View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
Friday, November 10, 1972
11:00 a.m. E.S.T.




INTEREST RATES AND CREDIT DEMANDS IN THE UNITED STATES

Remarks
By
Andrew F. Brimmer
Member
Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System

Before the
79th Annual Convention
of the
Savings Banks Association of New York State
Boca Raton Hotel and Club
Boca Raton, Florida

November 10, 1972

INTEREST RATES AND CREDIT DEMANDS IN THE UNITED STATES
By
Andrew F. Brimmer*

I.

Introduction
In considering the range of subjects on which I might

comment at this meeting, I concluded early that I would not attempt
to lecture to you about your own business.

After all, you know

far more about your own affairs than I do.

On the other hand, it

would not be appropriate for m e — a Member of the Federal Reserve
Board--to discuss the future course of monetary policy.

Given these

constraints, I decided to focus on an area in which our mutual concerns
intersect: the area of interest rates and credit demands in the months ahead.
In pursuing this topic, several boundaries must be identified
clearly.

In the first place, the views and attitudes expressed here

are my own and should not be attributed to my colleagues on the
Federal Reserve Board.

Secondly, as already indicated, the ground to

be covered—by necessity—cannot be extended to include a forecast of

* Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
I am grateful to a number of Board staff members for assistance
in the preparation of this paper. Several of these were especially
helpful in supplying information and should be mentioned specifically.
Mr. Stephen P. Taylor made a special effort to obtain preliminary flow
of funds statistics for the third quarter of 1972. The following
persons provided information on recent and prospective demands for credit
in particular markets: Messrs. Fred Taylor and Bernard N. Freedman
(residential mortgages); Mr. Richard Petersen (consumer credit); -Eleanor Pruitt and Helen S. Tice (State and local governments and
corporations), and Mr. Helmut F. Wendel (Federal Government).
Mr. Edward C. Ettin provided data on income and operating expenses of
commercial banks. Mrs. Mary F. Weaver helped to trace changes in
commercial banks1 prime lending rate. Finally, Mr. John Austin and
Mrs. Ruth Robinson (my assistants) helped with the statistical analysis
underlying several parts of the paper.
However, the views expressed here are my own and should not be
attributed to the Board's staff nor to my colleagues on the Board.



- 2interest rate levels.

In addition, there is no intention here to get

into the affairs of the Committee on Interest and Dividends.

Although

the Chairman of that unit of the Administration's Cost of Living
Council is also Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board, the
responsibilities of the two bodies remain separate and distinct.
But within these constraints, there remains considerable
scope to discuss a number of issues relating to interest rates and
credit demands.

Most of us are so preoccupied with our daily routines

that we seldom have the opportunity to stand aside to identify and
assess some of the fundamental trends that are reshaping the financial
environment in which we work.

I personally try to do that occasionally

and most recently I have attempted to broaden my understanding of some
of the long-run developments with respect to interest rates.
I have the impression that many observers--when they reflect
on interest rates at all—are likely to be more concerned about the
level and trend of rates than about their structure and economic impact.
Whether interest rates are "high11 or "low11 or whether they are "rising11
or "falling" are certainly questions of economic significance.

Yet,

they certainly do not exhaust the range of issues with respect to
interest rates which ought to be explored from time to time.
For example, we should also be concerned with the extent
to which a given structure of interest rates is commensurate with the
actual risks incurred by lenders.

In a similar vein, we should ask

whether borrowers in different segments of the money and capital




- 3markets get as much benefit from interest rate competition among lenders
as the overall supply of funds might indicate.

In the same context,

we ought to be curious as to whether interest rates on the volume of
debt outstanding are becoming more subject or less subject to market
determination as opposed to being set on an administered basis.
For those of us with particular concerns about the role of
financial institutions, we ought to be especially curious about the
evolving behavior of commercial banks in setting interest rates.

Of

course, our curiosity should extend to the practice adopted a year
ago by a few large banks under which their prime lending rate is linked
to key money market variables.

But it should not stop there.

We

should be equally concerned with the growing tendency of commercial
banks to take on commitments to make business loans with the
expectation of being able (under all circumstances) to offer interest
rates on large denomination certificates of deposits (CD's) high
enough to obtain the funds needed to meet the commitments.
These are some of the issues relating to interest rates
which are examined below.

In addition, a summary of information on

recent developments in credit flow is presented.

The latter is intended

primarily as background for an assessment of the main factors which
might have a bearing on credit demands in the months ahead.
These main issues can now be examined more fully.

In the

final section of the paper, the principal conclusions emerging from
the analysis are summarized, and some of their implications are
indicated.




-4II.

Long-Run Perspectives on Interest Rates
Anyone with even a casual awareness of interest rates in

the United States knows that the current levels are well above
those prevailing before the mid-19601s.

Table I (Attached) shows

interest rates in numerous segments of the credit markets since 1961,
Even a brief analysis of these data points up the extent to which
interest rates have mirrored developments in money and capital
markets over the last decade.

To help sharpen the focus, the

course of several key interest rates shown in Table 1 has been
traced by converting them into an index—using the 1961 level as a
base (i.e., 1961 = 100):

Interest Rate
3-mo. Treasury bills (market yield)
4-6 mo. commercial paper
Long-Term U.S. Gov't, bonds
Long-Term State & local bonds (Aaa)
Long-Term corp. bonds (Aaa)
Home mortgages (new, FHA)
(New conventional)
Prime rate, commercial bank

1965

1966

1969

1970

1971

167
147
108
97
103
98
96
111

206
187
119
112
118
107
102
133

283
264
156
167
162
134
128
189

271
260
169
187
185
143
139
150

183
172
147
160
170
130
127
117

1972

It might be recalled that, during much of the period
1961-65, a basic objective of national economic policy was the
stimulation of output and the reduction of unemployment.

The Federal

Reserve System shared in the pursuit of that objective by following




201
178
146
154
166
129
129
128

- 5a generally accommodating monetary policy.

At the same time, however,

the Federal Reserve was also concerned with the deficit in the
country's balance of payments—and especially with the heavy volume
of capital outflows.

Partly in an effort to reconcile those

competing aims, the System—during part of the period—adapted
its monetary policy to some extent to moderate any tendency for longterm rates to increase while permitting a rise in short-term rates.
The legacy of that course was still evident in 1965.

For example,

short-term interest rates were one-half to two-thirds higher in that
year than they had been in 1961.

In contrast, yields on long-term

U.S. Government and corporate bonds rose very little, and interest
rates on home mortgages declined slightly.

The prime lending rate

of commercial banks climbed only moderately.
The impact of severe credit restraint on interest rates
in 1966 can also be identified.

In that year, short-term rates

were roughly twice as high as they were in 1961 and about one-quarter
higher than in 1965.

On the other hand, the fact that long-term

bond yields advanced by only half as much during 1966--while mortgage
interest rates climbed by even less—may come as a surprise to some.
But on closer analysis, the pattern of rate changes in that year
appears not so surprising after all.

In its effort to help check

the inflation generated by the acceleration of military activity
in Vietnam, the Federal Reserve eventually exerted a substantial




- 6degree of monetary restraint in 1966.

However, the peak of restraint

was attained only in late Summer, and it was not held very long.
Moreover, the System—on balance—did make net additions to bank
reserves during the course of the year.

Under those circumstances,

overall pressures in the capital markets were considerable but
far short of those which developed three years later.
In the case of home mortgages, the modest increases in
interest rates recorded in 1966 are by no means an index of
pressures in that segment of the credit markets.

To a considerable

extent, mortage rates were subject to administrative ceilings (FHA
and VA rates) or to State usury laws (conventional rates).

Most

of the principal mortgage lenders were also severely circumscribed
by the lag in earnings on long-term mortgages in their ability to offer
competitive interest rates to savers.

As a consequence, ceilings were

imposed by Government on the interest rates that these institutions
could pay depositors.

But even so, the non-bank institutions (especially

savings and loan associations) experienced a sharp moderation in the
inflow of funds and were forced to reduce drastically the volume of
funds supplied to the housing market.
But in one sense, the 1966 experience was a rehearsal for
the drama that was to unfold three years later.

In 1969, as the

fight against inflation intensified, the Federal Reserve pursued
a particularly stringent monetary policy.

In this instance, the

volume of bank reserves and the money supply expanded very little.




- 7As market yields again climbed to—and exceeded--the maximum
interest rates which commercial banks, S&L f s, and mutual savings
banks could offer savers, these institutions experienced severe
strains on deposit inflows.

To counter these, some of the

institutions (particularly commercial banks) made a frantic effort
to tap new sources of funds—including Euro-dollars and sales of
commercial paper by affiliates of bank holding companies.
Reflecting mounting pressures on the supply of funds
in the face of continued strong demands for credit, all types of
market interest rates climbed to historic heights in 1969.
fact, the actual peak in rates extended in 1970;

In

and for the

latter year as a whole, only short-term market yields and the
commercial bank prime rate were below the levels reached in 1969.
During the recession of 1970-71, the Federal Reserve again pursued
an accommodating policy and greatly expanded the volume of bank
reserves supplied to the banking system.

In response to this policy

and the declining demand for certain types of credit (e.g., business
loans at banks), interest rates declined on a broad front.

However,

the decreases were much more noticeable in the case of short-term
than in the case of long-term rates.

The adoption of wage and price

controls by the Administration in August last year reinforced the
downtrend in interest rates.




While the currently prevailing

levels of short-term rates (i.e., in October) are above the averages
for 1971, the differences are rather small.

Moreover, the level

of long-term rates is essentially unchanged for the year-ago
average.
These long-term trends in interest rates should be kept
in mind.

They will contribute perspective to the subsequent

discussion of long-run credit flows.
III.

Lending Risks, Operating Costs, and Rates of Return
Another issue that has concerned me is the extent to

which interest rates received by lenders are reflective of the
risks they take and the costs of doing business.

I am personally

convinced that these may not be as closely linked as first impressions
might suggest.
All of us are familiar with the differences in interest
rates associated with loans of different quality and maturity.

We

understand why those loans entailing higher credit risks or extending
for longer periods of time generally carry higher interest rates.
Moreover, because the different

segments of the credit markets are

not completely isolated from each other, movements in interest rates
in one sector ordinarily generate repercussions in the same direction
in adjacent sectors.

But, since lenders and borrowers cannot switch

freely among the different sectors, interest arbitrage is far from
perfect, and money and capital markets are segmented to a considerable
degree.




- 9 We also recognize that, in assessing the interest rate
on a particular loan, we must be conscious of the particular types
of risk a lender incurrs.

For example, he must cover his credit

risk—i.e., the risk of default;

and in the case of marketable

loans, he must cover the market risk as well—i.e., the risk that
he might have to liquidate the asset at a price below what he paid
for it.

Moreover, in the case of long-term loans, we must also expect

lenders to hedge against future inflation by seeking a premium to
compensate—at least in part—for anticipated price increases and
the consequent erosion of the purchasing power of his future income.
In recent years, this premium has undoubtedly been quite high—although
we cannot quantify it.
In addition to risks, interest rates must also cover the
costs of doing business.

These costs also vary considerably with

respect to different types of loans.

Undoubtedly, it costs more

to book and maintain small consumer loans than it does to handle
large loans to business.

On the average, the risk of losses on

the former taken in the aggregate is greater than the loss exposure
on the latter.

Nevertheless, one ought to ask whether the large

differences in interest rates associated with different types of
loans can be explained fully by such factors.




- 10 A general idea of the richness of rate variations can be
seen in Table 2, showing interest rates on selected types of loans
to households and businesses.

Several features stand out.

In the

case of loans to consumers, the widely-known fact that commercial
banks charge interest rates well below those charged by finance
companies is clearly evident.

To some extent, of course, finance

companies generally deal with borrowers among whom the risk of loss
is higher than it is among bank customers.

Yet, one might reasonably

doubt that the differential in favor of finance companies of about
one-quarter in the rate

on new automobile loans and of one-seventh

on mobile home loans can be fully explained by this factor.
Similarly, the spread in favor of finance companies of over two-thirds
on personal loans may not be fully attributable to the greater loss
exposure which they face.
I am personally convinced that at least some of the margin
enjoyed by finance companies can be traced to segmentation of the
market for personal loans and the dampening of interest rate competition
which this implies.

In my judgment, if commercial banks were more

aggressive in pursuing customers who now depend mainly on finance
companies, the cost of credit to consumers would decline somewhat.
In fact, it was with this expectation in mind that I personally
supported the entry of bank holding companies into the finance
company field—as permitted under the 1970 amendments to the




- 11 -

Bank Holding Company Act.

Already a number of bank holding companies

have acquired finance company subsidiaries.

But the extent to which

such acquisitions have resulted in increased interest rate competition
is still uncertain.

Yet, I have the impression that no significant

downward pressure has been exerted.

Instead, it seems that the

entering bank holding companies typically accept the prevailing
structure of finance charges and seek to obtain as large a share of
the market as possible.

Hopefully, as more bank holding companies

expand into the finance company field, more interest rate competition
will result.
With respect to loans to business, the figures in Table 2
show clearly the expected tendency for interest rates to decline as
the size of loan increases.

For example, in the case of short-term

commercial bank loans (maturing in one year or less), the average
interest rate on loans in the $1,000-9,000 size range was about
one-quarter above that on all such loans in August of this year.
But in the $100,000-499,000 loan size class, the rate was only 6 per
cent about the average; and on loans of $1,000,000 and over the rate
was 5 per cent below the average.

The same general pattern existed

with respect to revolving credit and long-term loans to business.
Also, as one would expect, the interest rates on only the largest
loans (and then only in the case of short-term credits) were close
to the prevailing prime lending rate.




An even clearer perspective on the relationship among risks,
operating costs, and interest rates is provided by the figures in
Table 3.

These data are based on the average experience in 1971

of 994 member banks in 12 districts of the Federal Reserve System
which participate (on a voluntary basis) in a functional cost analysis
program.

The banks are grouped by size of total deposits (i.e.,

up to $50 million, 684 banks;

$50 million to $200 million, 231 banks;

and over $200 million, 79 banks).

The banks1 operating experience

is shown with respect to total loans;
consumer instalment loans;
investments combined.

real estate mortgage loans;

credit card loans;

commercial loans and

Calculations were made to show for each asset

category—as a percentage of outstanding volume: gross yield;
related operating expenses;

loan losses; and the cost of money.

In combination, these variables provide measures of the rate of return
to the banks on each category of asset—net of risk and operating
costs.
Here also several features of the data stand out.

First,

it will be noted that, for each class of commercial bank loans,
operating costs absorb a significant share of the gross yield.
all loans, the proportion was about one-quarter.

For

The highest

proportion shows up with respect to credit card loans (four-fifths),
followed by consumer loans (one-third), commercial loans (one-sixth),




- 13 and real estate mortgages (one-tenth).

For investments alone,

the proportion was smallest of all (less than 2 per cent).

For the

banks1 entire portfolio of earning assets (loans and investments
combined), the proportion was about one-sixth.

Secondly (except

in the case of credit cards), loan losses absorbed relatively small
proportions of the gross yield.
Perhaps an even clearer way to get an appreciation of the
relationship among operating costs, loan losses, and interest rates
is to relate them to the volume of loans outstanding.

To illustrate

the results, the experience of the banks in the middle size class
(i.e., those with deposits of $50 to $200 million) might be
examined.

In 1971, the average bank in this class had a gross yield

of 8.082 per cent on its total loans outstanding.

Operating expenses

were 1.907 per cent of total loan volume—providing a net yield before
losses of 6.175 per cent.

Since loan losses were 0.120 per cent of

outstanding loans, the net yield was reduced to 6.055 per cent.
However, the cost of money employed (which was 3.438 per cent of
loan volume) also had to be subtracted, and this reduced the net yield
further to 2.617 per cent.

This latter figure is the final measure

of the banks1 net return on loans.
The same calculations were made for each category of loans
taken separately and for each size class of bank.

Those calculations

are shown in detail in Table 3, and there is no need to list them here.




- 14 -

However, a few key points should be made.

For each

size of bank, the net rate of return on consumer instalment loans
is clearly higher than that on commercial and other business loans.
While operating costs and loan losses in relation to loan volume
are higher for consumer instalment loans than for business loans,
the cost of money does not differ appreciably between them.

Thus,

when all the adjustments are made, the banks are left with a margin
on consumer instalment loans that appears ftot to be directly related
to risk and operating costs incurred in making such loans.

In my

personal judgment, some part of that residual probably should be
attributed to a lesser degree of interest rate competition in consumer
credit extension than is found in the case of bank lending to
businesses.
IV.

Administered vs. Market Determined Interest Rates
As I indicated above, I personally believe that economic

welfare is improved when interest rates are subject more to market
1/
influences than to administrative decisions.""

Underlying this

belief is a conviction that price competition—when it can be made
to w o r k — i s a better guide to credit and resource allocation than
actions taken on the basis of conventional practices or other nonmarket standards.

Of course, I realize that in numerous circumstances

price competition cannot be made to work or other public policy
objectives may require overt intervention by Government to moderate
1/

Earlier this year, I examined the same issue at some length with
respect to interest rates offered on consumer-type time deposits.
See "Interest Rate Discrimination, Savings Flows, and New Priorities
in Home Financing," presented before the University of Washington
Alumni Association, Seattle, Washington, June 9, 1972.




- 15 the workings of the market.

But I believe such occasions should

be exceptional, and wherever possible our goal should be to
encourage price determination on the basis of market forces over as
wide a range of economic decisions that we can reasonably have.
In passing, I should say that it is in that framework
that I have viewed bank merger and bank holding company acquisition
applications that come before the Federal Reserve Board for decision.
I have been concerned not only with the effects of a proposed
merger or acquisition on existing competition but also on potential
competition in a given market.

The common thread in all my comments

on such cases (particularly in those rare instances in which I
differ from the Board majority) is a persistent quest for ways to
increase rather than diminish the effects of market competition on
interest rates and other costs of providing banking services.
Against that background, I recently tried to classify the
volume of outstanding debt, by major sectors and credit instruments,
according to the extent to which the related interest rates are
determined on the basis of administrative decisions or are substantially
subject to market forces.
Table 4.

The results of that effort are shown in

Data are presented for 1961 and 1971, so broad changes—if

any—can be traced over the decade.
Before commenting on the results, however, let me say
immediately that some of the classifications are matters of judgment
and are necessarily arbitrary.




Some of the debt categories (such

- 16 as U.S. Government obligations) are officially identified in marketable
or non-marketable terms.

The status of other classifications (such

as open market commercial paper and publicly offered bonds) is
widely recognized in the money and capital markets.

Interest rates

on still other debt obligations are subject to a mixture of market
and nonmarket

factors, and it was necessary to record them in one

category or the other for the present analysis.

Commercial bank

loans to business are an outstanding example in this class of credit
instruments.

The recently adopted practice whereby some banks

link their prime lending rate to market variables makes it even
more difficult to classify business loans with respect to administered
vs. market determined interest rates.

But on balance, the vast

majority of banks have not adopted floating prime rates, so bank
loans to businesses
Turning
evident.

were classified in the administered rate category.
to the figures in Table 4, a clear pattern is

In both 1961 and 1971, the total outstanding debt

in the United States was about equally divided between market and
administered interest rate classes.

But among major sectors of the

economy, the division varied widely.

For instance, virtually all

of the household debt was subject to administered

rates.

At the

opposite extreme, all of the State and local government debt was
subject to market determined interest rates.
the division was about half-and-half.

In the business sector,

As mentioned above, interest

rates on bank loans to business are classified as determined by




- 17 administrative decisions, and the volume of these loans heavily
weights the total volume of business debt in that direction.

About

four-fifths of the Federal Government debt is in the market rate
category.
Over the last decade, no dramatic changes occurred in
the distribution of debt in the major economic sectors between market
and administered rate classes. However, a few differences are observable,
and these might be noted.

In the case of the Federal Government, the

proportion of debt subject to administered rates declined somewhat
(from 21 per cent to 17 per cent of the total).

This was due mainly

to the relatively slow expansion in the volume of savings bonds
outstanding.

In the data presented here it will be noted that

special issues of Federal Government debt (whether held by trust
funds or foreign official institutions) are classified as "nonmarketable11
but recorded in the market determined interest rate class.

While

these issues cannot be transferred in the market, the interest rates
on them are linked explicitly to yields on U.S. Government marketable
securities.

Because both trust fund and foreign-held special issues

rose enormously in the last decade—while the volume of savings
bonds rose only moderately--the proportion of nonmarketable outstandings
subject to market interest rates climbed from 45 per cent in 1961
to 65 per cent in 1971.




- 18 When the situation is viewed in terms of the share of
major economic sectors in the volume of debt classified in each
category—i.e. , subject to market vs. administered interest
rates—several other changes are put into sharper focus.

Thus,

in 1961 and 1971, the household sector accounted for about the same
proportion of all administered rate debt outstanding (56 per cent
and 58 per cent, respectively).

However, in the share of the business

sector the proportion in the administered rate class rose somewhat
(from 30 per cent to 35 per cent).

This was mainly a reflection

of the high rate of growth of bank loans reinforced by the expansion
in trade credit.

On the other hand, the level of total U.S.

Government debt rose more slowly over the decade than total debt
outstanding, although its composition shifted more toward the
marketable component.

As a consequence, the Federal Government's

share of all debt subject to market determined interest
rates declined from 50 per cent in 1961 to 37 per
cent in 1971.

Yet, that segment of the Federal debt that expanded

most rapidly (special issues) carries interest rates determined in
the market rather than by administrative decision.

In contrast,

savings bonds—which carry administrative rates (which were well
below comparable market yields during much of the last decade) —
experienced a decline from 12 per cent of all administered rate
debt in 1961 to 7 per cent in 1971.




- 19 v#

Market Factors in the Determination of Commercial Bank Lending Rates
At this point I would like to discuss the growing influence

of market factors on interest rate determination by commercial banks.
In the last year—during which roughly a half dozen large banks
have followed the practice of linking their prime lending rates to
money market variables—observers have become increasingly aware
of the impact of market forces on rates set by commercial banks.
Yet, the tying of the prime rate to short-term market yields is
essentially an overt (and highly visable) manifestation of a
tendency that has been evident for some time--if one looked carefully
at the changing sources and uses of commercial bank funds.
In essence, commercial banks have become increasingly
willing to commit themselves to lend to their regular corporate
customers, for which commitment the latter have shown a growing
readiness to pay a fee.

The banks, in turn, have made such commitments

on the expectation that they could obtain funds as needed by offering
competitive rates on CD's.

In other words, the banks have become

increasingly prepared to buy resources to be rechanneled to their
best customers.
The extent to which banks have come to rely on interestbearing sources of funds can be seen in Table 5, showing liabilities
of all insured commercial banks in the United States for the
1961 and 1971.




years

For present purposes, the key figure in the table

- 20 is the proportion of total resources on which the banks paid
2/
interest.

In 1961, that proportion was 32 per cent, and by 1971

it had risen to 50 per cent.
The most significant change in the composition of these
interest-bearing deposits was the dramatic rise in the volume of
large negotiable CD's.

In 1961, the amount outstanding (while

not reported separately) was known to be fairly small.

By 1971,

the volume had risen to $34 billion and accounted for 10-1/2 per
cent of the $320 billion of the banks1 total interest bearing
liabilities.

The second significant change centered in the expansion

of federal funds purchased and securities sold under repurchase
agreements.

This category was not reported separately in 1961;

but last year such liabilities (primarily federal funds) amounted
to $24 billion--or 7-1/2 per cent of all interest-bearing liabilities.
In 1961, savings deposits on the banks1 books amounted
to $64 billion and represented 73 per cent of the $88 billion of
interest-bearing liabilities.

Time deposits (of which the CD

component was negligible) amounted to $19 billion--or 22 per cent of
interest-bearing resources.

So, in combination, these two categories

accounted for 95 per cent of the total liabilities on which the
2/
~

These interest-bearing resources are defined here as total
liabilities and capital minus demand deposits, bankers1 acceptances
outstanding, minority interest in consolidated subsidiaries,
total reserves, and equity capital.




- 21 banks paid interest.

By 1971, while savings deposits had expanded

to $111 billion, their share of total interest bearing liabilities
had shrunk to 34 per cent.

Total time deposits had risen to

$163 billion (51 per cent of interest-bearing liabilities).

But

if the volume of CD's is subtracted, the share is reduced to 40
per cent.
Another source of interest-bearing funds not shown
separately in Table 5 is the Euro-dollar market.

As is generally

known, about a dozen and a half large banks systematically bid
3/
for Euro-dollars-

when the differential cost of short-term money

at home and abroad favors greater reliance on such funds compared
with federal funds and CD's to provide additional liquidity.

The

extent to which banks made use of Euro-dollars in 1961 is unknown.
However, at the end of 1971, the indebtedness of U.S. banks to their
foreign branches amounted to $0,9 billion.
in 1969, the volume was $15.4 billion.

At the high point reached

As I have stressed on

4/
several occasions," I believe firmly that these Euro-dollar inflows
greatly aggravated the task of monetary policy in this country in 1969
and 1970.
3/ The bidding for Euro-dollars is done primarily through these
banks' London branches, but other banks also participate in
the Euro-dollar market through correspondents, brokers, and other
arrangements.
4/ For example, see "Commercial Bank Lending and Monetary Management,"
remarks before the 57th Annual Fall Conference of the Robert Morris
Associates, Los Angeles, California, October 25, 1971.




- 22 Of course, the counterpart of banks1 increased reliance
on interest-bearing resources is the erosion of the relative
5/
importance of interest-free demand deposits.~~

In 1961, the

latter amounted to $165 billion and accounted for three-fifths of
the banks1 total liabilities and capital.

By 1971, the volume of

demand deposits had risen to $261 billion, but their share of
resources had fallen to two-fifths.
demand deposits expanded by only

In fact, over the decade,

58 per cent--while time and savings

deposits rose by 233 per cent and total liabilities by 130 per
cent.
The relative decline of demand deposits available to
banks and their increased dependence on interest-bearing funds
were by no means wholly voluntary on the banks1 part.

Instead, the

growing sophistication of liquidity management by corporate treasurers
and others with control over large cash balances has meant a sharp
decrease in their willingness to keep idle funds with banks.

The

high rates of return available on money market instruments during
much of the last decade have added to their incentive to economize
on cash holdings.

In response, the commercial banks have found

it increasingly necessary to bid for interest-bearing funds in the
money market—both at home and abroad.
5/ Although demand deposits earn no interest, they are by no
means "free" of costs to the banks. The operating costs of
handling such deposits must be covered—but this is also
true of other deposits.




- 23 The impact of such bidding can be seen clearly in the
banks1 operating results.

Figures which help in assessing this

impact are given in Table 6, showing income, expenses, and dividends
for insured commercial banks in 1961 and 1971.

It will be recalled

that, from the banks1 point of view, interest paid is an operating
expense.

In 1961, the banks1 total operating expenses amounted

to $7.4 billion, and these had climbed to $29.7 billion by 1971.
Included in these expenses were $2.1 billion of interest payments
in 1961 and $12.2 billion last year.

The interest on federal funds

pruchased amounted to $1.1 billion in 1971.

The banks also paid

$38 million of interest on other borrowed money in 1961 and $139
million in 1971.

In addition, in 1971, they paid out $142 million in
6/

interest on capital notes and debentures.
So .the combined interest payments made by the banks
represented about 30 per cent of their operating expenses in 1961.
By 1971, the proportion had risen to 46 per cent.

For deposits

alone, the figures were 28 per cent and 41 per cent, respectively.
These payments on deposits were equivalent to an effective rate of
interest on deposits of 2.7 per cent in 1961 and 4.8 per cent ten
years later.
The intensified market pressures faced by commercial banks
in the competition for funds have induced them to search for
6/




No figures were available separately showing interest payments
on federal funds and capital notes and debentures in 1961.

- 24 ways to adapt the methods they use to establish the rates they
charge to make the latter more responsive to market forces.

The

most widely noted development in this regard was the practice
adopted in November, 1971, under which several large banks tie
their prime lending rate to money market variables.
banks in this group are:

Principal

(1) First National Bank of Boston,

(2) Bankers Trust, New York, (3) First National City Bank, New
York, (4) Irving Trust, New York, (5) Mellon National Bank,
Pittsburgh, (6) Michigan National Bank, Detroit, and (7) Exchange
National Bank, Chicago.
A variety of explanations of their actions were given by
these banks when they shifted from a fixed to a floating lending
rate to be charged on loans to their best business customers.
Moreover, the specific money market variables employed and the
techniques used to link the prime rate to them also differed.

But

the common theme in the banks1 comments was a desire to make their
lending rates more responsive to market forces. ^^

To this end,

most of the banks adopting the floating rate approach linked their
own rates in some way to market yields on such short-term market
instruments as commercial paper and CD's.

Most of them also announced

that they would post changes in the rate on a weekly basis.
7/
~~

In passing, it might be noted that some observers thought the
move to floating rates was also partially motivated by the
desire to make changes in the prime rate less subject to political
criticism.




- 25 The emergence of floating prime rates has been commented
on many times, and on the surface there appears to be little more
to say about the matter.

The decision of one bank (Bankers Trust)

made a week or so ago to suspend its floating rate renewed the
discussion briefly.

However, most of the public comments which

followed seemed to have been generated by the bank's explanation
that it made the move in order to cooperate with the Administration
in pursuit of its economic policy objectives.
Thus, one might still ask whether the experience of these
half dozen banks with a floating prime rate cast any light on the
general responsiveness of commercial banks1 basic lending rate
to money market forces.
in the affirmative.

I believe that question should be answered

This conclusion is based on considerations

regarding the nature of competition among large banks as well as
on the statistical record.
The following figures as of December 31, 1971, will put the
issue in perspective (amounts in millions of dollars):

Category

Total
Deposits

Total
Loans

Business
Loans

535,703

345,386

117,603

30,878

21,222

11,385

All insured commercial
banks
Floating rate banks
Per cent of Total




5.74

6.14

9.66

- 26 These figures suggest that the floating prime rate banks1
impact on the market for business loans is likely to be considerably
greater than their impact in the economy as a whole.

At the end

of last year, their share of total loans was only slightly larger
than their share of total deposits.

However, their share of

business loans was significantly larger.
Data from another part of the statistical record also
supports the conclusion that floating rate banks are able to exert
considerable influence on the prime rates charged by other banks.
These data shown in Table 7 relate to the pattern and timing of
changes in prime lending rates during the last year.

In this

table the prevailing rates are divided into two classes:

fixed

rates for the majority of banks and a range of rates charged by
banks with floating rates.

The rate data are further analyzed to

see whether any judgment can be made with respect to any leadership
role which floating rate banks might seek to play.

The amount of

time elapsed before the majority of fixed rate banks brought their
own rates into line once a floating rate had been changed is
also shown.
Several points should be kept in mind when focusing on
these rate statistics.

The floating rate banks change their

rates in varying units such as 1/8 and 1/4 per cent.
changes weekly while others do so less often.

Some post

Consequently, on a

given date, two or more floating rates may be in effect at different




- 27 banks.

The range of floating rates indicated in Table 7 is designed

to encompass that situation.
The leadership role of floating prime rate banks in
determination of the prevailing rate is judged on the basis of
the extent to which the majority of fixed rate banks adjust their
own rates.

The floating rate banks are assumed to be "successful"

leaders when a rate change by one or more of the floaters establishes
a trend to a new rate level which is subsequently joined by the
majority of fixed rate banks.

A "failure" of leadership is

assumed to occur when one or more of the floaters makes a rate
change but the majority of fixed rate banks do not follow the move
8/
to confirm the change as a new, generally accepted rate.—

The

time lag in adjustment is the amount of time it took the fixed
rate banks to change to a new rate after such change has been
successfully led by the floating rate banks.
From an analysis of the rate data, several conclusions
were reached.

Beginning in November last year, the floating rate

banks did play a leadership role in the establishment of the prime
lending rate charged by the majority of banks.

From a prevailing

rate of 5-3/4 per cent set on October 20, 1971, the floating rate
8/




It will be noted that as used here successful "leadership"
requires that a rate move must establish a trend--e.g., mark
a change in level that was sustained. An alternative
view of leadership may apply to those cases where the move is
from one level to another but in the same direction as previous
leading moves. The latter view is not the one considered here

- 28 banks led a successful move on November 1 to reduce it by 1/4
to 5-1/2 per cent.

It took only 3 days for the majority of

banks to make the adjustment.

When a floating rate bank subsequently

reduced its rate to 5-3/8 on November 22, another floater not only
moved in the same direction a week later--but went down even
futher to 5-1/4 per cent.

However, in this instance, the majority

of banks kept their rate fixed at 5-1/2 per cent.

In fact, 39

days elapsed before the fixed rate banks again changed their
rate—bringing it down to 5-1/4 per cent on December 31.

In

the interval, the floating rate banks had moved in four steps to
reach the 5-1/4 per cent level.
In two subsequent actions, the floating rate banks cut
their prime rate to 4-3/4 per cent--the latter rate being posted
for the first time on January 17, 1972.

Yet, it required another

week for the fixed rate banks to give up their 5-1/4 per cent rate-and even then they moved only to 5 per cent.

The time lag involved

in this move from 5-1/4 to 5 per cent required 21 days.

On the

other hand, it took only 7 days for the fixed rate banks to drop
their rate to 4-3/4 per cent.

This was the low point by the fixed

rate banks in the downard rate movement.

At least one of the floating

rate banks got down as low as 4-3/8 per cent--set the same day the
fixed rate banks adopted a 4-1/2 per cent rate.

However, this 4-3/8

per cent floating rate lasted only two weeks, and by March 20, all
of the banks--floating and fixed rate—were together at 4-3/4 per cent.




- 29 But a week later, on March 27, the floating rate
banks launched an upward rate movement that continued until
after October 16.

On that March date, one floating rate bank

posted a rate of 4-7/8 per cent, and another set it at 5 per cent.
But no fixed rate banks made a change at that time.

However, on

April 5, the fixed rate banks adopted a 5 per cent rate (which
at least one floating rate bank had charged since March 27), and
all the floaters posted the same rate.

But this situation was

short-lived, for on April 17 a floating rate bank moved up to 5-1/4
per cent, and another moved up to 5-1/8 per cent two weeks later.
However, this latest phase of the upward movement in the prime
rate led by the floaters could not be sustained.

On May 30, all

of the floating rate banks moved back down to 5 per cent--the level
at which the fixed rate banks had remained.
On June 12, the climb in the prime rate resumed as one
floater posted a rate of 5-1/8 per cent.

On June 26 a 5-1/4 per

cent floating rate was adopted, and the fixed rate banks moved to
the same level.

This upward trend continued until August 7.

In

the interval, the floating rate had risen to 5-1/2 per cent--a
rate that was actually first posted by one bank on July 10.

However,

even some of floating rate banks lingered behind at 5-1/4 and 5-3/8
per cent, and all fixed rate banks kept their rate at 5-1/4 per
cent.

So on August 7, the floating rate bank quoting 5-1/2 per cent

gave up and moved down to 5-3/8 per cent.
cut their rates further to 5-1/4 per cent.




A week later, all floaters

- 30 The last segment of the upward movement in the prime
rate (which ended at least temporarily on October 16) got underway
on August 21--when a 5-3/8 per cent floating rate was posted.
Subsequently, in four moves, the floating prime rate was advanced
to 5-7/8.

However, the fixed rate banks remained at 5-1/4 per

cent until August 29—when they adopted 5-1/2 per cent.

The

latter rate was in place until October 4 — w h e n 5-3/4 per cent was
established, a rate that is still in effect.
On November 6, the floating prime rate was moved back
to 5-3/4 per cent from 5-7/8 per cent.

As already indicated,

that move was said to have reflected a desire of the bank involved
to cooperate with the Administration's economic objective.
What should we have learned from this review of the
statistical record?

We should have learned that the floating rate

banks can—and did—exert a leadership influence on the determination
of the prime rate.

But we should have also learned that their role

is far from dominant.

By the criteria employed here, they were

successful leaders in eight rate changes and failures in four cases.
Moreover, in only three of the successful cases did the fixed rate
banks adjust their rates in less than two weeks.
Beyond the statistics presented here, the nature of
competition among large banks for business customers also suggests
that the floating rate banks can play a leading role—but not a
dominant one.




As is generally known, the large banks service a

- 31 substantial number of the same customers.

In fact, some corporations

systematically rotate their borrowing among their principal banks
on a fairly fixed schedule.

Thus, these firms are highly conscious

of differences in the prime rate and can be expected to tailor
the pattern of borrowing with an eye to minimizing the cost of
money to them.

Consequently, a bank which sets its rate well above

its competitors will experience some loss in demand for loans.
opposite is also true:

The

if its rate is well below its competitors,

it will be faced with an expansion in loan demand—and with the
discomforting knowledge that it is providing funds at a rate below
what other lenders are gettingThus, the ability of corporate borrowers to shift among
lenders serves to dampen the extent to which large floating rate
banks can influence the establishment of the prime rate.

On the

other hand, the need for the banks themselves to bid for funds in
the money market means that market factors must necessarily have a
considerable impact on the interest rates they must charge their
customers.
VI.

Recent Developments in Capital Market Borrowing
At this juncture, we can review briefly the broad outlines

of capital market borrowing by major sectors during the last year.
For this purpose, preliminary data for the third quarter from the
Federal Reserve Board T s flow of funds accounts can be used.
are presented in Table 8.




The figures

- 32 The volume of funds raised in the capital market by major
sectors during the third quarter of 1972 was about the same as a
year earlier ($147•9 billion in 1971 and $151.8 billion this year).
However, the amount of borrowing by households rose sharply;

the

amount raised by the nonfinancial business sector recorded a sizable
decline, and borrowing by the Federal and State and local governments
also eased off somewhat.

On the other hand, the Federal Government

ran down its cash balances by a sizable amount last quarter in contrast
to a large build-up a year earlier.
In terms of capital market instruments, the volume of
State and local government securities and corporate and foreign
bonds declined moderately on a year-over-year basis.

In contrast,

all types of real estate mortgages rose--with home and commercial
mortgages registering particularly noticeable increases.

Corporate

equity shares showed quite a large decline.
Private credit raised without the use of market instruments
dropped by about one-fourth between the third quarter of 1971 and
the third quarter of this year.

The relative decrease centered in

commercial bank loans and open market commercial paper.
actual attrition in the latter of about $5-1/2 billion.)

(There was
On the

other hand, consumer credit registered a fairly large gain.
These summary credit flows are examined somewhat more closely
in the next section in connection with an assessment of the outlook
for credit demands in the months ahead.




- 33 VII.

Outlook:

Factors Affecting Prospective Credit Demands

In general, it appears that we might see a noticeable
moderation in the demands for funds registered in the capital
markets during the first part of the coming year.

This anticipation

is independent of any market impact that might result from the
recent national election or which might follow as the peace moves
regarding the Vietnam War continue.

The easing in credit market

demands is expected to be particularly noticeable in the case of
State and local governments, and demands by corporations are likely
to remain moderate.

On the other hand, the volume of borrowing by

the Federal Government in the first half of 1973 may be well above
that recorded in the same period this year.
Corporate long-term credit demands.

As corporations sought

to restructure their balance sheets after the liquidity crisis of
1969-70, total corporate security offerings rose to historical highs
in the last 3 years.

Even with long-term bond rates rising to new

peaks in the first half of 1970, public bond volume started tp increase
sharply as a large communications system began a sizable external
financing campaign.

The capital needs of public utility and communications

firms have provided a high base

of long-term credit demand in the

capital markets in the early 1970's, and the restructuring needs of
many large industrial corporations resulted in a peak public bond volume
of over $8 billion in the first quarter of 1971.

Although the continued

needs of the utlities and an unusual volume of debt offerings by banks




- 34 and other financial firms kept public bond offerings at historically
high levels well into the first half of 1972, public bond volume has
moderated significantly this year.
Total corporate security volume in 1972 has not declined
as sharply as public bond offerings.

In general, it appears that the

liquidity needs of many industrial firms—especially the large, highgrade firms—have been satisfied for now.

However, a number of

smaller, less prestigious corporations were still in the process of
balance sheet restructuring in late 1971 and 1972, and utility needs
for long-term capital remained high.

However, these borrowers have

often found it necessary or desirable to issue equity or privatelyplaced debt.

In the case of the utlities, concern about debt/equity

ratios, interest coverage ratios, and maintenance of high bond ratings
has stimulated a trend toward issuance of stock rather than bonds.
Many medium-sized and small industrial firms have also utilized the
stock market, and gross new equity volume has been averaging about $1
billion a month for almost 2 years.

The high cash flows enjoyed by

insurance companies in recent years have made available an abundant
supply of funds in the private placement market and stimulated a sharply
increased volume of such offerings in 1971 and 1972.
Given the good cash flow and liquidity position of corporations
in the aggregates, one may expect long-term credit demand from industrial
corporations to remain moderate over the next few months.

We may see

some seasonal increase in public bond volume in the first quarter of




- 35 1973 and a continued high level of offerings in the private placement
and equity markets.

According to most underwriters, relatively few

firms now plan to offer bonds either this year or in early 1973.

Only the

energy, communications, and transportation industries appear to have
pressing needs for capital funds, and it is probable that firms in
these industries will continue to meet some of these needs in the
equity and private placement markets rather than by issuance of public
bonds.
Long-term credit demands of State and local governments.
Long-term debt offerings by State and local governments also peaked
in the early 1970fs as a result of inflation, increased social needs,
and an almost inevitable catch-up process after the sharp drop in
tax-exempt financing which occurred during the period of severe
monetary restraint in 1969.

As in the corporate market, bond volume

set a new record in 1971 and then moderated in 1972 as the revenue
flows and liquidity position of most State and local governments
improved significantly.

Thus far in 1972, the pace at which general

obligation issues have been offered has slowed relatively more than that
of revenue bonds.
It appears that one still ought to expect further tapering
in municipal bond volume, with less than the usual seasonal rise
in the first quarter of 1972.

The favorable liquidity position that

many governments find themselves in, plus expectations of revenue
sharing funds which will be distributed in the near future, will




- 36 probably exert some downward pressure on long-term borrowing,
especially in the general obligation area.

Underwriters report a

large backlog of industrial pollution bonds, which will offset this
to some extent, but marketing of pollution bonds will probably rise
slowly because of the long market lead time required for such issues.
Home mortgage debt.

Net 1- to 4-family mortgage debt

formation reached a record seasonally adjusted annual rate of $39.5
billion in the third quarter of 1972.

However, the rate of increase

slowed moderately in that period—mainly as a lagged response to
a slowing of the quarterly increase in outlays for 1- to 4-family
construction.
We should expect 1- to 4-family mortgage debt formation to
rise moderately further in the fourth quarter of this year and then
level off in the first quarter of 1973.

The anticipated further slowing

in the uptrend in 1- to 4-family mortgage debt formation reflects an
expected leveling off in 1- to 4-family construction activity as well
as some moderation in activity in the existing home market.
Because of seasonal factors, net mortgage debt formation
tends to be lowest in the first quarter of a year.

Allowing for

this factor, net mortgage debt formation may be about one-third less
in next year's first quarter than in this year's third quarter—which
amounted to $10.6 billion, the record high on a seasonally unadjusted
basis.




- 37 Consumer credit growth to mid-1973.

Consumer credit

outstanding should continue to grow at a substantial rate throughout
1972 and into early 1973.

Extensions of consumer credit have been

strong throughout most of 1972 and should continue to be strong
through 1973.

The chief reason for this is that consumer credit

extensions are related to the level of economic activity and the
level of consumer optimism.

Both consumer optimism and level of

economic activity should be strong into the early part of 1973.
In addition, due to the combination of high consumer incomes
and enforced price restraint, domestic automobile demand should be
very strong into early 1973.

Not only are basic demand factors

favorable but the relative price of automobiles is probably more
favorable now than it would be in the absence of price restraint.
Furthermore, due to the recent strong level of housing starts
consumer demand for household furnishings and durable goods will tend
to be strong for the next several years.

Yet, due to the inclusion

of more durables in the purchase price of housing, the lagged demand
effect of housing starts on consumer credit demand now may be weaker
than formerly.
Finally, consumer optimism as measured by sentiment indexes
has recently risen substantially due to the decline in unemployment and
the slackening in the rate of inflation.

Since unemployment is expected

to continue to decline and the rate of inflation is not likely to return




- 38 to its former levels, consumer optimism should continue to be
strong.

Thus, the main forces which account for consumer credit

demand are strong and are likely to remain strong for the near
future.

In addition, monetary conditions have recently been

sufficiently expansive that there should be no serious limitation
in the supply of consumer credit in the near future.
Net cash borrowing by the Federal Government.

As mentioned

above, the Federal Government is the principal sector that is expected
to expand appreciably the volume of funds raised in the capital
markets in the

early months of next year.

This prospect seems

in store whether or not the Administration is successful in keeping
Federal outlays within the $250 billion target set for fiscal year
1973.

It will be recalled that, even with expenditures held at that

ceiling, the Government would probably run a deficit of about $23.5
billion.

Of course, cash borrowing could be well below the size of

the deficit because the Treasury's cash balance can be drawn down.
In the July-December period this year, Federal Government
net cash borrowing may be in the neighborhood of $15.0 billion—considerably
below the $21.6 billion registered in the same period a year ago.

About

two-thirds of the $15.0 billion of new cash may be raised in the fourth
quarter.
Looking ahead, Federal Government net cash borrowing may
amount to about $5.0 in the first half of calendar 1973.

In

the same period last year, about $2.1 billion of borrowing was repaid.




- 39 In fact, because of the typical pattern of Federal Government receipts
and expenditures, one might usually expect net repayment of debt
in the first half of each calendar year.

However, the experience over

the last five years has been far from usual.

In both 1968 and 1971,

the Government had to undertake net cash borrowing in the January-June
months ($4.2 billion and $3.2 billion, respectively).
Even so, if net cash borrowing reaches $5.0 billion in
the first half of 1973, the Federal Government will be a major force
in the capital markets next year.
VIII.

Summary and Conclusions
The main conclusions reached in this discussion have been

presented in each section.

However, it may be helpful to summarize

them here:




--The detailed analysis of the operating experience
of commercial banks in 1971 shows that a major share
of the fairly high interest rates charged on consumer
instalment loans is needed to cover high operating
costs and the risks of credit losses. However, even
after allowing for the cost of money to banks, a
fraction of the interest charge remains that cannot be
explained readily by the above factors.
--Instead, the relative absence of interest rate
competition among consumer credit lenders may account
for the remaining component. A similar situation
exists in the case of consumer loans extended by
finance companies—only more so.
--The proportion of debt outstanding in some sectors of
the United States that is subject to market-related
interest rates—rather than to rates set on an administered
basis—appears to be rising. The big exception is the
debt incurred by consumers.

- 40 --Commercial banks are finding it increasingly necessary
to bid for funds needed to carry on their business.
As a consequence, interest payments on borrowed money
have become a major element in their operating costs.
Given this impact of market forces on their sources
of funds, banks have sought increasingly to introduce
market considerations in determining the interest rates
which they charge large borrowers. In fact, the
practice adopted a year ago by several large banks
whereby their prime lending rate is linked to money
market variables is an overt manifestation of this
concern.
— I n the early months of 1973, credit demands registered
in the capital markets are likely to moderate considerably.
The demand for funds by the Federal Government may be
the only major exception to this outlook.

Having explored the above terrain, I am left with several
impressions.

With respect to interest rates paid by consumers, I am

personally convinced that we need much more competition among lenders.
It is for this reason that I have supported the entry of bank holding
companies into the finance company field.

While bank charges on

consumer loans are well above those on loans to businesses, they are
considerably below those charged by finance companies.

Of course,

the latter typically deal with less credit-worthy borrowers, and their
higher rates undoubtedly need to reflect this fact.

However, there

still seems to be scope for seeking a better balance between risks
and interest rates on consumer loans.
I am conscious of the rising cost pressures encountered by
commercial banks as they find it increasingly necessary to bid for
funds in the money market.




Clearly at least some part of their own

- 41 higher cost of money must be passed on to their own customers.
However, I am also concerned by the other side of the coin:

the

largest banks in the country are also becoming increasingly willing
to commit themselves to lend money to their best customers at
some unspecified future date.

They are making such commitments

with the expectation of being able to raise the funds wken needed
by competing for them in the money market.
It seems clear to me that—if this becomes the prevailing
practice over wide segments of the banking system--the effectiveness
of monetary policy as an instrument of national stabilization policy
will be severely weakened.




- 0 -

^^ile 1.

Interest Rates in Selected

Category

1961

1965

Cr

CD

Market

1966

'

1961

1969

*"1972
1970

1971

1972
(October)

Money Market Rates
Federal funds

1.96

4.07

5.11

8.22

7.17

4.66

5.00

Prime commercial paper
4 to 6 months

2.97

4.38

5.55

7.83

7.72

5.11

5.30

Finance co. paper, placed
directly
3 to 6 months

2.68

4.27

5.42

7.16

7.23

4.91

5.13

Prime, 90-day bankers accpt.

2.81

4.22

5.36

7.61

7.31

4.85

5.05

2.38
2.36

3.95
3.95

4.88
4.86

6.68
6.67

6.46
6.39

4.35
4.33

4.72
4.74

U.S. Government Securities
3-month bills
New issue
Market yield
6-month bills
New issue
Market yield
9 to 12 month issues
1 yr. bill (market yield)
Other
3- to 5-year issues
Long-term bonds

2.60
2.59

4.06
4.05

5.08
5.06

6.85
6.86

6.56
6.51

4.51
4.52

5.12
5.13

2.81
2.91
3.60
3.90

4.06
4.09
4.22
4.21

5.20
5.17
5.16
4.66

6.79
7.06
6.85
6.10

6.49
6.90
7.37
6.59

4.67
4.75
5.77
5.74

5.39
5.41
6.11
5.69

State and local Govft. sec.
Total
Aaa
Baa

3.60
3.27
4.01

3.34
3.16
3.57

3.90
3.67
4.21

5.73
5.45
6.07

6.42
6.12
6.75

5.62
5.22
5.89

5.24
5.03
5.45

4.35

4.50

5.43

7.71

8.68

7.62

7.38p

4.66

4.64

5.34

7.36

8.51

7.94

7.59p

4.35
5.08

4.49
4.87

5.13
5.67

7.03
7.81

8.04
9.11

7.39
8.56

7. 21p
8.06p

4.54
4.82
4.57

4.61
4.72
4.60

5.30
5.37
5.36

7.22
7.46
7.49

8.26
8.77
8.68

7.57
8.38
8.13

7.36p
7.97p
7.63p

5.97
6.04

5.74
5.87

6.14
6.30

7.66
7.68

8.27
8.20

7.60
7.54

7.70*
7.75*

- - -

5.76
5.89

6.11
6.24

7.81
7.82

8.44
8.35

7.74
7.54

7.56*
7.53*

FHA series (New)

5.97

5.83

6.40

7.99

8.52

7.75

7.70*

Secondary market
FHA insured (New)

5.69

5.47

6.38

8.26

9.05

7.70

7.56*

4.5

5.0

6.0

8.5

6.75

5.25

5-3/4 5-7/8

Corporate bonds
New Issue (Aaa utility)
Seasonal issues
Total
By selected rating
Aaa
Baa
By group
Industrial
Railroad
Public utility
Residential mortgages
Conventional first mtgs.
New homes
Existing homes
Home mortgage yields
Primary market (conv.)
FHLB Bd. series
New homes
Existing homes

Memorandum
Prime lending rate
Comm. banks (year-end)

Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin.
* Data is for September 1972.
 p indicates preliminary data.


Table 2.
Sector and Type of Loan

Interest Rates on Selected Loans to Households and Businesses, 1972
January

February

March

April

May

Jul*

August

10.02

September

Households
Bank Loans:
consumer 1/
Instalment credit
New automobiles (36 months)
Mobile homes (84 months)
Other consumer goods (24 months)
Other personal exp. (12 months)
Credit card plans
Finance Company Loans 4/
Automobiles: Total
New
Used
Mobile homes
Other consumer goods
Personal loans

10.26

10.20
10.88

10.94
12.57
12.74
17.11

12.50
12.72
17.13

13,.09
12,.07
16..17

13.06
11.99
16.27
—
—

10.12
10.61
12.43

12.60
17.20 2/

10.00
10.45
12.37
12.58
17.221'

9.96
10. 73
12.44
12.63
17.25

9.98
10.49
12.38
12.65
17.25

9.97
10.77
12.39
12.73
17.25

13.01
11.86
16.47
12.29
I*. 30
21.23

13.02
11.85
16.52

13..02
n . .84
16.>57
12.,26
19.,43
21.,24

13.04
11.85
16*62

7. 34

7.32

7.44

13.02
11.92
16.32
12.57
19.73
21.21

13..00
11..87
16..40

7. 21

7.28

7.23

—

10.71
12.47
12.72
17.25

10.02
10.67
12.47
12.70
17.25

—

Businesses
Bank loans
Small, short-term noninstal. 5/
Farm production loans, banks 1/
(less than I yr. maturity)
Feeder cattle operations
Other farm production
Operating expenses

7. 31

7.19

7.16

7.55

7.46

7.37

7.44

7.35

7.44

7.34

7.54

7.55

7.63

7.62

7.51

7.57

7.58

7.73

7.55

7.58

7.75

Bank Loans (By size and
maturity) 6/
Short-term
All sizes ($'000)
1-9
10-99
100-499
500-999
1,000 and over
Revolving credit
All sizes ($'000)
1-9
10-99
100-499
500-999
1,000 and over

6.16
5.60
5.31
5.18

Long-term
All sizes ($'000)
1-9
10-99
100-499
500-999
1,000 and over

5.64
6.98
6.85
6.19
6.13
5.44

Prime rate, banks 7/
Floating rate
1/

2/
3/
4/

5/
§/
7/

5.52
7.08
6.44
6.76
5.44
5.31

5.59
7.07
6.53
5.94
5.57
5.33

5.24

5.59
6.52

6.60

4-3/4
4-1/2-5

4-3/4
4-3/8-4-3/4

5
5-5-1/4

6.2 0
5.91
5.59

5.69
5.60
5.57

5.83
6.78
6.51
5.93
5.83
5.81

5.87
7.03
6.65

6.31
7.47
6.80

6.26

6.51

5.87
5.78

6.27
6.28

6.28

4-3/4
4-3/4-5

5.84
7.27
6.72

5
5

5-1/4
5-1/4
5-1/2
5-1/2
5-5-1/4 5-3/8-5-1/2 5-1/4-5-1/2 5-1/4-5-3/4

Interest rates in this category are based on a survey conducted jointly by the Federal Reserve System and the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation of loans made during the first full calendar week of each month by a sample of 370 insured
commercial banks.
They represent simple unweighted averages of the "most common" effective annual rate reported by
respondents in each loan category.
The "most common" rate is defined as the rate charged on the largest dollar volume of
loans in the particular category during the week covered in the survey. Consumer instalment loan rates are reported on a
Truth-in-Lending basis as specified in the Federal Reserve Board's Regulation Z.
Includes upward revisions of data for a few respondents to correct reporting errors. Revisions not carried back, and March
data therefore are not fully comparable with earlier months.
Includes upward revisions of data for one respondent to correct a reporting error. Revisions not carried back, and April data
are therefore not fully comparable with earlier months.
Interest rates on automobiles are finance rates on new and used car instalment credit contracts purchased from dealers
by major automobile finance companies.
Interest rates on mobile homes, other consumer goods, and personal loans are
compiled from a bimonthly survey conducted by the Federal Reserve Board. For mobile homes and other consumer goods, the
data cover contracts purchased by finance companies, primarily from retail outlets; for personal loans, they cover secured
and unsecured loans made directly by finance companies for household, family, or other personal expenditures.
Loans of $10,000 to $25,000 maturing in one year or less.
Data are from the Federal Reserve Board's "Quarterly Survey of Interest Rates on Business Loans."
Beginning November, 1971, several banks adopted a floating prime rate keyed to money market variables.
The first rate
shown is that charged by the majority of commercial banks;
the second is the range of rates charged by those banks with a
floating rate. Rates recorded are those prevailing on the last day of the month.




Table 3

Rates of Return and Operating Costs in Commercial Bank Lending, By Size of Bank, 1971
(Size: [ \ l Deposits. Rates are percentages of^^lume outstanding.)

O
Category

Up to $50 million
(684 banks)

1

$50-200 million
(231 banks)

Over $200 million
(79 banks)

Total Loans
Gross yield
Less-expense
Net yield before losses
Losses
Net yield after losses
Cost of money
Net yield after cost of money

8.255
1.980
6.274
.107
6.167
3.694
2.473

8.082
1.907
6.175
.120
6.055
3.438
2.617

7.994
880
114
154
960
346
2.614

Real estate mortgage loans
Gross yield
Less-expense
Net yield before losses
Losses
Net yield after losses
Cost of money
Net yield after cost of money

7.047
.806
6.242
.029
6.213
3.906
2.307

7.101
.686
6.414
.024
6.391
3.662
2.729

7.422
.617
6.829
.031
6.798
3.609
3.189

Consumer instalment loans
Gross yield
Less-expense
Net yield before losses
Losses
Net yield after losses
Cost of money
Net yield after cost of money

10.417
3.501
6.915
.354
6.561
3.801
2.960

10.169
3.445
6.725
.363
6.362
3.558
2.804

10.690
3.891
6.799
.369
6.430
3.500
2.930

Credit card loans
Memo: Number of banks
Gross yield
Less-expense
Net yield btrore losses
Losses
Net yield after losses
Cost of money
Net yield after cost of money

136
17.180
17.142
.038
1.962
- 1.924
3.676
- 5.600

101
17.951
14.215
3.736
1.953
1.783
3.484
- 1.701

54
18.862
14.431
4.431
2.682
1.749
3.369
- 1.620

Commercial and other loans
Gross yield
Less-»expense
Net yield before losses
Losses
Net yield after losses
Cost of money
Net yield after cost of money

7.557
1.377
6.180
.240
5.940
3.767
2.172

7.311
1.113
6.199
.254
5.945
3.513
2.432

7.052
.912
6.140,
.304
5.835
3.500
2.335

Investments
Gross yield
Less-expense
Net yield before cost of money
Cost of money
Net yield after cost of money

6.674
.155
6.519
3.801
2.718

6.567
.112
6.454
3.559
2.895

6.729
151
6.578
3.500
3.078

7.590
1.213
6.377

7.459
1.168
6.290

7.513
1.223
6.290

3.801
2.576

3.558
2.732

3.500
2.790

Portfolio, loans and investments
Gross yield
Less-expense
Net yield before cost of money
(taxable basis)
Cost of money
Net yield after cost of money

Source:

Federal Reserve Board. Functional Cost Analysis: 1971 Average Banks.
Ratios based on data for 994 participating member banks in Twelve Federal
Reserve Districts.




Table 4:

1961
Subject
to
AdminTotal
istered
Outstanding
Rates
Total Outstanding
Household JL/
Consumer Credit
Instalment
Other
Home Mortgages
Other Bank Loans, NEC
Security Loans
Deferred & Unpaid Insurance Prem.
Business
Corporate Bonds
Mortgages
Home
Multifamily
Commercial
Bank Loans, NEC 2/
Open Market Paper
Finance Co. Loans
U.S. Government Loans
Trade Debt
Other Liability
Government
State and Local
Short-term
Long-term
A
U.S. Government
Marketable
Bills
Certificates
Notes
Bonds
Non-Marketable
Savings Bonds
Special Issues
Trust
Foreign
Other

792,,862
223,,046
57,,982
A3,,891
14,,091
147,,678
8,,138
6,,736
2,,512

388,,625
216,,310
57,,982
43,,891
14,,091
147,,678
8,,138

236,,954
79,,952
35 ,967
1 ,146
11 ,178
23 ,643
38 ,133
1 ,541
2 ,525
922
53 ,888
24 ,026

118,,115

332 ,862
76 ,062
3 ,636
72 ,426
256 ,800
158 ,600
39 ,500
3 ,700
50,,200
65,,200

54 ,200

98,,200
47,,400
44,,000
43,,500
500
6,,800

54,,200
47,,400

—

2,,512

—

1,,146
1,,146
—
—

38 ,133

Amount Outstanding (Millions)
1971
Subject
Subject
to
to
AdminMarket
Total
istered
Rates
Outstanding
Rates
404,,237
6,,736

1,556,,880
475,,875
137,,237
109,,545
27,,692
296,,117
25,,773
11,,180
5,,568

806,,054
464,,695
137,,237
109,,545
27,,692
296 ,117
25,,773

582,,102
187,,305
89,,046
2,,615
23,,014
63,,417
101,,807
9,,577
13,,562
1,,604
119,,276
59,,925

285,,227

278 ,662
76 ,062
3 ,636
72 ,426
202 ,600
158 ,600
39 ,500

498,,903
166,,471
19,,179
147,,292
332 ,432
173 ,400
65,,900

56 ,132

3,,700
50,,200
65 ,200

69,,300
38,,200

—

—

—
—
—

6,,736
-

118,,839
79,,952
34,,821
—

11,,178
23,,643
—

—

1,,541

—

2,,525

922
53 ,888
24 ,026

—
—

54 ,200
—
—

—
—
—

6,800

Debt Outstanding by Type and Sector and Interest Rate Determination:
Administered vs. Market
(Amounts in Millions of Dollars)

—

—
-

44,000
—

44,000
43,500
500
—

159,032
53,832
102,900
85,500
17,400
2,300

—

5,,568

—

2,,615
2,,615
—
—

101 ,807
—
—

1 ,604
119 ,276
59,,925

—
—
—

56 ,132
-

—

-

56,132
53,832

__

Subject
to
Market
Rates
750,,826
11,,180
—
—
—
—
—

11 ,180
-

296,,875
187 ,305
86,,431
—

23,,014
63,,417
—

9 ,577
13,,562
--

—
-

442 ,771
166 ,471
19 ,179
147 ,292
276 ,300
173 ,400
65,,900
69,,300
3fi.200
102,900

__
85,500
17,400

2,300

1/

Includes some data for personal trusts and non-profit organizations. The line items selected for
this part of the table are believed to contain data mostly attributable to the household sector.

2/

With the exception of those banks which follow a floating prime rate.

3/

Percentages are otnitted when all of outstandings belong to one category.

Source:

Federal Reserve Board




Percentage Distribution of Amount Outstanding
1961
Subject
Subject
to
Subject
to
Adminto
Administered
Total
Market
istered
Total
Rates
Outstanding
Rates
Rates
Outstanding
100.00
28.14
7.31
5.54
1.78
18.63
1.03
.85
.32

100.00
55.66
14.92
11.29
3.63
38.00
2.09

29.88
10.08
4.53
0.14
1.41
2.98
4.81
0.19
0.32
0.12
6.80
3.03

30.39

41.98
9.59
0.46
9.13
32.39
20.00
4.98
0.47
6.33
8.22

13.95

12.39
5.98
5.55
5.49
0.06
0.86

13.95
12.20

100.00
30.57
8.81
7.03
1.78
19.02
1.65
.73
.36

100.00
57.66
17.03
13.59
3.44
36.74
3.20

37.38
12.03
5.72
0.17
1.48
4.07
6.54
0.62
0.87
0.10
7.66
3.85

35.38

68.94
18.82
0.90
17.92
50.11
39.23
9.77
0.91
12.42
16.13

32.05
10.69
1.23
9.46
21.36
11.14
4.23

6.96

10.88

10.22
3.46
6.61
5.49
1.12
0.15

100.00
1.67
------

1.67
.65

0.29
0.29

29.39
19.78
8.61

__

--

9.81

--

__

0.38
0.62

0.24
13.87
6.18

13.95
--

----

1.75

2.76
5.85

---

10.88
10.76
0.12
--

4.46
2.45

--

Subject
to
Market
Rates
100.00
1.49

Per cent of Total Outstanding^/
1971
1961
Subject
Subject
to
Subject
to
Subject
Adminto
Adminto
Istered Market
istered
Market
Rates
Rates
Rates
Rates
48.23
2.35

49.02
96.98

50.98
3.02

51.71
97.65

49.85

50.15

49.00

51.00

3.19

96.81

2.94

97.06

16.28

83.72

11.25

88.25

21.11

78.89

16.88

83.12

55.19

44.81

35.30

64.70

-----

1.49

.69

--

0.32
0.32
—

--

12.63
---

0.20
14.80
7.44

--

i---

6.96
---

39.54
24.95
11.52
--

3.07
8.45
--

1.27
1.80
---

58.97
22.17
2.55
19.62
36.80
23.10
8.78

--

—

--

9.23
5.09

—

6.96
6* 68

13.70

--

13.70
11.39
2.31

---

0.28

--

--

Table 5.

Liabilities of All Insured Commercial Banks in the United States*
(Dollar amounts in millions; ratios in per cent)
Dec. 30,
1961

Liability Item
Savings deposits
Time deposits
Negotiable CD's
Time deposits less negotiable CD's

Dec. 31,
1971

$ 63,685
18,770
1/
1/

$ 111,475
163,151
33 951
129,200

164,721

261,077

2/
462
2/
1,689
5,185

24,177
1,451
655
4,038
16,617

2/
4/

4
6,429

Total capital accounts
Capital notes and debentures
Equity capital - total
Preferred stock
Common stock
Surplus
Undivided profits
Other capital reserves

22,088
22
22,067
15
6,571
10,783
4,153
545

46,731
2,938
43,793
92
11,762
19,829
11,101
1,009

Total liabilities and capital

276,600

635,805

88,123

320,464

Demand deposits - total
Federal funds purchased and securities sold
under agreements to repurchase
Other liabilities for borrowed money
Mortgage indebtedness
Bankers' acceptances outstanding
Other liabilities

3/

Minority interest in consolidated
subsidiaries
Total reserves on loans and securities

Interest - bearing liabilities

5/

Ratio of interest - bearing liabilities
to total liabilities and capital

*

31.9

50.4

Continental U.S. only.

1/ Not reported separately prior to 1964; subsequently at weekly reporting banks only.
2/

Not reported separately in 1961.

3/

Reported as "rediscounts and other borrowed money11 in 1961.

4/

Not included in balance sheet prior to 1969.

5/ Total liabilities and capital minus demand deposits, bankers' acceptances outstanding,
~~ minority interest in consolidated subsidiaries, total reserves, and equity capital - total.




TabLe 6.

Income, Expenses, and Dividends of Insured Commercial Banks"
(Dollar amounts in millions; ratios in per cent)

Income item
Operating expenses - total
Interest paid on:
Deposits
Federal funds purchased
securities sold under
agreement to repurchase
Other borrowed money
Capital notes and debentures

1961

1971

1/ 7,440

29,651

2,107

12,218

2/
/ 38
_1/

1,096
139
142

Ratio to total operating expenses
Interest paid on:
Deposits
Federal funds purchased
and securities sold
under agreements to
repurchase
Other borrowed money
Capital notes and
debentures

28.3

41.2

2j
2/0.5

3.7
0.5

1/

0.5

2.7

4.8

Interest on time and savings
deposits to time and
savings deposits
(Time
and savings
deposits
outstanding
- in millions)

3/ (77,659)

3/ (255,655)

* U.S. and other areas
1/ "Interest on capital notes and debentures" and "Provision for loan losses" not included in
"operating expenses-total" prior to 1969.
2/ "Interest on Federal funds purchased, etc." was included in "Interest on borrowed money"
prior to 1969.
3/ For 1961 averages of amounts for four consecutive official call dates beginning with the
end of the previous year and ending with the fall call of the current year. For 1971,
averages of amounts reported at beginning, middle, and end of year.




Table

Effective Date

7.

Prime Rates Charged by Hanks: Floating vs. Fixed Rates
October 20, 1971 to November 6, 1972

Floating Rate Range 1/
(per cent)

Fixed Rate 2/
(per cent)

Leadership Role of
Floating Rate Banks 3/
Success

October 20, 1971
November I
November 4
November 8
November 22
November 29
December 6
December 27
December 31

5-3/4
5-5/8-5-3/4
5-1/2-5-5/8-5-3/4
5-1/2
5-3/8-5-1/2
5-1/4-5-1/2
5-1/4-5-3/8-5-1/2
5-1/4-5-1/2
5-1/4

5-3/4
5-3/4
5-1/2
5-1/2
5-1/2
5-1/2
5-1/2
5-1/2
5-1/4

January 3, 1972
January 17
January 24
January 31
February 28
March 13
March 20
March 27
April 3
April 5
April 17
May 1
May 30
June 12
June 26
July 3
July 10
July 17
July 31
August 2
August 7
August 14
August 21
August 25
August 29
September 4
September 5
September 11
September 25
October 2
October 4
October 16
November 6

5-5-1/8-5-1/4
4-3/4-5
4-5/8-4-3/4-5
4-1/2-4-3/4-5
4-3/8-4-1/2-4-3/4
4-1/2-4-3/4
4-3/4
4-3/4-4-7/8-5
4-3/4-5
5
5-5-1/4
5-5-1/8-5-1/4
5
5-5-1/8
5-5-1/4
5-1/4-5-3/8
5-1/4-5-3/8-5-1/2
5-1/4-5-1/2
5-3/8-5-1/2
5-1/4-5-3/8-5-1/2
5-1/4-5-3/8
5-1/4
5-1/4-5-3/8
5-1/4-5-3/8-5-1/2
5-1/4-5-3/8-5-1/2
5-1/4-5-1/2
5-1/2
5-1/2-5-5/8
5-1/2-5-5/8-5-3/4
5-3/4
5-3/4
5-3/4-5-7/8
5-3/4

5-1/4
5-1/4
5
4-3/4
4-3/4
4-3/4
4-3/4
4-3/4
4-3/4
5
5
5
5
5
5-1/4
5-1/4
5-1/4
5-1/4
5-1/4
5-1/4
5-1/4
5-1/4
5-1/4
5-1/4
5-1/2
5-1/2

1/
2/
3/
~~

4/
""

5-1/2
5-1/2
5-1/2
5-1/2
5-3/4
5-3/4
5-3/4

Time Lag in Adjustment
of Fixed Rate Banks 4/
(days)

Failure

39
X

21

X

7

14

23

Floating prime rates are defined as those rates charged by large banks which announce that they
will tie their prime lending rates to money market variables. Data are necessarily fragmentary
since some banks that float their rates do not announce their prime rates.
Fixed rates are the prime rates charged by the majority of banks.
Floating rate banks are assumed to play a "successful" leadership role when a rate change by one or
more of the floaters establishes a trend to a new rate level which is subsequently joined by the
majority of fixed rate banks. A "failure" of leadership is assumed to occur when one or more
of the floaters makes a rate change but the majority of fixed rate banks do not follow the move
to confirm the change as a new, generally accepted rate.
The time lag in adjustment is the amount of time it takes the fixed rate banks to change to a
new rate after such change has been successfully led by the floating rate banks.




Table 8. Funds Raised in the Capital Market, Third Quarter, 1971--Third Quarter, 1972
(Billions of Dollars)
1971
III
Total Funds raised by nonfinaneial
sectors

IV

I

1972
II

IIIp

173.7

164.1

145.4

156.2

162.5

25.9
25.6
0.3

31.4
30.6
0.8

6.4
4.2
2.2

16.0
14.6
1.5

15.7
12.8
3.0

147.9
17.0

132.7
11.4

139.0
10.3

149.6
15.9

151.8
11.1

130.9

121.2

128.7

133.7

137.7

Debt capital instruments
State and local government securities
Corporate & foreign bonds
Mortgages
Home mtg.
Other residential
Commercial
Farm

89.7
19.2
15.9
54.6
32.1
8.8
11.5
2.2

91.2
17.7
18.8
54.6
31.4
9.3
11.7
2.3

82.6
16.7
12.9
52.9
28.7
8.7
12.9
2.6

94.7
14.3
14.7
65.8
38.1
9.9
14.9
2.9

105.7
17.6
14.7
68.3
39.5
10.6
15.3
2.8

Other private credit
Bank loans, nec.
Consumer credit
Open-market paper
Other

41.1
23.6
12.6
2.2
2.8

30.1
12.4
14.5
- 3.0
* 6.1

46.1
20.6
13.3
2.9
8.6

39.0
16.9
17.5
0.3
4.2

32.0
16.9
18.6
- 5.5
5.1

147.9
8.0
20.2
46.8
72.9
57.5
10.6
4.9

132.7
3.6
18.0
55.1
55.9
42.8
8.8
4.3

139.0
4.2
17.8
49.2
67.8
53.9
10.1
3.9

149.6
1.5
14.7
61.4
72.0
56.4
10.7
4.9

146.8
3.0
18.0
66.5
59.3
44.8
9.7
4.8

3.4

11.8

- 10.7

4.1

- 5.0

170.4
22.5

152.3
19.6

156.1
17.1

161.5
11.9

167.5
20.7

U.S. Government
Public debt
Budget agency issues
All other nonfinancial sectors
Corporate equity shares
Debt instruments

By Borrowing Sector
Foreign
State and local Government
Households
Nonfinancial business
Corporate
Nonfarm noncorp.
Farm
Memo: U.S. Government cash balaTotals: net of changes in U.S. C "ernmenf.
cash balances
Total funds raised
By U.S. Government
Source: Federal Reserve Board, FLow of Funds Section
p « preliminary.