaugural Lecture
in the
Samuel Z . Westerfield, J r « , Distinguished Lecture Series
Sponsored Jointly By
Westerfield Advisory Committee
African-American Scholars Council
and the
School of Business Administration
Atlanta University

Atlanta, Georgia
October 25, 1973

INTERNATIONAL CAPITAL MARKETS
and the
FINANCING OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
by
Andrew F 0 Brimmer*
A striking change has occurred in recent years in the sources
of funds available to finance economic development in those countries
still struggling to modernize their economies:

a significant number of

these nations have been able to raise a record amount of capital on terms
which were previously available to only the most creditworthy borrowers
normally found only in the most advanced industrial countries 0

Partly

reflecting these changed circumstances, private capital has assumed a
much more important role in developing countries than was thought possible
only a few years ago*
The improved market standing and the increased ability to borrow
of many of the less developed countries (LDC's) have clearly brought
numerous benefits«
important of these c

The ready availability of funds is obviously the most
Greater flexibility in project planning and the

^Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
I am grateful to several members of the Board's staff for assistance
in the preparation of this paper. M r . Rodney H . M i l l s , J r c , and M r s . Ruth
Robinson compiled much of the statistics on Euro-currency borrowings, and
M r . Mills also helped trace recent changes in lending practices by Eurocurrency banks 0 M r . Yves Maroni helped with the analysis of capital flows
and uses of funds by developing countries 0 M r . Reed J . Irvine assisted
with the assessment of the implications of increased Euro-currency borrowing
by developing countries.
However, while I am grateful for the staff's assistance, the views
expressed here are my own--and should not be attributed to the staff nor to
my colleagues on the Board.




-2freedom from restraints (such as competitive bidding) imposed by multilateral lending institutions have also been hailed by LDC borrowers 0
On the other hand, the greatly expanded participation by the newcomers
in the Euro-currency markets also raises a number of questions:
!

--Why are so many L D C s able and willing to borrow
in the Euro-currency and Euro-bond m a r k e t s — w h e n it
appears that they might obtain financing on more
advantageous terms from the international lending
institutions, if not under the bilateral aid programs
conducted by some of the advanced countries?
--What are the implications of these recent international
capital market developments, and what are the prospects
for the future?
--How dependable as sources of financing for economic
development are the Euro-currency and Euro-bond
markets likely to be?
--Are there inherent in the recent evolution of these
markets excessive risks for the Euro-currency banks
which extend the loans? For the developing countries
which have come to rely so heavily on such a highly
volatile source of funds?
These questions are examined in this paper.

To place these recent

developments in perspective, long-term trends in capital flows to developing
countries are summarized in the next section.
Trends in Capital Flows to Developing Countries
f

It has long been generally agreed that the L D C s must rely
primarily on their own savings to finance their economic development.
B u t , it has also been agreed that foreign capital has an essential role
to play in raising investment in those countries to a more adequate level.




-3Following the Second World W a r , it was believed that foreign capital
was unlikely to be available to the less developed countries from
private sources in sufficient amounts to finance the wide range of
projects necessary to launch them on the road to self sustaining
growtho

Consequently, steps were taken to mobilize capital through

official channels.

The International Bank for Reconstruction and

Development (the World Bank) was organized.

It was later expanded

by the addition of two sister institutions--the International Finance
Corporatian (IFC) and the International Development Association (IDA).
Regional development lending institutions were created to serve specific
areas — the Inter-American Development Bank (IDB) for Latin America, the
Asian Development Bank (ADB) for Asia, and the African Development Bank
(AfDB) for Africa e

National governments in the advanced countries undertook

to provide economic aid to the less developed countries under bilateral programs.
In 1962, the LDC's received about $8.4 billion of financial
resources in the form of net official and private capital transfers from
the 16 countries belonging to the Development Assistance Committee (DAC)
1/
of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) a
Tables 1 and 2, attached) 0

(See

Just over $ 4 0 3 billion (about half of the total

flows) originated in the United States in 1962 a
$ 1 0 4 billion, or one-sixth of the total.

France was second--supplying
f

Net official flows to the L D C s

amounted to $6.0 billion in 1962 representing 70 per cent of the total.
f

1/ The DAC statistics refer to the amount provided to the L D C s and the
multilateral development agencies. For the sake of simplicity in exposition,
it is assumed that the amounts received by these agencies are equal to the
amounts which they in turn provided to the LDC's.




-4The United States supplied approximately $3.5 billion of this amount, or
nearly three-fifths of all official transfers to developing countries.
Nearly 90 per cent of the official capital was for development assistance.
France provided $977 million in the form of official transfers—accounting
for just over one-sixth of the total.
in 1962 amounted to $2.5 billion.

Private capital flows to the LDC's

Approximately one-third of this sum

($819 million) came from the United States.

In this case France was

again in second p l a c e — a c c o u n t i n g for $418 million, also equal to onesixth of total private flows.
Between 1962 and 1972, the volume of capital flows from DAC
1

countries to LDC s more than doubled — climbing from $8.4 billion to
$19.4 billion.

The United States remained in first place as a source

of funds, but its relative position declined substantially.

Of the total

flows, $7.4 b i l l i o n — o r 38 per c e n t — o r i g i n a t e d in the United States.
A decade earlier, the U 0 S . accounted for just over half of the total.
By 1972, Japan had replaced France as the second most important
supplier of capital to LDC's.

Last year, Japan provided $ 2 0 7 billion

to these countries—representing one-seventh of the total.

The United

States' share of official transfers and of development assistance was
of roughly the same magnitude as its share of total capital flows in
1 9 7 2 — 3 5 per cent; 39 per cent, and 38 per cent, respectively.

In

contrast, Japan supplied 14 per cent of total capital flows and 14.5
per cent of official t r a n s f e r s — b u t only 7.1 per cent of the official
transfers for development assistance 0




-5During the decade 1962-72, private capital flows to the
developing countries more than t r i p l e d — r i s i n g from $ 2 0 5 billion in
1962 to $9.3 billion in 1972.

Private capital represented just over

one-quarter of total flows in 1962, but the proportion had risen to
almost one-half a decade later.

The United States private capital

amounted to $3.8 b i l l i o n — o r two-fifths of all private flows to L D C ' s .
In 1962, the U . S . had accounted for about one-third of the total.
Moreover, slightly more than half of all capital flows from the U . S .
to LDC's in 1972 arose from private s o u r c e s — i n contrast to only onefifth in 1962.

In the case of no other major country did such a
f

dramatic shift occur in the composition of capital flows to L D C s »
except for Japan, which was a relatively small donor in 1962.

In the

United Kingdom the direction of change was the same, but the extent
of the shift was less striking.

On the other hand, several industrial

countries (especially Canada, Denmark, Italy, Sweden and Switzerland),
provided proportionately less through private c h a n n e l s — a n d more
through official m e a n s — i n 1972 than they did a decade earlier.
Between 1962 and 1972, the net flow of official and private
financial resources from the advanced DAC countries to LDC's declined
slightly in relation to the gross national product (GNP) of the donor
countries.

In 1962, the proportion was .80 per cent of the DAC group's GNP,

and in 1972 it was .77 per cent.

(See Table 3.)

The major share of this

decline was accounted for by the United S t a t e s — w h e r e capital transfers
to LDC's as a percentage of GNP decreased from .76 per cent in 1962




-6to .64 per cent in 1972.

In the case of France, Italy and Switzerland

also total capital flows to developing countries declined in relation
to G N P .

All other countries m a i n t a i n e d — o r raised--the proportion of

GNP transferred to LDC's.

If the four countries which recorded a

decline had maintained in 1972 the same capital f l o w — G N P ratio that pref

vailed in 1962, the L D C s would have received about $3.8 billion (or onefifth) more than they actually received 0

The United States alone would

have supplied a total of $8,733 m i l l i o n — o r $1,379 million more than it
actually provided.

France would have supplied an additional $1,603 million;

Italy $504 million, and Switzerland $277 million more than it actually
supplied.
The decrease in official capital transfers in relation to DAC
1

countries GNP was particularly dramatic.

In fact, for the group as a

whole, all of the net decline centered in this category,,

For all DAC

f

countries combined, official capital supplied to L D C s decreased from
0

57 per cent of GNP in 1962 to .40 per cent in 1972.

Six countries (Austria,

France, Germany, Italy, United Kingdom, and the United States) accounted
for the net decline,.

If the 1962 official c a p i t a l — G N P ratios for these

countries had been maintained, the LDC's would have received in 1972 an
additional $5,306.6 million 0

The United States would have provided

$3,465.0 million more to L D C ' s .
would have been:

For other countries, the additions

France, $ l , 2 2 4 e l million; Germany, $387.9 million; United

Kingdom, $167.5 million; Italy $39.2 million, and Austria $22.9 million.




-7Onthe other h a n d , the countries which raised their official capitalGNP ratios

between 1962 and 1972 were responsible for an additional

$997o5 million in official transfers above the amount they would have
supplied had the 1962 ratios been maintained.

Combining these results,
f

if all the DAC countries had provided official capital to the L D C s and
the multilateral agencies in 1972 in the same proportion to their GNP
as in 1962, the amount transferred would have been $4,309.1 million
more than it actually w a s .
To a considerable extent, however, the short-fall in official
1

transfers to L D C s (measured by the decline in the official capital-GNP
ratio) was made up by the substantial rise in private capital flows 0
For all DAC countries, the private capital-GNP fraction climbed from
.23 per cent in 1962 to .37 per cent in 1972.

Reflecting this increase, the

!

L D C s received $3.5 billion more in 1972 than they would have if the
1962 ratio had prevailed.

Nine countries accounted for an additional

$4,221.5 m i l l i o n — w h i c h was partly offset by a short-fall of $738.8 million
attributable to those countries whose private c a p i t a l — G N P ratio
declined or remained unchanged between 1962 and 1972.
lifted this ratio

Countries which

provided additional amounts as follows:

United States,

$2,200.3 million; Japan, $672.9 million; United Kingdom, $446.0 million;
Germany, $343.2 million; Canada, $262.4 million; Netherlands, $168.9
million; B e l g i u m , $55,9 million; Austria, $47.2 million, and Sweden,
$24.7 million.




-ff-

In summary, the foregoing figures tell an important story:
the decline in the official capital-GNP ratio of DAC countries between
1962 and 1972 resulted

in LDC's receiving $4.3 billion less than they

would have gotten if the ratio had remained constant.

Over the same

period, the rise in the private c a p i t a l — G N P ratio provided the LDC's
with $3.5 billion more than they otherwise would have received.

So,

the relative rise in private capital flows held the short-fall in total
capital flows to only $826.4 m i l l i o n — u s i n g the 1962 ratio as a measuring
rod.

In the case of the United States alone, the decline in the official

capital-GNP ratio cut the volume of these flows by $3.5 billion.

On

the other h a n d , the rise in private capital in relation to GNP lifted
such flows by $2.1 billion above what they otherwise would have b e e n .
T h u s , the net effect of the relative expansion in private capital was
to keep the short-fall in total U . S . capital flows to LDC's in 1972 in
the neighborhood of $1.4 b i l l i o n — a g a i n using the 1962 ratio as a benchmark.
Changing Composition of Private Capital Flows
Not only has the volume of private long-term capital flows to
LDC's expanded greatly but the composition of such flows has also changed
appreciably.

Three principal types of flows can be identified in the

available OECD statistics:
export financing.

portfolio investment, direct investment, and

(See Table 4.)

The OECD figures show that, between

1960 and 1970, the flow of portfolio capital rose by roughly 50 per cent-from $830 million in 1960 to $1,250 million in 1970.




During the same

-9period, the flow of direct investment capital d o u b l e d — r i s i n g from
$1,770 million to $3,560 million.

Export credits quadrupled--from

$550 million in 1960 to $2,210 million in 1970.

Export financing

accounted for about 30 per cent of the $7,880 million in total
private capital flows from the advanced countries to the LDC's in
1 9 7 0 — u p from roughly 17 per cent a decade earlier.

The share of

direct investment had shrunk to 50 per cent from 56 per cent, and
the share of portfolio investment had declined to 18 per cent from
26 per cent.
The rapid growth of export credits occurred even though the
terms on such credits are relatively hard, and the short maturities
as well as the comparatively high interest rates which they generally
entail inevitably burden the borrowing countries with increasingly
serious debt servicing problems.

For this reason, a number of the

less developed countries have taken deliberate steps to hold down
the growth of this type of indebtedness.

These moves have often been

made as part of a comprehensive set of policies supported by standby
agreements with the International Monetary Fund.

But an even more important development has occurred since
1970.

There has been an upsurge in portfolio investment, especially

that part which flows directly from the advanced countries to the LDC's.
The indirect flows channeled through the private bond flotations of the
multilateral lending institutions have also gone up.




However, the direct

-10bilateral flows tripled between 1970 and 1972, and the volume probablycontinued to expand rapidly in 1973.

The preliminary OECD figures for

1972 place the total bilateral portfolio investment flows to the less
developed countries at about $2.3 billion, representing about 25 per
cent of the total private flow to these countries in that year.
Clearly, a part of the increase in the dollar size of the
capital flows between 1970 and 1972 reflects the exchange rate changes
which have occurred since the middle of 1971.

The available information

does not permit the necessary correction to be made.
that the upsurge of portfolio investment was larger

But it is clear
than any change

that occurred with respect to direct investment or export credits.
Euro-Currency Market Borrowing by Developing Countries
More important still is the fact that there has been a
dramatic rise in borrowings by the less developed countries in the
Euro-currency and Euro-bond markets.

These borrowings are only

partially reflected in the statistics of the OECD, since there is
no comprehensive system for reporting them.

But the evidence from

other sources is striking.
According to the Bank for International Settlements, Eurocurrency claims on the LDC's reported by banks in eight Western European
countries increased by $8.0 billion in 1972.

This includes both short-

term and long-term claims--i.e., those with a maturity of less than
one year and those with a maturity of more than one year, respectively.




-11Total Euro-currency claims of banks in the eight reporting Western
European countries rose by the amounts indicated in each of the last
three years:
billion.

1970, $19.5 billion; 1971, $22.2. billion; 1972, $31.7
f

Thus, the L D C s share of the total increase climbed from

one-sixth in 1970 to one-quarter in 1971 and 1972.
All indications are that these claims have increased even
more rapidly so far in 1973.

Since the great bulk of these Euro-currency

claims was denominated in dollars, there is little reason to adjust
the data reported in dollars for exchange rate changes since mid-1971.
The figures just cited are useful indicators of trends, but
they are imperfect in two respects.

On the one hand, they do not include

medium- and long-term Euro-currency credits extended by banks in Germany,
the Netherlands, and France.

Nor do they include Euro-currency credits,

of whatever maturity, extended by banks in Japan and Canada.

On the other

hand, they include credits to Australia, New Zealand, and South Africa,
which cannot be regarded as "less developed countries
in this paper.

11

in the sense used

Nevertheless, the order of magnitude of the flows which

they reflect is sizable.

By comparison, the flow of official capital

from 16 OECD countries to the less developed countries and to the multilateral lending institutions totaled $10.1 billion in 1972.
The statistics showing claims of the Euro-banks on the less
developed countries do not provide a breakdown between short-term and
long-term claims.




But there is strong evidence that the greater part

-12of the total is in short-term claims.

At the same time, from other

sources, it is clear that claims of more than one year have increased
especially rapidly in the last two or three years.

A compilation of

such credits places the total new credits announced in 1972 at about
$3 billion, up from about $1 billion in 1971.

(See Table 5.)

In the

first half of 1973, announcements of new Euro-currency credits to the
f

L D C s with a maturity of more than one year totaled nearly $2.4 billion-an annual rate more than 50 per cent higher than that recorded in 1972.
In addition to these Euro-currency borrowings, in 1972, twelve
of the less developed countries sold bonds in the Euro-bond markets for
a total of over $490 million.

(See Table 6.)

Only four less developed

countries had sold bonds in the Euro-bond markets in 1971 for a total
of only $71 million, and only five had done so in 1970 for a total of
$128 million.

Moreover, as recently as 1969, only those few LDG's which

had made the most progress in economic development (e.g., Brazil, Mexico,
Iran, and Netherlands Antilles) were borrowing in the Euro-bond market.
Since then, participation has broadened significantly.
The importance of the borrowings by the LDC's in the Euro-currency
markets is best shown in the statistics relating to their share of total longterm loans extended.

For example, in 1971, total long-term Euro-currency

loans amounted to $4.1 billion, and $985 million went to LDC's.

In 1972,

the total rose to $7.8 billion, and loans to LDC's jumped to $3.1 billion.
S o , the LDC's share of the total climbed from one-quarter in 1971 to
two-fifths in 1972.




Estimates of the total volume of long-term credits

-13advanced so far in 1973 are not available.

However, Euro-currency

credits extended to LDC's were $2.4 billion during the first six
months of the year.

These figures suggest that LDC's share of the

market will probably increase further during the course of this year.
In fact, one experienced market participant has estimated that the
borrowings of the less developed countries in the Euro-currency markets
in 1973 will probably exceed the total Euro-currency loans to such
countries outstanding at the end of 1971.
Probably, some of the Euro-currency borrowings by the less
developed countries subsitituted for financing from other sources, such
as suppliers

1

credits.

The fact that the flow of suppliers

1

credits to

these countries in 1972 was one-third smaller than in 1971 suggests that,
in part, the borrowers were shifting some of their financing to the Eurocurrency markets.

Also in this category are Euro-currency loans to re-

structure debts, which may have substituted for more traditional refinancing
operations.

But a part of the financing was undoubtedly for projects or

purposes which w o u l d not have been eligible for loans from more traditional
sources.

This is especially true of loans for which the traditional lenders

(such as the international lending institutions) would have imposed conditions unacceptable to the borrowers, or which the borrowers could not meet.
Moreover, insofar as projects were financed promptly through Euro-currency
l o a n s — i n s t e a d of being delayed for protracted periods for study b y — a n d
negotiation w i t h — t h e international lending institutions, the financing
provided by the Euro-currency markets added to the capital flows that




-14would otherwise have occurred.

However, it is not possible to measure

statistically either the extent of the substitution or the magnitude
of the additionality of the capital flows attributable to the Eurocurrency borrowings of the less developed countries.
Among the less developed countries, the heaviest recipients
of Euro-currency loans in 1972 were Brazil, Mexico, Iran, Algeria,
Venezuela, Argentina, and Peru--in that order.

These seven countries

together borrowed nearly $2.5 billion in this form or 81 per cent of
the total of $3.1 billion borrowed by all of the less developed countries.
(Table 5).

The balance went to eighteen other countries.

In the first

half of 1973, Algeria alone accounted for one-third of the total amount
borrowed in this form by the less developed countries while five other
countries (Brazil, Iran, Indonesia, Peru, and Mexico) accounted for
another 40 per cent.

Thirteen other countries shared the rest.

Uses of Euro-Currency Loans
Available information indicates that most of the Euro-currency
loans to less developed countries were obtained by borrowers in the public
sector of these countries.

The list of borrowers includes national, state,

and local governments, central banks, state-owned development and commercial banks, and public entities in the fields of transportation, telecommunications, electric power generation and distribution, petroleum and
natural gas, and mining.

Private sector borrowers include basic industries

such as steel, aluminum, and cement, as well as private banks.

Of course,

a part of the resources raised by the official banks was intended to finance
private sector activities.




-15National governments and central banks borrowed in connection
with economic stabilization programs, to bolster the balance of payments,
and to finance economic development

projects.

was also a purpose for some of the borrowings.

General budget support
The development projects

involved included road building; construction of airports, subways, and
shipyards;

purchases of equipment for airlines, urban transportation,

shipping lines, and telecommunication systems; construction of facilities
to produce and transmit electric power, to produce steel, liquified
natural gas, and fertilizer; expansion of petroleum and copper production;
construction of government buildings and tourist hotels, etc.

In many

cases, the purpose of the borrowing is not known, while in others it is
known only in general terms--such as when the borrower is a bank which
is planning to re-lend the funds locally, presumably for the whole range
of purposes which it normally finances.

In this manner (and also through

borrowings obtained directly in the Euro-currency markets by the enterprises concerned), a part of the resources raised was used to provide
working capital to industry and commerce.

Some of the borrowings were

intended to restructure debts.
Bank Competition and the Expansion of Euro-Currency Loans to Developing
Countries
The increased lending to the developing countries did not come
about because the banks suddenly became aware of the demand for capital
by these countries.

Nor did it result from any overnight improvement in

the creditworthiness of these countries as a group, making them more




-16attractive as borrowers.

On the contrary, there was a growing awaref

ness in the late 1960's and early 1970 s that the developing countries,
as a group, had incurred very large foreign debts and were faced with
heavy debt service requirements in the years ahead.
For example, in 1969, the Commission on International Development
headed by Lester Pearson stated that "debts already contracted by many
developing countries cast a pall over the short- and long-term management
of their economies."

Debt servicing problems were also highlighted in

the report of a Special Presidential Task Force headed by Rudolph Peterson
which was also released in 1969.

In 1970, the World Bank undertook a

thorough study of the growing indebtedness of the developing countries
and the problems this might pose.

This study found that, by the end of

1969, 80 developing countries had incurred almost $59 billion in external
public debt, over half of which was concentrated in only nine countries.
The biggest borrowers were India, Pakistan, Brazil, Mexico, Indonesia,
Iran, Argentina, Chile, and K o r e a — i n that order.

Four of these countries

(India, Pakistan, Mexico, and Argentina) had debt service payments equal
to over 20 per cent of their annual earnings of foreign exchange.

In

the other c o u n t r i e s — e x c e p t for Indonesia, which had just undergone a
debt r e s c h e d u l i n g — t h e debt-service ratio ranged from 12 to 18 per cent.
In the light of the growing concern about the debt servicing
problems of the developing countries, one might be surprised to learn
that bank lending to the LDC's began its sharp rise just at the time




-17that these concerns were being widely discussed.

Factors other than

generally increased confidence in the creditworthiness of the developing
countries were obviously at work.
The main explanation for the change appears to lie in the
abundant supply of funds to the Euro-dollar market and the failure of
demand for loans from borrowers in developed countries to keep pace
with the expansion in credit availability.

The demand for this type

of financing by well-established customers in Europe and the United States
slowed

noticeably

in the last few years.

This was related to tightened

restrictions in some European countries on incoming capital and to the
ample supply of funds in the United States for business borrowers.
As a result, the Euro-currency banks (especially those in
London) began to push loans to the developing countries with considerable
vigor.

In order to do this, it was necessary to reduce the spread between

the cost of money to the bank and its lending rate.

The cost of money is

typically measured by the 6-months London interbank rate (LIBO). Previously
this spread had been much higher for LDC borrowers than for borrowers in
developed c o u n t r i e s — r a n g i n g up to as much as 3 percentage points over
LIBO.

The spread has been sharply r e d u c e d — i n some cases being set as

low as 5/8 of one per cent.

In addition, the maturities of the loans

have been stretched considerably.

From a range of 5-8 years as recently

as 1970, some banks are currently offering loans for up to 15 years.




-18Under the pressure of c o m p e t i t i o n — m u c h of it from American
and Japanese banks recently arrived in L o n d o n — t h e institutions are
borrowing short and lending long, a practice that has traditionally been
looked upon with disfavor.

The growth of this type of lending has been

encouraged by the adoption of the floating interest rate.

While the

loan may be committed for as much as 15 years, the interest rate is
ordinarily committed for one year at m o s t — a n d frequently for six
months.

This enables the lending banks to make sure that its cost of

money is always slightly below the rate of interest charged on the loan.
The borrower is assured a medium or long-term loan at the short-term
rates prevailing over the life of the loan.
Advantages of Euro-Currency Loans for Borrowers and Lenders
The expansion of Euro-currency loans to the developing
countries has provided a new source of capital to many of these nations.
The interest rates, however, have been substantially higher than rates
on comparable loans from international lending institutions such as the
World Bank or the Inter-American Development Bank.

Moreover, they may

even have been higher in many cases than rates charged on officially
guaranteed supplier credits.
Why have the borrowers in so many poor countries been willing
to accept this relatively expensive money?
The answer seems to be that the loans can be obtained relatively
quickly, with a minimum of red tape, and without the imposition of policy




-19conditions to which they may object.

There are rio requirements that

the projects they finance be carried out on the basis of international
competitive bidding.

The goods and services financed are not tied to

any stipulated country of origin.

The loan may not be tied to a project

and it may not cover any imports.

It may be a simple balance of payments

loan, or it may be used to restructure a country's e x t e r n a l — o r even
internal—debt.

It may be used to avoid lengthy and unpleasant debt

rescheduling negotiations with other creditors.

This flexibility has

considerable appeal for many borrowers.
In addition, the credits may enable the borrower to switch
indebtedness from currencies that are appreciating relative to its own
to currencies that are expected to maintain their parity or even depreciate.

They also enable the borrower to take advantage of possible

declines in the cost of money, since the interest rate is variable.
A n advantage to the lending banks is that they are able to
employ the large volume of funds pouring into the Euro-currency markets.
These loans have probably spelled the difference between breaking-even
and incurring l o s s e s — a n d perhaps earning a profit--for some of the 136odd foreign bank branches or subsidiaries operating in London.

While

the interest rate spread has been reduced to a level that many banks
consider uncomfortably thin, many of the credits are large in size, and
the costs of arranging and servicing are relatively low.
Many of the loans are provided by a consortium of banks, with
a lead bank making credit investigations (frequently not very thorough)




-20and handling the arrangements.

This relieves the other participants

in the consortium of much of the effort and expense associated with
the arrangement of the loan, although individual banks may in some cases
wish to make their own independent investigation.

The consortium arrange-

ment permits a spreading of the risk among a number of banks and an
economizing of labor in loan preparation.

The quality of the supporting

documentation for the loan may be exceptionally high in some cases,
while in others it may be quite inadequate.
In addition, the banks perhaps believe that these credits
produce goodwill for them in the borrowing c o u n t r y — a s s i s t i n g them in
other interests that they may have, such as establishment or maintenance
of branches in the borrowing country.
Disadvantages for Borrowers
The ease with which these loans can be contracted and the
rapidity with which they have grown in volume is encouraging to the
developing countries, but it is also a danger.

Borrowers may be induced

to contract debts that they may have difficulty servicing.

This is es-

pecially likely to be true if the credits are not used wisely and in ways
which increase the economic strength of the borrower.

The World Bank

made this point in its Annual Report for 1971, which said:




In a narrow sense, good debt management implies
restraint in the assumption of external debts except
where there is a reasonable presumption that the
borrowed capital will generate production which can,
directly or indirectly, be transformed into additional
foreign exchange resources over a period appropriate
to the service of the debt.

-21In the situation now prevailing in which the lenders are
competing intensively to make loans, there is a genuine danger that the
borrowers will be permitted or encouraged to incur large debts for
purposes which will add little or nothing to their capacity to service
debt.
The floating interest rate has disadvantages also.

A capital

intensive project that might promise a satisfactory rate of return when
the interest rate is at 5 per cent can get into serious difficulty if
the

rate climbs to the range of 8-10 per cent.

That has happened in

the Euro-currency market.
The easy availability of funds without any requirement for
competitive bidding for engineering and construction may also be disadvantageous to a poor country.
for the wrong reasons.

This can result in contracts being let

The country may place large orders with inefficient

or high-cost suppliers—domestic or foreign—resulting in far more costly
procurement than could have been obtained had the procedures required
by the international lending institutions been followed.
If Euro-currency loans are used as a substitute for drawings
from the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to help tide a country over
a balance-of-payments crisis, there is the possibility that the country
will continue to follow economic policies which contributed to the
difficulty initially.

If the IMF were called upon, the country would

have the advantage of its counsel and suggestions for overcoming basic




-22problems.

Of equal importance, it might be supported by the international

community in taking politically unpopular measures necessary to restore
domestic economic health,

A large Euro-currency loan for balance of

payments purposes made without any reference to the views of the IMF
could enable the country to continue to follow counter-productive policies
and thus further aggravate the situation.
Problems for Lenders
f

The rapid growth in Euro-currency loans to L D C s also presents
problems that must be of concern to the lenders.
the question of risk.

First and foremost is

Although some of the less developed countries have

an excellent record of debt-servicing, one cannot escape the fact that
the developing countries as a group have traditionally demonstrated less
political and economic stability than the developed countries.

The

volatility of commodity prices on which many of them depend can create
cycles of excessive optimism when prices soar followed by depression
when they decline.

If the country over-extends itself during the optimistic

phase, it may have serious trouble meeting its obligations when the boom
subsides.

Even government guarantees of credits may be of little help

when this happens.

The result can be a default or at least an urgent

request that the debts be rescheduled.
There is no foolproof way of telling when a country is getting
too deeply in debt.

The ratio of debt service payments to foreign

exchange earnings is not an infallible indicator.




However, a prudent

-23lender must have a good idea of what the overall indebtedness of the
prospective borrower is, and he should have some impression of the
resources likely to be available to service the debt.
The rapid expansion of credits to the developing countries
in the Euro-currency market has raised doubts about the adequacy of
the information available to the lenders regarding the indebtedness of
their clients.

Since the Euro-currency market as such is unsupervised

and u n r e g u l a t e d — u n l i k e the domestic banking business--there is no
official published record of the volume of lending to individual
countries.

It is possible that, in some borrowing countries, the

governments themselves are not fully aware of the volume of credit
that is being contracted.
It is becoming increasingly important for both the governments
of the borrowing countries and potential lenders to be informed much
more fully of the new commitments being made and the total debt outstanding.

The data now available are admittedly imperfect.

Moreover,

there is a fear that information is becoming less complete as this
activity grows in volume and as Euro-currency loans to the developing
countries are treated as routine matters not deserving of special public
announcements.

One country (Japan) has already instituted a reporting

procedure covering Euro-currency credits by its banks.
the time has come for others to follow suit.

I believe that

The World Bank is now

doing a good job of collecting debt statistics for the developing countries.
There is also an indication that some American b a n k s — a t




least—would

-24be happy to see its capabilities for collecting Euro-currency debt
statistics improved.

I personally hope that the World Bank will further

strengthen its own efforts, and also assume leadership by urging member
governments to join in the program.
Concluding Observations
Better data would be useful to the lenders and borrowers alike
and might help avoid excesses.

However, there is no easy solution to

f

the problems posed for L D C s by the volatility of the Euro-currency market
itself.

The International Finance Corporation pointed this out in its

1973 Annual Report, observing in part:




It is not inconceivable that a reversal of the
recent favorable circumstances which have facilitated
the entry of the developing countries into the Eurocurrency market, or other international monetary
developments, might result in a sudden drying up of
this new source of funds. Historically, high levels
of economic activity in the industrial countries have
created large internal demands for capital which in
turn have impinged upon the cost and availability of
private capital to the developing world. Although a
tightening of monetary conditions, accompanied by
rising interest rates, can currently be observed in
countries of Europe and North America, these do not
appear so far to have affected the availability of
funds in the Euro-currency market. Moreover, there
should continue to be, at least for some time to come,
sizable additions to the supply of funds in the Eurocurrency market, not only from traditional sources, but
also from the rising payment surpluses of the developing
countries themselves, especially the oil producing
countries. Nevertheless, the developing countries which
have borrowed heavily in the market should expect sharp
fluctuations in the liquidity conditions in the market,
and they should allow for significant changes in the
cost of their outstanding borrowing as part of overall
debt management.

-25Bearing these problems in m i n d , the willingness of commercial
banks to finance promising projects in developing countries that are
managing their economies well is a welcome development.

There is no

reason to assume that only advanced countries should have access to
the Euro-currency markets while only official institutions are qualified
f

to undertake this type of financing for L D C s .

The weakening of support

for official foreign assistance reflects in part some feeling that foreign
aid has not achieved all that was expected of it.

As the growth of

official aid flows slackens, it is encouraging to see that private capital
has come forward to provide the funds needed to maintain the developmental
pace in a number of countries.
However, it is also clear that private investors and lenders can
find themselves and their clients in an excessively exposed position if they
do not exercise the judment and caution characteristic of prudent participants in international markets.

They must be careful not to be driven

into unduly risky loans and investments merely by the pressure of competition.

Suppliers of funds have a responsibility to themselves and to their

clients to evaluate with care both the overall debt situation and the
particular project for which financing is sought.

And they must not

hesitate to give their best advice to all their customers, attaching
conditions to loans when it seems appropriate to do so.
With their improved access to capital markets, developing
countries may take justifiable pride in their ability to attract private




-26capital and large banking credits.

At the same time, however, it is

also important that the justification for that pride not be diminished
by excessive and indiscriminate reliance on currently a v a i l a b l e — b u t
highly volatile--funds obtainable through the international capital
markets.

Unless the risks inherent in these markets are recognized

and appreciated, the effort to launch and sustain a solidly based drive
for economic development is likely to be f r u s t r a t i n g — a n d perhaps
d i s a p p o i n t i n g — i n the long-run.




-0-

Table 1. Net Flow of Offical and Private Financial Resources
to Less Developed Countries and Multilateral Agencies, 1962 and 1972
(Millions of U.S. Dollars)
Total
Flows
Country

1. United States

Total

1962
Official Flows
Official
Development
Assistance

Private
Flows

Total

1972
Official Flows
Official
Development
Assistance

Total
Flows

Other
Purposes

Private
Flows
Other
Purposes

4,304.5

3,485.5

3,181.5

304.0

819.0

7,354.0

3,545.0

3,349.0

196.0

3,809.0

286.2

168.2

85.3

82.9

118.0

2,725.4

1,467.5

611.1

856.4

1,257.9

1,395.2

976.9

945.2

31.7

418.2

2,072.7

1,337.0

1,320.5

16.5

735.7

2.

Japan

3.

France

4.

Germany

609.4

466.4

405.1

61.3

143.0

1,713.8

956.8

808.3

148.5

757.0

5.

United Kingdom

743.9

421.0

421.0

- -

322.9

1,695.8

625.0

608.7

16.3

1,070.8

6.

Canada

109.6

54.4

34.5

19.9

55.2

985.9

576.6

462.5

114.1

409.3

7.

Netherlands

114.2

65.0

65.0

- -

49.2

652.9

314.9

309.6

5.3

338.0

8.

Italy

390.4

111.2

80.1

31.1

279.3

539.3

253.8

103.9

149.9

285.5

9.

Australia

73.8

73.8

73.8

- -

- -

424.8

276.3

271.9

4.4

148.5

10

Belgium

118.2

69.8

69.8

- -

48.4

391.0

206.0

192.6

13.4

185.0

11.

Sweden

37.2

18.5

18.5

- -

18.7

272.0

197.7

197.7

- -

12.

Switzerland

161.1

4.9

4.9

- -

156.2

172.8

67.0

64.4

2.6

105.8

13.

Portugal

40.8

40.8

36.0

4.8

—

163.2

135.0

115.0

20.0

28.2

14.

Denmark

14.7

7.4

7.5

.1

7.3

119.9

98.3

95.6

2.7

21.6

15.

Austria

31.0

13.8

2.3

11.5

17.2

111.6

16.6

18.5

1.9

95.0

16.

Norway
Total DAC
Countries

6.8

6.9

7.3

.4

0.1

56.1

65.2

63.3

1.9

9.1

8,437.0

5,984.5

5,437.8

546.7

2,452.5

19,451.2

10,138.7

8,592.6

1,546.1

9,312.5

Source:

-

74.3

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Development Assistance Committee, "General Statistics, 1972", July 1973
Tables 1, 2, 3, and 4.
'
'




Table 2.

Total

1962
Official Flows
Official
Development
Assistance

Other
Purposes

Total
Flows
Countrv

Net Flow of Official and Private Financial Resources,
By Principal Types, 1962 and 1972
(Percentage Distribution)
Private
Flows

Total

1972
Official Flows
Official
Development
Assistance

Total
Flows

nrivaEe
Flows
Other
Purposes

1.

United States

100.0

81.0

73.9

7.1

19.0

100.0

48.2

45.5

2.7

51.7

2.

Japan

100.0

58.8

29.8

29.0

41.2

100.0

53.8

22.4

31.4

46.2

3.

France

100.0

70.0

67.7

2.3

30.0

100.0

64.5

63.7

.8

35.5

4.

Germany

100.0

76.5

66.5

10.0

23.5

100.0

55.8

47.1

8.7

44.2

5.

United Kingdom

100.0

56.6

56.6

43.4

100.0

36.9

35.9

1.0

63.1

6.

Canada

100.0

49.6

31.5

50.4

100.0

58.5

46.9

11.6

41.5

7.

Netherlands

100.0

56.9

56.9

- -

43.1

100.0

48.2

47.4

.8

51.8

8.

Italy

100.0

28.5

20.5

8.0

71.5

100.0

47.1

19.3

27.8

52.9

9.

Australia

100.0

100.0

100.0

- -

100.0

65.0

64.0

1.0

35.0

10.

Belgium

100.0

59.1

59.1

- -

40.9

100.0

52.7

49.3

3.4

47.3

11.

Sweden

100.0

49.7

49.7

- -

50.3

100.0

72.7

72.7

- -

27.3

12.

Switzerland

100.0

3.0

3.0

- -

97.0

100.0

38.8

37.3

1.5

61.2

13.

Portugal

100.0

100.0

88.2

100.0

82.7

70.5

12.2

17.3

14.

Denmark

100.0

50.3

51.0

15.

Austria

100.0

44.5

16.

Norway

100.0
100.0

Total DAC
Countries
Source:

18.1

—

11.8

—

.7

49.7

100.0

82.0

79.7

2.3

18.0

7.4

37.1

55.5

100.0

14.9

16.6

- 1.7

85.1

101.5

107.4

- 5.9

- 1.5

100.0

116.2

112.8

3.4

- 16.2

70.9

64.4

6.5

29.1

100.0

52.1

44.2

7.9

47.9

Calculated from Table 1.




- -

-

Table 3. Net Flow of Official and Private Financial Resources
in Relation to Gross National Product,!/ 1962 and 1972
(Percentages)
Total
Flows
Total

Country

1962
Official Flows
Official
Development
Assistance

Private
Flows

Total
Flows

Other
Purposes

Total

1972
Official Flows
Official
Development
Assistance

Privati
Flows
Other
Purposes

1. United States

.76

.61

.56

.05

.14

.64

.31

.29

.02

.33

2.

Japan

.49

.29

.14

.15

.20

.93

.50

.21

.29

.43

3.

France

1.88

1.31

1.27

.04

.56

1.06

.68

.67

.01

.38

4.

Germany

.68

.52

.45

.07

.16

.67

.37

.31

.06

.29

5.

United Kingdom

.92

.52

.52

- -

.41

1.11

.41

.40

.01

.70

6.

Canada

.27

.14

.09

.05

.14

.95

.55

.44

.11

.39

7.

Netherlands

.85

.49

.49

- -

.37

1.43

.69

.68

.01

.74

8.

Italy

.89

.25

.18

.07

.64

.46

.21

.09

.12

.24

9#

Australia

.43

.43

.43

- -

- -

.96

.62

.61

.01

.33

10.

Belgium

.91

.54

.54

—

.37

1.12

.59

.55

.04

.53

11.

Sweden

.24

.12

.12

- -

.12

.66

.48

.48

- -

.18

12.

Switzerland

1.51

.05

.05

—

1.47

.58

.22

.21

.01

.35

13.

Portugal

1.43

1.43

1.26

2. 15

1.78

1.51

.27

. 37

14.

Denmark

.20

.10

.10

- -

.10

.57

.47

.45

.02

.10

15.

Austria

.42

.19

.03

.16

.23

.55

.08

.09

- .01

.46

.13

.13

,14

- .01

- -

.37

.42

.41

.01

- -

Total DAC
.80
Countries
At market price s.

.57

.52

.05

.23

.77

.40

.34

.06

.37

16. Norway

y

Source:

.17

- -

OECD/DAC, "General Statistics , 1972", July 1973, Tables 26, 27, 28, and 29.




Table 4 .

Flow of Private Financial Resources
from DAC Countries to Developing Countries and
Multilateral Agencies, 1960, 1970, 1972
(in billions of dollars)
1960

1970

J-/
1972"

.20
.63
.83

.47
.78
1.25

.62
2.33
2.95

Direct Investment

1.77

3.56

3.85

Export Credits
Sub-total
Grants by Voluntary Agencies
Total Private Flows

.55
3.15
n . a.
n . a.

2.21
7.02
.86
7.88

1.48
8.28
1.02
9.30

Bonds of Multilateral Agencies
Bilateral Portfolio Investment
Total Portfolio Investment

1/

Provisional

Sources:




IBRD, Annual Report for 1973, p . 86; and OECD, Development Assistance
Efforts and Policies of The Members of DAC, 1969 Review, p . 38*

Table 5.
1/

Euro-Currency C r e d i t s
to the Less Developed Countries
with a Maturity of more than one Year
by Nationality of Borrowers
(in millions of U.S. dollars)
1971
(Year)

1972
(Year)

1973
(First Half)

Latin America and Caribbean
Argentina
Brazil
Colombia
Dominican Republic
Guyana
Jamaica
Mexico
Nicaragua
Panama
Peru
Venezuela
Total

50.0

212.0

243.9
577.3
90.0
4.0

7.3
309.0
25.0
12.5

140.0

12.0
111.0
40.0
85.0

78.3
506.3

508.8
15.0
40.0
209.4
258.5
1.846.9

120.0

282.0

812.5

224.0

18.3
385.4

242.6

695.7

1,055.1

10.0
16.0

188.6
20.0
810.4

Middle East and North Africa
Algeria
Dubai
Iran
Israel
Total

344.0

10.0

Other Asia
Brunei
Hong Kong
Indonesia
Malaysia
Philippines
South Korea

27.5

20.0

Total

40.0
40.0

97.6
76.1
61.3
30.0
312.5

200.0
80.0
280.0

Other Africa
10.0

Gabon
Guinea
Ivory Coast
Kenya
Mauritania
Senegal
Swaziland
Zaire
Zambia

22.0
8.0

41.0
46.0

15.0
25.0

95.0

3.2
90.0
25.0
198.2

212.0

985.3

3,053.3

2,357.5

55.0
Total

A l l Less Developed Countries

1/ Amount of newly contracted loans.
Sources: Compiled from published loan announcements.



25.0
40.0

50.0
50.0

Table 60.
Euro-Bond Issues by
Borrowers in the Less Developed Countries
1969-1973
by Nationality of the Borrowers
(in million of U.S. dollars)
1969
Year

1970
Year

_
10.0

50.0
15.5

1971
Year

1972
Year

_

_
121.0

Latin America and Caribbean
Argentina
Brazil
Colombia
Jamaica
Mexico
Netherlands Antilles
Panama
Venezuela
Total

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

45.0
38.7
-

-

93.7

20.0
-

30.0
13.3
128.8

30.0
_
16.0
-

46.0

-

10.0
80.0
-

20.0
39.8
270.8

:1/
1973
First Hj

_
25.0
20.0
14.0
31.0
-

90.0

Middle East and North Africa
Algeria
Egypt
Iran
Israel
Total

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

8.0
.9
8.9

25.0
-

20.0
20.0
65.0

-

53.0
20.7
-

73.7

Other Asia and Pacific
Hong Kong
Malaysia
Papua-New Guinea
Philippines
Singapore
Total

15.0

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

_

_

—

-

-

10.0
25.0

•

24.8
-

-

17.1
17.2

50.0
51.0
125.8

34.3

30.0
30.0

30.0
30.0

491.6

228.0

-

Other Africa
Guinea
Total
All Less Developed Countries

102.6

128.8

71.0

1/ Provisional
Source:

IBRD, Annual Report for 1972, p . 93, and Annual Report for 1973, p . 99.