View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
Monday, October 25, 1971
10:00 a.m., P.S.T. (1:00 p.m., B.S.T.)




COMMERCIAL BANK LENDING AND MONETARY MANAGEMENT

Remarks by

Andrew F. Brimmer
Member

Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System

Before the

57th Annual Fall Conference
of the

Robert Morris Associates

Century Plaza Hotel
Los Angeles, California

October 25, 1971

COMMERCIAL BANK LENDING AND MONETARY MANAGEMENT
By

Andrew F. Brimmer*

I was delighted to accept the invitation to participate in
this Annual Meeting of the Robert Morris Associates.

The request to

me indicated that I might address myself to any subject.

However,

because the typical member of this Association is primarily concerned
with bank commercial loans, it was thought that a discussion of monetary
policy in relation to bank lending would be of particular interest.
Moreover, with the introduction of the Administration's New Economic
Policy in mid-August, such a topic has undoubtedly become even more
appealing.
I recognize the concern of the organization's members, and
I would like very much to respond to it.

Unfortunately, however, it

would be impossible for me to discuss prospective developments in
monetary policy,

By long tradition (which I support), Members of the

Federal Reserve Board do not speculate in public about the future
course of monetary policy.

The reason is simple:

the seven members,

^Member, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.
I am grateful to several members of the Board's staff for assistance
in the preparation of these remarks. Mr. Frederick M. Struble helped
with the analysis of banks' asset preferences and lending behavior.
Mr. Peter J. Feddor was responsible for the computer programming on
which the study of asset preferences and lending behavior is based.




-2-

along with the Presidents of five of the Federal Reserve Banks, also
serve on the Federal Open Market Committee; through their votes, they
help determine the objectives and content of monetary policy.

Thus,

in my own public comments, I try to avoid giving any indications which
might be taken as a forecast of my own views about the appropriate
targets of Federal Reserve monetary policy.
So, rather than respond to what I recognized as a natural
interest, I would like to focus again on a problem that has troubled
me a great deal during the 5-1/2 years that I have been a Member of
the Federal Reserve Board.

That problem is the differential impact of

changing credit conditions on the availability of credit in particular
sectors of the economy.
widely recognized.
inflationary

The general features of this problem are

During periods of strong credit demands and

pressures (such as 1966 and 1969-70), Federal Reserve

monetary policy ordinarily assumes a posture of substantial restraint.
However, the impact of this restraint is felt most unevenly by various
groups of borrowers in the country.

Some borrowers (most notably the

largest business concerns) are able to obtain most (or at least a
large share) of the funds they require to continue their activities
particularly investment in plant expansion.

—

In contrast, other borrowers

(especially State and local governments and families attempting to
purchase homes) are severely rationed in their efforts to obtain credit.
The effects on spending and output that result from this disproportionate
shift in the distribution of loanable funds are no less apparent.




-3Business spending on plant and equipment and on inventories continues
at a pace essentially unchanged from that prevailing prior to the
adoption of a restrictive credit policy; and the expansion continues
long after spending by State and local governments -- and particularly
by home buyers -- has been severely retarded.
This is a familiar story, and the explanation of the outcome
is also widely known:

the institutional rigidities of housing finance

(derived from the inflexibility of the mortgage as a debt instrument
and the limited ability of savings and loan associations to compete
for funds), combined with the reluctance of home buyers to pay marketdetermined rates of interest, serve to erect formidable obstacles to
the continued flow of j&ands into residential construction during
periods of tight credit conditions.

Similar rigidities (notably

limitations on borrowing costs) inhibit the ability of State and local
governments to compete in the capital market.

Numerous proposals have

been advanced to cope with the situation by lessening barriers and
stabilizing the flow of funds into specific sectors.

Some of these

have been adopted, and a few have resulted in improvements.
Nevertheless, the problem remains an urgent one, and much
of the debate over the issue continues to focus on the role of the
Federal Reserve.

This is not surprising because the reduced avail-

ability of funds in the adversely affected sectors becomes most
evident as market forces respond to monetary restraint.




Of course, one

-4can contend that the objective of monetary policy is to impose general
restraints on borrowing and place the blame for the differential impact
which it actually has on rigidities in housing finance and state and
local borrowing limitations.
this position.

And there is an element of truth in

Nonetheless, if the impact of monetary policy consis-

tently affects specific sectors of the economy and just as consistently
leaves other sectors unaffected, then it is also true that whatever
its intent, the effect of monetary policy is specific rather than
general.

It is recognition of this fact that has led many observers

to feel that they need to look no farther than Federal Reserve policy
for an explanation -- and remedy of this problem.
When the Federal Reserve is called upon to devise a solution,
it is really being asked to "do something11 to insure greater stability
in the allocation of commercial bank credit over the cycle.
on the commercial banks is by no means misplaced.

This focus

While other insti-

tutions may play a larger overall role (in terms of total lending) in
certain markets than commercial banks, changes in the volume of funds
supplied by the latter over a fairly short period of time can have a
disproportionate impact on the level of spending in particular sectors.
And the principal beneficiary of such shifts in the availability of
funds is the corporate business sector.
But, as I emphasized above, this is not a new situation

—

and taken alone it would not justify a discussion on the crowded
agenda of this Annual Meeting.

However, there are forces at work

behind the familar facade which are less readily recognized but whose
potential effects on the Nation's financial system could be considerable;




-5and the lending behavior of commercial banks is the fulcrum of the
situation.

In fact, the situation is roughly analogous to that of

an iceberg:

the proportion below the surface greatly exceeds that

which is visible at first glance.

What can be seen readily is the

changing availability of funds in particular sectors as commercial
banks respond to monetary restraint. What is less visible is the
mosaic

of relations between banks and corporations which virtually

guarantees that bank loans to business firms will be substantially
insulated from monetary restraint.
The natural preference which banks have for business loans is
attributable in part to their high profitability.

This attraction is

reinforced by a pattern of customer relationsips that makes it difficult
for banks to decline requests for business loans.

Moreover, the historic

and continuing interest between commercial bank lenders and business
borrowers has been strengthened further by the rapidly spreading
tendency of banks to make forward commitments to lend to such customers.
The latter, in turn, are becoming increasingly willing to pay a fee
to ensure accommodation.

To meet such commitments, banks have become

far more prepared to compete for loanable funds (both at home and
abroad) and to pay whatever interest rates the money market may set.
The net result is a linkage of banks and business which dampens the
effectiveness of monetary policy and makes more difficult the
management of national economic policy in the United States.




-6-

The evidence supporting this conclusion is presented below.
The highlights can be summarized here:




- To a considerable extent, the striking shifts
in the availability of credit in key sectors of
the economy in recent years can be traced in part
to the lending behavior of commercial banks as they
responded to the changing requirements of monetary
policy. Moreover, a significant part of the
instability in the composition of commercial bank
credit flows, in turn, can be traced to the activity
of roughly 20 multi-national banks (which are an
integral part of the Euro-dollar market) and
about 60 larger banks which are dominant in their
regions.
- Commercial banks have a marked tendency to
prefer loans to business firms over loans to
other sectors of the economy. The preference
for business loans rises progressively as the
size of banks increases, with the largest banks
having more than one-third of their total earning
assets represented by such loans. Moreover,
the preference for business loans at the
largest banks appears to have strengthened over
the last five years.
- This strong preference by banks for business
loans is partly the result of the relatively
high profitability of such loans. However, the
preference is reinforced by a network of customer
relationships which substantially insulates
bank credit to business from the impact of
monetary restraint.
- In the last year or so, these linkages between
banks as lenders and businesses as borrowers have
been increasingly strengthened by the spreading
tendency of banks to make commitments to lend in
the future. Frequently a fee is paid by the potential borrower. The result is a significant reduction
in the banks1 ability to manage their assets in a
flexible manner. It may also mean a reduction in
the ability of the Federal Reserve to influence
spending in the private sector in the interest of
economic stability.

-7Fortunately, if the economic stabilization program
that was recently introduced serves to curb inflation to the extent
we hope it will, I believe there is a good chance that we can
for some time avoid having to face the kinds of conditions that
necessitate severe credit restraint.

Thus, the need to establish

arrangements to ameliorate the problems created by the differential
effects of monetary restraint would appear unlikely to become
acute in the immediate future.

Nevertheless, I believe that the

best time to confront and resolve a potential problem is well
before it is likely to arise.

Monetary Policy and Commercial Bank Lending in Recent Years
The differential impact of monetary policy on particular
types of credit flows can be seen clearly in the record for the last
few years.

It will be recalled that, as a by-product of the policy

of severe monetary restraint followed in 1969, a striking change
occurred in the pattern of credit flows compared with that for the
previous year.

In 1970, to a considerable extent, such credit flows

returned to more traditional channels.




Of course, the policy of

-8-

monetary restraint in 1969 itself was an integral part of the national
campaign to check inflation.

In the same vein, the policy of moderate

easing in credit conditions was part of our national effort to cushion
the slowdown in the economy and thereby prevent a large decline in
production and an unacceptable rise in unemployment.

Thus, in both

1969 and 1970, the pattern of credit flows was a by-product of concerted efforts to attain the nation1s economic objectives.
Of course, the most graphic picture of the impact of monetary
policy on credit flows can be seen in the behavior of commercial banks.
The figures in Table 1 (attached) can be used for this purpose.

In

1969, commercial banks' liabilities (the key to their lending ability)
rose by roughly two-fifths as much as in the preceding year.

The primary

reason for the lag was a noticeable loss of time deposits -- especially
negotiable certificates of deposits in denominations of $100,000 and
over (CDfs).

The latter experience, in turn, was due to the decision

of supervisory authorities to hold the maximum rates of interest which
could be paid on time deposits below sharply rising market yields.

In

1970 (and particularly after mid-year when the ceilings were suspended
with respect to CD's with maturities of less than 90 days), interest
rates offered by the banks were again competitive with market yields -which were declining sharply -- and the banks gained funds.
The figures in Table 1 also show the sharp changes in uses of
commercial bank funds in recent years.

In 1969, total bank credit

expanded by less than half the amount recorded the previous year.
However, the rise in bank loans in 1969 was about as large as that




-9recorded the year before.

To meet this private demand for credit,

the banks liquidated a sizable amount of U.S. Government securities
and switched the funds into loans.

In 1970, the growth in bank credit

was nearly double that recorded in the preceding year.

But the over-

whelming proportion of the banks' funds went into investments, and
only a modest growth occurred in bank loans.

Finally, in 1969,

commercial banks pulled in a record amount of Euro-dollars through
their foreign branches in an effort to offset the loss of domestic
time deposits.

Last year, they employed a substantial portion of

their enlarged resources to repay liabilities to their foreign
branches.

Banking Structure and the Behavior of Bank Credit Flows
Early in 1970, I devised a framework of analysis which
allows one to study the lending behavior of commercial banks
according to the character of their business.—^

The framework was

constructed by recasting data for selected groups of large banks
which report to the Federal Reserve on a weekly basis.
Given the focus of these remarks, it might be helpful to
summarize here developments at these groups of banks during the last
few years.

The results of the regrouping are shown in Tables 2 and 3.

In this schema, I identified 20 banks as

l?

Multi-National Banks" and

1/ The approach was first described in "The Banking Structure
and Monetary Management," which I presented before the San Francisco
Bond Club, April 1, 1970.




-10another 60 banks as "Major Regional Banks.11

Those banks classed as

multi-national banks were picked on the basis of their size, volume
of business loans, importance in the Federal Funds market in particular and the money market in general, the volume of their foreign
lending, and the extent of their participation in the Euro-dollar
market.

Similar criteria were used to classify major regional banks,

but greater stress was given

to domestic activities and the relative

importance of these banks in their own area of the country.

The

remaining 250 weekly reporting banks were designated "Large Local
Banks."-/
The experience of these groups of banks with deposit flows
has differed considerably.

In 1968, the multi-national banks lagged

somewhat behind the other two groups in the expansion of deposits.
However, in 1969, both the multi-national banks and major regional
banks experienced deposit outflows that were relatively much more
severe than those recorded by the large local banks.

Yet, similar

relative changes were recorded in earning asset holdings, both
unadjusted and adjusted for loan sales, at all groups of banks.

This

similarity in total asset performance in the face of markedly different
deposit flows reflected greater flexibility among the largest banks in
developing alternative sources of lendable funds.

The two larger

groups of banks relied much more heavily on domestic nondeposit

2/ It should be remembered that the smallest banks in this
group have total deposits of at least $1Q0 million.




-11sources and siphoned substantially larger volumes of funds from the
Euro-dollar market.

The multi-national bankswere particularly heavy

borrowers in the Euro-dollar market.

The affiliates of multi-national

and major regional banks also sold a considerably larger volume of
commercial paper -- and in turn purchased larger quantities of loans -than did the large local banks.
General changes in the composition of asset portfolios were
somewhat more similar at these three groups of banks.

However, data

in Table 2 do indicate that the multi-national banks made relatively
larger reductions in their security holdings than did the other two
bank groups.

At the same time, after adjustment for loan sales, growth

in total loans and in business loans was much stronger at the
multi-national banks than at either the major regional or large local
banks in 1969.
The pattern of deposit and credit flows at these three groups
of banks in 1970 differed considerably from that recorded in 1969.
Referring again to Tables 2 and 3, it will be noted that the multinational banks gained a substantial volume of new deposits during the
year.

This growth, measured in relative terms, was considerably

stronger than that which occurred at the major regional banks, and
it was almost as strong as that recorded by the large local banks.




-12Yet, growth in earning assets (again in relative terms) at
the multi-national banks was only slightly below that recorded by the
major regional banks although it was considerably less than that which
occurred at the large local banks.

The explanation for the failure

of earning asset developments at the three groups of banks to match
more closely changes in deposits at these banks is that the multinational banks decided to use a large portion of their incoming
deposit funds to reduce nondeposit liabilities.

The large local

banks, on the other hand, channeled only a small portion of their
relatively large inflow of deposits to the repayment of nondeposit
liabilities while there was virtually no net change at major regional
banks.
A fairly diverse pattern of change in credit expansion can
also be seen in the statistical data for the three groups of banks.
It appears that loan demands, particularly business loan demands,
eased markedly at both the multi-national and major regional banks
during 1970.

Multi-national banks recorded a slight drop in their

total loans, adjusted for loan sales, and a somewhat larger decrease
in their business loans.

The major regional banks had a modest rise

in total loans (adjusted) and no net change in loans to business.
contrast, growth in total loans at the large local banks was much
stronger in 1970 than in 1969, and the rate of advance in business
loans was somewhat higher
recorded in 1969.




than the relatively sharp increase

All three groups of banks made net additions to

In

-13their investment portfolios during 1970.

However, growth at the multi-

national banks was substantially stronger than at the other groups of
banks.
The above analysis leads me to the following conclusion
regarding the relative impact that changes in monetary and credit
conditions have on different categories of banks and the ways
in which these different groups of institutions have adjusted to the
shifting deposit and loan circumstances:

The largest banks -- with

both domestic and foreign customers and which raise funds at home and
abroad -- are able to avoid a substantial share of the effects of
monetary restraint.
their earning assets.

Consequently they can maintain -- or even expand -The large regional banks can succeed almost

aJ well in pursuit of a similar course.

The large local banks,

although also much larger than the average bank in the country, can
do so to a much lesser extent.

But the net result of the overall

pattern of response of all of these large banks is a substantial
insulation of business loans from monetary restraint.

Asset Preferences of Commercial Banks
It is widely recognized that commercial banks channel a
major share of their lendable funds into loans to business firms.
However, the extent to which this is true is less widely appreciated.
To cast more light on the role of business loans in bank lending, the
composition of earning assets (total loans and investments) of all




-14insured commercial banks, as of June, 1966, June, 1970, and June, 1971,
was examined in considerable detail.

The results are shown in Tables

3/
4, 5, and 6.—

There is no need to discuss here the detailed findings.

However, several points should be made, for they throw considerable
light on the asset preferences of commercial banks.

The first

comments are based on the banks1 structure of earnings assets in
June, 1971, but the general pattern holds for each of the three
years.

The following generalizations can be made for each group of

banks:
- Small banks hold a larger proportion of their
earning assets in securities than do larger
banks: the ratio of total investments (mainly
U.S. Government and State and local issues)
to total earning assets declines continually
as the size group of banks increases. While
there are minor differences among various
classes of banks, the ratio generally drops
from about 40 per cent for the smallest
banks to about 27 per cent for the largest.
- Holdings of U.S. Treasury securities become
a progressively smaller proportion of total
earning assets -- and of total investments
held -- as the size of banks encrease.
- Holdings of State and local government
securities, expressed as a percentage of
total earning assets, is generally higher
at medium size banks than at either the
smallest or largest size group.

3/ In this part of the analysis, the 13,000-odd insured
commercial banks were grouped by deposit size, and 22 asset categories
were identified separately. For each individual bank, the ratio of a
particular asset category to the bank's total earning assets was calculated These ratios for individual banks were then averaged to obtain
ratios for each size group of banks. Data were obtained from the
Call Reports for June, 1966, June, 1970, and June, 1971.







-15- The ratio of total loans (including
Federal funds sold) to total earning assets
rises continually as the size of banks
increases. The ratio is about 60 per
cent for the smallest size group and rises
to about 75 per cent for the banks
at the top of the size scale.
- Of the various categories of loans,
business loans display the closest — and
clearest -- association with size of bank.
The relative importance of such loans compared
with total earning assets climbs progressively
and in tandem as the size of banks advances.
The ratio of business loans to total earning
assets rises from about 8 per cent at the
smallest size group to about 35 per cent at
the largest.
- A similar pattern -- although less
dramatic -- is evident in the case of
loans to financial institutions (banks,
nonbank financial institutions and
brokers and dealers) and in loans to
other investors for carrying securities.
These "financial11 loans rise from about
1 per cent at the smallest banks to about
10 per cent at the largest lenders.
- Loans to farmers as a percentage of total
earning assets decline as the size of bank
increases -- from around 17 per cent to
1 per cent,
- Real estate loans expressed as a proportion
of total earning assets are generally
highest at the medium size banks and lowest
at both the smallest and largest size groups
of banks. In general, such loans at the
largest banks amount to about 12 per cent of
total earning assets and to roughly 14 per
cent at the smallest. In contrast, at medium
size banks, the ratio was about 20 per cent.

-16- A similar "rainbow-shaped11 distribution of
loans to individuals can be observed, with the
ratios ranging from 14 per cent up to 19 per
cent and down to 9 per cent, respectively, for
the three size groups of banks.

Still further

insights into the lending behavior of commercial

banks can be gotten from an analysis of the changes in the composition
of their assets, by size of bank, between June, 1966, June, 1970, and
June 1971.




The following generalizations are applicable:
- Between 1966 and 1970, total investments
declined as a percentage of total earning
assets at all size groups of banks. The
extent of the decline was fairly uniform -ranging, in almost all instances, between
2 and 3 percentage points. However, in the
12 months ending last June, the proportion
of investments rose slightly.
- In the five-year period, U.S. Treasury issues
declined -- and other securities increased -in relative importance at all size groups of
banks.
- Total loans increased in relative importance
between 1966 and 1970. With respect to
business loans, there was little if any
change in relative importance -- except at
the very largest banks, where such loans
climbed a few percentage points in relation
to total earning assets. But in the last
year, as the demand for business loans
slackened somewhat, while deposit inflows
were strong, the proportion of loans in
the banks1 portfolios eased slightly.
- Real estate loans over the five-year period
decreased at the smallest size group of
banks and generally increased at the largest
size groups -- when expressed as a proportion of total earning assets. However, in
both cases, the changes were quite moderate
-- about 1 or 2 percentage points.

-17- Loans to individuals declined in relative
importance over the five-year period. The
proportionate decrease was evident at banks
in most size categories.

On the basis of the evidence yielded by this analysis of
commercial banks1 asset preferences, I reach the following conclusions:
the attraction of loans to business is so strong that one should ordinarily expect banks to respond to the fullest extent possible to the
demand for credit by business firms.

Experience indicates, moreover,

that in a period of severe monetary restraint, other sectors of the
economy are likely to obtain proportionately less -- while the business
sector obtains proportionately more -- of a given supply of commercial
bank funds.

Since the Federal Reserve must channel through the banking

system whatever additions to bank reserves it finds consistent with
overall monetary policy objectives, this suggests that the lending
behavior of commercial banks must be a matter of prime concern.

Network of Customer Relationships
The data reviewed above indicate the extent of the preferential
treatment that banks give their business customers.

Thus, if we are

to assure that banks1 lending behavior reinforces the basic aims of
monetary management, some means must be found to discourage banks from
favoring their business customers so disproportionately and to
encourage them to channel a larger share of their funds to other borrower
groups.

Personally I would prefer to see this objective achieved

through the voluntary decisions of bankers to alter their credit




-18allocation policies.

However, the factors militating against such a

voluntary change in the scale of bank preferences for different
assets are formidable indeed.

At the crux of the difficulty is the

network of linkages between banks and their business customers.
In part, the growth of business lending at the expense of
other forms of lending during periods of restraint is a reflection of
the success of commercial loan officers in building and cementing
relationships with business borrowers.

Many of these officers have

watched ventures grow and mature, in significant part because their
banks have provided much of the necessary financing and financial
expertise required for the successful development of an enterprise.
The experience gained in dealing with customers and solving financial
problems builds up a valued personal relationship.
Business customers that successfully approach a commercial
bank for loans in periods of restraint also very often have a record
of having provided the bank with a major source of revenue for long
periods of time.

Such customers often have maintained large deposit

balances while previously requesting little in the way of loan accommodation.

In addition, many of these firms also may be the customers of

auxiliary businesses of the bank, buying special data processing services
or using the services of leasing subsidiaries.

The bank's trust depart-

ment may also administer the customers1 pension fund, and their parent
or subsidiary companies may also maintain profitable relationships
with the lending institution.




-19These customer relationships may even be sufficient at times
to induce a bank to honor a loan request even though this can be done
only by incurring a substantial loss.

More often than not, however,

the return on such business loans, when appropriate account is taken
of compensating balance requirements, is quite attractive relative to
the return on other types of assets.

Thus, the inducement to honor

the loan requests of business customers is further reinforced.

Recent Developments in Loan Commitments
The customer relationships just described give rise to what
might be called "implicit commitments" on the part of banks to honor
customer loan requests.

These implicit commitments, however, are

commonly made explicit by more formal arrangements in the form of firm
or disclosed lines of credit.

While only the former of these agreements

may be legally binding, in effect both serve, when money is tight,
to convert a situation in which it is "good business" for the bank to
provide credit

into a situation in which the bank feels a moral

obligation to provide financing under the terms of the credit line
agreement.

Thus, formal loan commitments combine with the inducements

provided by a network of customer relationships and the high profitability
of business loans to make extremely difficult -- if not impossible -the decision to rechannel already reduce supplies of lendable funds
into assets other than credits to business firms.
It is the recognition of these considerations (which banks
find compelling) that leads me to be far from optomistic about the




-20prospects of achieving a shift in bank lending policies on a voluntary
basis.

In the past, when stringent credit conditions have arisen,

banks have been so committed -- either implicitly or explicitly -to honoring their business customer requests that it would have required
some form of governmental intervention in the decision process to
induce them to shift their selection of assets.

To state it simply,

when monetary restraint was imposed, banks were in an extremely
inflexible position vis-a-vis their business customers -- because of
decisions and arrangements made earlier.
However, this experience does provide us with a guide to
one condition that is a necessary requisite for obtaining a different
mix of credit flows on a voluntary basis.

At the very least, banks

must conduct their activities during periods of general credit ease
characterized by slack business loan demands so that when restrictive
credit conditions arise they retain some degree of flexibility in their
portfolio allocation decisions.
In my opinion, the question of flexibility in asset management is particularly critical at the present time.

Since early last

year, there has been a sizable build-up in loan commitments at commercial banks.

Surveys of loan commitments taken by the Federal Reserve

System during the last year and a half have strongly suggested that
banks have been expanding their commitment agreements at a very sharp
pace.

In part, this increase seems to be connected with uncertainties

in financial markets created by developments such as the Penn Central




-21-

and Lockheed crises.

But much of the movement in commitments seems

to be attributable to bank aggressiveness in seeking these arrangements.

I assume the objectives are to increase the volume of

business loans and to earn the fees and compensating balances associated
with the granting of commitments.
Of course, I know that bank managements do not expect to
have to meet all of their outstanding commitments.
canceled or are simply unused.

Many of these are

But it is equally true that a large

percentage of such commitment agreements is taken down.

Moreover, it

appears that the proportion of takedowns to total commitments has
been rising in recent years.

Thus, banks have been positioning them-

selves during this period of relative credit ease in such a way that
they would again be in a very inflexible position, if conditions of
credit restraint were to return.
Fortunately, in my judgment, the likelihood of circumstances arising that would bring about extremely tight conditions
in the immediate future is quite small.

Thus, with normal growth

in deposits, the potential problems created by the present commitment volume can be diminished.

However, to do so will require a

different ordering of bank preferences than that which has been
displayed to date.




-22Concluding Observations
As I indicated at the outset, for a number of years,
I have been concerned with the differential impact of monetary
policy on different sectors of the economy.

I have also urged that

means be found to moderate these adverse effects.

It was with this

objective in mind, and given the record of commercial bank lending
behavior, that I suggested in April, 1970, that consideration be
given to imposing a supplemental reserve requirement on loans
extended by banks.

The response to the proposal was vigorous --

and for the most part adverse.

The adverse reaction by Robert Morris

Associates was among the strongest -- and resulted in a speciallycommissioned critique of my position in the organization's official
publication, The Journal of Commercial Bank Lending.
I certainly would not come before this Annual Meeting to
reopen that debate.

However, I would like to stress again my con-

viction that the adverse effects of monetary restraint on particular
sectors of the economy -- amplified by the lending behavior of
commercial banks -- are also serious.

I believe members of the

Robert Morris Associates will agree with this evaluation if they
were to take another look at the evidence.

Hopefully, you would

conclude that a major effort must be made to increase

the equity --

and efficiency -- in the functioning of our financial system during




-23tight credit periods.

The key point is that we need a genuine

effort -- and not simply a continuation of pious rhetoric -- to
bring about an improvement in the flow of credit in the years
ahead.




Sources and Uses of Funds by Commercial Banks,
1968. 1969, and 1970
(Amounts in billions of dollars)

Table 1.

Source or Use
Net acquisition of financial assets
Total bank credit
Credit Market instruments
U.S. Gov't, securities
Direct
Agency issues
Loan participation certifs.
State and local obligations
Corporate bonds
Home mortgages
Other mortgages
Consumer credit
Bank loans, N.E.C.
Open market paper
Security credit

1968
Per cent
Amount of total

1969
Per cent
Amount of total

1970
Per cent
Amount of total

44.0

100.0

19.7

100.0

41.9

100.0

39.7

90.2

16.5

83.8

29.3

69.9

38.4
3.4
2.2
1.1
0.2

87.3
7.7
5.0
2.5
0.5

89.9
17.7
- 9.5 - 48.2
- 9.3 - 47.2
5.6
1.1
- 6.6
- 1.3

27.5
8.2
5.2
3.7
- 0.7

65.6
19.6
12.4
8.8
- 1.7

8.6
0.3
3.5
3.2
4.9
15.7
- 1.1

19.5
0.7
8.0
7.3
11.1
35.7
- 2.5

0.4
- 0.1
3.0
2.3
3.3
17.8
0.5

2.0
- 0.5
15.2
11.7
16.8
90.4
2.5

11.2
0.5
0.9
1.0
1.9
0.6
3.2

26.7
1.2
2.1
2.4
4.5
1.4
7.6

1.3

3.0

- 1.1

- 5.6

1.8

4.3

0.6

3.0

- 0.1

- 0.2

Loans to affiliate banks
Vault cash and member bank
reserves

2.0

4.5

0.4

2.0

2.2

5.3

Miscellaneous assets

2.3

5.2

2.2

11.2

10.5

25.1

42.2

100.0

18.0

100.0

39.8

100.0

13.3
- 0.2
13.5

31.5
- 0.5
32.0

5.2

28.9

*

*

5.2

28.9

6.4
2.7
3.7

16.1
6.8
9.3

20.6
3.1
17.4

48.8
7.3
41.2

- 9.7 - 53.9
- 12.6 - 70.0
16.1
2.9

38.0
15.2
22.9

95.5
38.2
57.3

0.9

2.1

0.1

0.6

*

*

*

*

4.7

3.3
0.6
23.3

1.8
0.5
- 0.3

0.2

0.6
0.1
4.2

0.7
0.2
- 0.1
- 1.9

0.1
17.4
7.0
10.4

0.6
96.7
38.9
57.8

0.3
0.1
- 9.3
- 3.7
- 6.1 - 15.3
6.0
2.4

Net increase in liabilities
Demand deposits, net
U.S. Gove rnment
Other
Time deposits
Large negotiable CD's
Other
Federal Reserve float
Borrowing at Federal Reserve Banks
Loans from affiliates
Bank security issues
Commercial paper issues
Profit tax liabilities
Miscellaneous liabilities
Liabilities to foreign branches
Other

- 0.1
7.3
1.8
5.5

- 0.2
17.3
4.3
13.0

*

Discrepancy

0.5

0.3

- 0.1

Current surplus
Plant and equipment

2.9

3.1
1.0

3.0
1.1

NOTE:

Data show combined statement for commercial banks and affiliates.

* Not available



*

- 4.8

Table 2.
CHANGES IN MAJOR BALANCE SHEET ITEMS, WEEKLY REPORTING BANKS
1968, 1969 and 1970 1/
(In billions of dollars, not seasonally adjusted)

Total loans and investments, gross
Total loan sales
Total loans and investments,
adjusted for loan sales
U.S. Treasury
Other securities
Total loans, gross
Total loans, adjusted for
loan sales
Business loans
Business loan sales
Business loans, adjusted
for loan sales
Real estate
Consumer installment
Total deposits 2/
Total demand deposits 2/
Total time and savings deposits
Large CDfs 3/
Borrowings from major domestic
sources 4/
Other liabilities
Euro-dollar liabilities 5/
Loans and security reserves
and total capital account
MEMO:
Commercial paper 6/
1/

60 Major Re "a /
gional Banks
1968
1969
1970

1968

Total
1969

1970

20-Mult
7/
Nat'l Banks —
1968 1969 1970

23.0
n. a.

2.6
4.0

21.8
-1.0

10.9
n.a.

1.7
2.8

5.7
-0.3

6.2
n.a.

-0.1
0.8

4.9
-0.5

5.8
n.a.

1.0
0.4

11.2
-0.3

23.0
0.9
5.4
16.7

6.6
-5.8
-3.1
11.6

20.8
4.4
8.3
9.1

10.9
0.9
2.8
7.3

4.5
-2.2
-2.7
6.6

5.4
2.6
3.3
-0.3

6.2
0.1
1.2
4.9

0.7
-1.7
-0.4
2.1

4.4
0.8
1.9
2.2

5.8

1.4
-2.0

1.4
4.5

2.9

10.9
1.0
3.1
7.1

16.7
7.3
n.a.

15.6
7.2
2.9

8,1
0.9
-0.7

7.3
4.2
n.a.

9.4
4.3
2.1

-0.6
-1.8
-0.2

4.9
1.6
n.a.

2.9
1.6
0.4

1.7
0.3
-0.3

4.5
1.5
n.a.

3.3
1.3
0.3

6. Q
2
-0.2

7.3
3.1
2.2

10.1
2.1
1.7

0.2

4.2
0.9
0.5

6.4
1.1
0.3

-2.0
-0.6
0.3

1.6
1.1
0.7

2.0
0.4
0.4

-0.2
0.1

1.5
1.1
1.0

1.6
0.6
1.0

2.2
0.8
1.0

14.2
4.8
9.4
3.1

-15.6
0.4
-16.0
-12.4

29.9
6.8
23.0
14.8

4.0 -9.1
1.0
1.0
3.0 -10.1
0.5 -7.2

12.9
2.5
10.4
7.7

4.6
1.6
2.9
1.4

-4.5
-0.5
-4.0
-3.4

5.7
0.9
4.7
3.6

5.6
2.1
3.5
1.2

-2.0
-0.1
-1.9
-1.8

11.3
3.5
7,9
3.5

3.7
4.9
2.7

10.1
9.3
7.5

-0.1
-4.7
-5.0

2.2
4.1
2.6

4.4
7.4
6.7

-0.5
-4.7
-4.2

1.3
0.5
0.1

3.4
1.2
0.6

0.3
-0.3
-0.6

0.2
0.3
- -

2.3
0.7
0.3

0.1
0.3
-0.3

1.8

1.8

1.6

0.9

0.7

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.3

0.4

0.7

1.0

n.a.

4.3

-2.0

n.a.

2.4

-0.7

n.a.

1.3

-0.8

n.a.

0.6

- -

1.5

- -

250 Large
Local Banks
1968
1970
1969

- -

- -

'

\

/

Changes for 1970 are from December 24, 1969, to December 23, 1970. Comparable dates were used to compute 1969 and 1968
changes.
2/ Less cash items in the process of collection.
3/ Negotiable time certificates of deposit in denomination of $100,000 or more.
4/ Largely borrowing in the Federal funds market and from Federal Reserve Banks.
5,/ Bank liabilities to foreign branches.
6/ Issued by a bank holding company or other bank affiliate.
7/ These banks were selected on the basis of a number of criteria including size, volume of business loans, relative
~~ participation in Federal Funds market, Euro-dollar market and commercial paper market.
e sam| criteria a£ those ligteg^in^foptnote^7 j^ere u s e d ^ t o ^ s e l ^ c t these 60 banks. However, these b a n k s , in g e n e r a l ,

1/
re smaller and each region of the country was given representation.


Table 3.
CHANGES IN MAJOR BALANCE SHEET ITEMS, WEEKLY REPORTING BANKS
1968, 1969 and 1970 1/
(In per cent, not seasonally adjusted)

Total loans and investments, gross
Total loan sales
Total loans and investments,
adjusted for loan sales
U.S. Treasury
Other securities
Total loans, gross
Total loans, adjusted for
loan sales
Business loans
Business loans sales
Business loans, adjusted
for loan sales
Real estate
Consumer installment
Total deposits 2/
Total demand deposits _2/
Total time and savings deposits
Large CD's 3/
Borrowings from major domestic
sources 4/
Other liabilities
Euro-dollar liabilities 5/
Loan and security reserves
and total capital account
MEMO:
Commercial paper
1/
2/
3/
4/
_5/
6/
7/

6/

1968
10.9
n.a.
10.9
3.2
16.3
11.1
11.1
11.1
n.a.

Total
1969
1970
9.2
1.1
n.a. -25.9
2.8
-20c 1
-8.0
6.9

8.6
19.0
23.1
5.1

20-MultiNat11 Banks —
1968 1969 1970
1.6
5.1
11.1
n.a. -9.4
n.a.

60 Major Re-g/
gional Banks —
1968
1969
1970
-0.1
8.6
12.3
n.a.
n.a. -65.7

4.2
4.8
11.1
7.8 -18.1 27.0
19.7 -16.0 23.4
8.2 -0.3
10.0

12.3
1.3
14.7
14.0

1.2
-24.1
-4.6
5.3

7.7
15.0
20.2
5.3

9.3
-0.4
12.9
10.7

2.1
-19.5
0.3
6.3

15.6
12.0
24.9
14.5

9.4
4.4
9.9
1.1
nca. -24.8

10.0
11.2
n.a.

11.7 -0.6
10.2 -4.0
nca. -10.0

14.0
11.2
n.a.

7.2
10.0
n.a.

4.0
1.8
-65.5

10.7
10.9
n.a.

11.2
8.3
9.4

15.3
8.8
6.0

-4.2
-4.4
5.4

11.2
17.0
16.6

12.7
6.0
8.1

0.2
-2.3
2.1

10.9
9.8
14.6

10.9
5.0
12.2

13.5
6.3
11.4

4.4 -9.7 15.2
5.4
2.4
2.3
6.3 -20.4 26.3
4.7 -59.1 156.0

9.2
6.5
12.1
27.5

11.4
-8.3
-lo 9
3.5
-14.7
20.5
-53.1 119.2

9.0
6.9
11.1
33.5

-2.9
-0.2
-5.4
-37.9

17.2
10.7
23.7
116.6

70.2 -4.9
56.2 -22.7
98.0 -33.2

61.7
29.2

95.1
56.4
600.0

4.4
-10.4
-62.0

15.9
15.6

148.7
29.2

—

--

2. i
10.8
-67.1

11.1
10.8
13.6

13.8
6.7
9.3

0.2
0.1
7.2

7.0
4.8
9.1
15.5

-7.2
0.4
-14.3
-53.3

14.9
6.6
24.0
135.1

48.8
38.8
63.0

88.7
56.2
107.1

-0.7
-17.4
-36.1

52.7
45.9
63.0

7.7

7.4

6.0

8.4

n.a. -45.3

n.a.

n.a.

250 Large
Local Banks
1968
1969
1970
9.3
1.4
16.1
n.a.
n.a. -63.3

- -

7.2
13.9
8.9
15.1
n.a. -71.7

2.4

7.6

8.6

5.2

6.7

9.6

12.1

n.a. -31.7

n.a.

n.a.

-59.4

n.a.

n.a.

-56.8

5.5

Changes for 1970 from Dec. 24, 1969, to Dec. 23, 1970. Comparable dates were used to compute 1969 and 1968 changes.
Less cash items in the process of collection
Negotiable time certificates of deposit in denomination of $100,000 or more.
Largely borrowing in the Federal funds market and from Federal Reserve Banks.
Bank liabilities to foreign branches.
Issued by a bank holding company or other bank affiliate.
These banks were selected on the basis of a number of criteria including size, volume of business loans, relative
participation in Federal Funds market, Euro-dollar market and commercial paper market,
8/ For definition see Table 1.
NOTE: Figures may not sum exactly due to rounding.




Table 4.
Ratios of Selected Assets to Total Earning Assets —
All Insured Commercial Banks, by Size Groups
June 1966
(In per cent)

Item (as per cent of
total earning assets)

Size Group—Total Deposits
(in thousands of dollars)
10,000- 25,00050,00025.000
50.000
100.000

Under
5.000

5,00010.000

32
12
56
16
7
9

26
16
58
19
7
12

23
17
60
20
7
12

21
17
62
20
7
12

19
17
64
20
7
12

17
16
67
17
7
10

13
15
72
15
5
10

12
14
75
13
4
9

1
17
8
14

1
9
11
17

2
4
13
19

3
2
16
20

4
1
19
18

5
1
21
19

9
1
27
17

14
1
33
11

Government agency securities
5
Municipal securities
7
Corporate and other securities
1
na
Trading account securities
-Federal funds sold
Total loans less Federal funds
56
sale
1
Residential, Government guarantee
8
All other residential
—
Loans to commercial banks
Loans to other financial
-institutions
—
Loans to brokers and dealers
Other loans for carrying securities —
6 ,697
Number of banks (Total: 13,555)
Average size (Total: 23,391)
2 ,539

4
12
1
na

3
14

3
14

2
14

1
14

1
12

—

—

- -

—

—

—

3
13
1
na
1

na
1

na
1

na
1

na
1

na
1

57
1
10

59
2
11

61
2
10

63
3
9

66
3
7

—

—

—

—

—

71
4
6
1

74
4
5
1

U.S. Treasury securities
All other securities
Total loans
Real estate loans
Nonresidential
Residential
Loans to financial institutions
and investors in securities
Agricultural loans
Business loans
Loans to individuals

1/

1

1
—

1
3,127
6,793

—

1
2,282
14,847

Ratios are average of ratios for individual banks.
and th«ir affiliates are not reflected in the data.




2
—

1
726
33,124

2
1
1
329
66,128

100,000500.000

4
1
1
304
190,031

Loan transfers between banks

500,0001,000.000

6
1
1
53
610 , 69 3

Over
1,000,000

3
2
37
2,945,526

Table 5.
Ratios of Selected Assets to Total Earning Assets:
All Insured Commercial Banks, By Size Groups
June 1970
(in per cent)

Item (as per cent of
total earning assets)
U.S. Treasury securities
All other securities
Total loans
Real estate loans
Nonresidential
Residential
Loans to financial institutions
and investors in securities
Agricultural loans
Business loans
Loans to individuals
Government agency securities
Municipal securities
Corporate and other securities
Trading account securities
Federal funds sold
Total loans less Federal funds
sale
Residential, Government guarantee
All other residential
Loans to commercial banks
Loans to other financial
institutions
Loans to brokers and dealers
Other loans for carrying
securities
Number of banks (Total: 1 3 ^ 3 3 )
Average size (Total: 31,2^5)

Under
5,000

5,00010,000

500,0001,000,000

Over
1,000,000

25
15
60
15
7
3

20
19
61
18
8
10

17
21
63
19
7
12

14
21
65
20
8
12

lb
21
65
20
8
12

12
19
69
19
8
11

9
17
7^
17
6
11

8
15
77
13
b
9

1
18
8
13

1
11
10
16

1
6
13
19

2
2
16
20

3
1
18
19

b
1
22
19

7
1
28
16

10
1
38
11

T
7
1

5
13
1

h
16
1

k
17
1

3
17
1

2
16
1

1
lb
1

1
13
1

k

k

3

3

2

3

2

58
1
10

59
1
11

62
2
11

63
2
10

66
2
9

69
3
8
1

75
3
6
1

1

2

5
1

6
2

1
480
67,048

1
39^
199,139

1
62
683,65U

1
bl
3,093,814

_L

56
1
7

mm M

M 9 2
2,835

l

1

1
—

—

1
3,^32
7,087

1/ Ratios are average of ratios for individual banks.
and their affiliates are reflected in the data.



10,00025,000

Size Group — Total Deposits
(in thousands of dollars)
100,00025,00050,00050,000
100,000
500,000

—

1
3,170
15,095

1
—

1
1,106
33,516

—

Loan transfers between banks

Table 6.
Ratios of Selected Assets to Total Earning Assets
All Insured Commercial Banks, By Size Groups
June 1971
(in per cent)

Item (as per cent of
total earning assets)
U-S. Treasury securities
All other securities
Total loans
Real estate loans
Wonre s ident ial
Residential
Loans to financial institutions
and investors in securities
Agricultural loans
Business loans
Loans to individuals
Government agency securities
Municipal securities
Corporate and other securities
Trading account securities
Federal funds sold
Total loans less Federal funds
sale
Residential, Government guarantee
All other residential
Loans to commercial banks
Loans to other financial
institutions
Loans to brokers and dealers
Other loans for carrying
securities
Number of banks
(Total: 13,550)
Average size
(Total: 35,290)

Under
5,000

5,00010,000

500,0001,000,000

Over
1,000,000

2k
17
59
Ik
r
0
8

19
21
60
16
7
9

17
21
61
18
7
11

11+
23
63
19
7
12

11+
23
63
20
8
12

12
22
66
18
7
11

10
21
69
17
6
11

9
18
71+
12
1+
8

l
17
8
Ik

l
11
10
16

1
6
12
18

2
3
16
19

2
1
17
18

5
1
21
18

6
1
21+
16

11
1
36
9

8
8
1

6
Ik
1

5
16
1

5
18
1

1+
18
1

3
18
1

—

—

—

—

—

2
17
1
1
1+

1
ii+
1
2
3

66
3
7
1

71
2
5
1

5

6
3

—

1+

h

55

56
1
9

56
1
10

59
1
11

59
2
10

65
3
7

—

—

—

—

—

—

—

—

—

—

—

7

- -

M86
2,907

- -

3,3^6
7,126

1/ Ratios are average of ratios for individual banks.
are reflected in the data.


and their affiliates


10,00025,000

Size Group—Total Deposits
(in thousands of dollars)
25,00050,000100,00050,000
100,000
500,000

- -

3,1+89
15,117

3

2

1

1
—

1+

—

—

1,293
33,71'!

1
—

—

562
67,269

Loan transfers between banks

3
1
1
1+1+3
198,216

—

1
77
696,815

1
5l+
3,081,220