View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Before the Hyman P. Minsky Conference on Financial Structure, The Levy Institute,
Annandale-on-Hudson, New York
April 23, 1998

Toward A Better Class of Financial Crises: Some Lessons from Asia
Drawing lessons from the Asian financial crisis has become a minor industry, partially
offsetting the impact of the crisis on developed economies -- at least for economists. It
contributes to conference budgets, airline revenues, bar tabs, and the length of academic
resumes. The opining classes can turn almost any bad news into an excuse for more meetings
in beautiful settings like Bard College.
Some of the talk has been devoted to the blame game. Was the crisis (or rather the rolling set
of interrelated crises) home-grown, that is, brought on by ill-conceived investment,
over-leveraged companies, lax banking supervision and crony capitalism in the borrowing
countries? Was it the greed, inattention, or herd instinct of the lenders? Or was it the
inherent instability of international capital flows? Did the IMF step in just in time to avert
total meltdown or did it fail to provide early enough warning? Did the conditions imposed on
borrowers help restore investor confidence or further undermine it?
The quick answer is that all of the alleged culprits bear part of the responsibility.
International flows of capital can be unstable -- what flows in can quickly flow out -- and
fast. The enormous escalation in the volume of private capital flows, coupled with the
advent of simultaneous communication in all the world's markets, has greatly increased the
exposure of economies to rapid turnarounds in cross border flows. Decades of rapid growth
and apparently unending capital inflow had made the Asian emerging markets, until recently
known as "tigers," believe they were immune from the reversals of investor confidence that
beset other parts of the world and produced an incaution that led to over investment in some
sectors, inflated equity and real estate prices, and some ill-thought-out projects, public and
private. Close relations between companies, banks and governments created false senses of
security, as well as uneconomic "policy" loans and investments. Weak supervision of
financial institutions and markets, on top of traditions of secrecy in business and
governmental transactions, aggravated the crises when things turned down. At the same
time, foreign investors and creditors asked too few questions, were hesitant to reign in the
galloping goose that had laid so many golden eggs, and reinforced each other's reluctance to
be the first to pull back. As tensions were developing, the IMF pointed to some of the
dangers without getting much response, and missed some others, as did the much-vaunted
market gurus and rating agencies. When the crises hit, the IMF quickly crafted rescue
packages that imposed serious structural reform as conditions of aid, inevitably making some
mistakes in the process, but arresting the spreading downward spiral and restoring enough
confidence to allow the countries to get their policies in shape to support the climb back to
economic health. No one thinks the climb will be easy, but the best bet is that the worst is
over.

Now the talk has shifted to the more difficult subject of what the international community
can do to prevent, mitigate and manage financial crises in the future. The stakes are high, for
industrial and emerging market countries alike. When international capital markets function
well, they help achieve rising standards of living for both creditor and debtor countries.
When the markets crash, they bring incredible hardship to ordinary workers and their
families -- often people who have been pulled out of their traditional occupations and
communities by economic change and may have nothing to fall back on.
Two sets of prescriptions are relatively uncontroversial, albeit deceptively hard to achieve.
First, the world's capital markets and the machinery designed to stabilize them would
function better with more complete, accessible and timely information flows. Investors can
make better decisions and lenders can exercise more discipline over borrower behavior if
they have more accurate and more complete information and have it sooner. Both
international and domestic officials can monitor, supervise and warn of impending danger
only if they know the facts. Improving transparency should apply not only to businesses and
banks, but to official bodies, both national and international. It's important to know what a
country's budget deficit really is (on budget and off budget) and what its exchange reserves
really are, including any operations in the forward markets. The Asian crisis was certainly
exacerbated by lack of information of many sorts, including accurate data on reserves.
There is currently a great flurry of activity in various international fora to raise standards of
accounting and reporting on business, banking and governmental activity and balance sheets.
Progress will be made. But one should not expect too much. Although post mortems on
financial crises, especially reviews of investor decisions that went sour, feature a great deal
of if-only-we-had-known rhetoric, in actual fact a great deal of information usually turns out
to have been available which no one ever looked at or effectively analyzed. For
transparency to be useful, people need to actually want to look -- and too often those who
are making high profits would rather not hear bad news.
Second, a major sustained international effort is needed to strengthen the structure,
functioning and supervision of financial systems in emerging market countries. A clear
lesson of recent economic history (and not just in emerging market countries) is the crucial
importance of strong banks and other financial institutions, adequately capitalized and able
to manage risk, overseen by serious prudential supervision and an independent well managed
central bank. Industrial countries can ill-afford to be sanctimonious on this score -- many of
us have experienced the adverse effects of poor prudential supervision or lack of political
will to close failing financial institutions -- but good management and strong supervision of
financial institutions is clearly a key to withstanding economic shocks.
Here, too, consensus is strong and serious activity is underway under the aegis of a variety
of international bodies, perhaps too many, to evolve clear rules for financial supervision and
help countries implement them. The task will require time, patience and resources. It is not
just bank examiners, but bankers who need training in how to do their jobs in modern, fast
moving internationally exposed economies. Strengthening financial systems, including
improving corporate governance, goes hand in hand with efforts to improve transparency
and information flows -- to investors, shareholders, supervisors and international agencies -and both will require sustained effort and run into significant resistance.
The first two prescriptions are preventive, designed to reduce the frequency and amplitude
of financial crises. But no one with a sense of history -- or reality -- believes that crises can

be eliminated. Hence, a third prescription also appears on everybody's list, albeit with far
less agreement on what it means, namely, private creditors should take on a greater portion
of the burden of resolving future international financial crises. Sharing the burden is a far
more difficult issue to come to grips with conceptually than either the need for greater
transparency or the need for stronger, better supervised financial systems. Not much
intellectual structure yet exists for thinking about burden-sharing in international financial
crises. Moreover, cross-border financing is growing so rapidly and market instruments are
morphing so fast that designing ways of sharing the burden is like changing the tires on a
moving car -- pretty exciting and not obviously doable.
The task cannot be set aside, however, for at least two reasons. First, the cost of resolving
international financial crises is outrunning the likely resources available for that purpose.
The volume of cross-border flows has grown precipitously and the cost of breakdown has
escalated with it. High speed traffic on a six lane freeway moves a lot of people to their
destinations fast, but the pile-up in a wreck is a lot more expensive than on a winding two
lane road. If recent trends continue, managing the next crisis will call for more resources
than taxpayers in the U.S. and other developed countries are likely to feel comfortable
turning over to the IMF and other international organizations, even if they are reasonably
confident that the borrowing countries will pay the loans back, as experience indicates they
will.
Second, and far more important, the perception that official resources can be counted on to
bail out creditors (directly or indirectly) arguably generates moral hazard. It could lead to
excessive risk-taking by lenders and funding of less economically defensible projects. It may
also channel financing into less stable forms whose overuse makes crises more likely to
occur. In recent episodes, direct investors and holders of equity and long-term debt have
taken serious losses, but short-term lenders, especially interbank lenders, have been largely
protected. While a country in trouble has understandable reasons for not wanting to cut itself
off from short-term bank credit and for using its scarce international resources to keep this
lifeline attached, the result may be to reinforce excessive dependence on debt rather than
equity and on short, rather than longer-term financing.
Both reasons combine to create an urgent need for serious and creative thought on the part
of the international community about how to "bail in" private sector financiers, in order to
reduce the impact on the financial resources of official institutions like the IMF, the World
Bank and the regional development banks, to reduce moral hazard leading to excessive
risk-taking, especially short term inter-bank borrowing, and to improve risk assessment.
Designing mechanisms for appropriate burdensharing among private sector investor/creditors
is inherently hard because it runs into some very sticky and fundamental dilemmas. The
basic principle from which all borrowing and lending must proceed is that people who use
other people's money have a firm obligation to pay it back. Hence, a suspension of payments
or a work-out arrangement must be clearly rare and exceptional, resorted to only in extreme
situations. Raising fears that suspensions are likely or work-outs normal could unnecessarily
increase the cost of capital, cause drastic reductions in cross border flows and diminish
future incomes of debtors and creditors alike. Yet having no known or understood process
for dealing with default can, as has been seen in Asia, lead to inequitable burden sharing,
high official cost and potential future moral hazard.
A related basic dilemma involves the timing of a suspension of payments. Authorities have
to hold off long enough to be sure there is no other choice, but not wait so long that creditors

are running for the doors and irreversible damage is already done.
The problem is, of course, not entirely new. International borrowers have gotten into trouble
before, and precedents for workouts have been developed -- Paris Club procedures for
resolving sovereign debts to public creditors; London Club for resolving sovereign debts to
private banks. But each crisis is different from the last. A critical element in the Mexican
crisis of 1994-95 was the threat of default on dollar-indexed Mexican short-term bonds
(tesebonos1) for which no work-out process existed. Dealing with bond holders (who are
likely to be numerous and scattered) is more complex than dealing with lending governments
or a relatively small (and known) group of international banks. The recent Asian crises posed
still another problem. The borrowers were not governments, but private banks and
corporations, a situation that may be typical of future crises, and one that adds greatly to the
legal and organizational complexities of sharing the burden of financial distress.
When the debt in question is sovereign debt, whether to banks or other lenders, it may not
be hard to reestablish stability and confidence in the sovereign. The IMF can lend enough to
solve the borrowing government's immediate liquidity problem while the government works
out a debt restructuring with its creditors. IMF rules permit "lending into arrears" in these
circumstances.
If the creditors are bondholders, as they were in Mexico, the situation is more difficult. IMF
rules do not at present permit a government borrowing from the IMF when it is unable to
pay its bondholders. Even a small minority of the bondholders can use their bargaining
power to obstruct a resolution of the crisis in hopes of getting a better deal. After the
Mexican crisis had been resolved with the help of significant new official lending to Mexico,
the international community focussed on how to improve the bargaining position of the
debtor government with its bondholders if such a crisis should arise in the future.
The "Rey Report" on Sovereign Liquidity Crises (named for its author, Jean-Jacques Rey of
the Central Bank of Belgium) was a major effort by the G-10 countries to learn the lessons
of Mexico. It recommended two new steps:
First, the IMF should expand its willingness to lend into arrears to cover the situation
in which a sovereign was making a good faith effort to work out a debt restructuring
with its bondholders.
Second, it recommended that bonds issued in international markets contain clauses
that would facilitate debt restructuring if it became necessary. Clauses could be added
to provide for debtholder representation in negotiations with the sovereign or qualified
majority voting on changes in terms. Such clauses would make it harder for minority
creditors to block restructuring or exact a higher price than necessary to satisfy the
majority.
Neither of these recommendations received much official attention until the Asian crisis hit.
Although the recommendations were not actually germane to the situation in Asia, the IMF
reviewed the recommendations at its Interim Committee meeting in April 1998 and action in
the near future seems more likely than a year ago. Perhaps the official community will
always be one crisis late.
Unlike the sovereign debt crises in Latin America, the situation in Asia involved private
debts (of banks in Korea, corporations in Indonesia, and some of each in Thailand) to private
creditors, mostly banks. Hence, it was inherently harder, as currency values plummeted and

reserves all but disappeared, to design ways either to restore stability or to organize
work-outs.
An additional complication was the fact that, although the debts were private, some of them
involved varying types of implied government guarantees. In Korea, the Finance Minister
ill-advisedly volunteered that the Korean government would honor foreign debts of Korean
banks. When the Korean banks experienced difficulty rolling over their international bank
loans, the Bank of Korea provided the reserves they needed to repay the loans, in effect
delivering on the guarantee, but rapidly depleting the central bank's reserves in the process.
Guarantees of this sort clearly create moral hazard. Pre-crisis, they result in more bank
lending than would otherwise have taken place, and when trouble begins they may
accelerate a bank run. But much less explicit guarantees can be trouble as well. Where
governments are heavily intertwined with banks and companies, as has been normal
throughout much of Asia, foreign lenders and investors may well assume that the
government will not allow favored operations to fail. One of the challenges of mitigating and
managing future crises, therefore, is finding ways to discourage emerging market
governments from guaranteeing private debts or being so closely involved with private
enterprises that these enterprises are seen as immune from market forces.
The expectation that future borrowers in international markets will be mostly private
enterprises, greatly increases the importance of the first two prescriptions -- increasing
transparency and strengthening financial system surveillance -- not just to prevent and
mitigate crises, but to manage them when they happen.
In an economy that tolerates secrecy in business and financial dealings and where
information disclosures are limited, firms with fairly shaky fundamentals may be able to
borrow easily in a boom. They will be carried along by the general optimism, since everyone
wants to believe the best and there is no tradition of asking hard questions anyway. But in a
crisis, market participants tend to believe the worst. To contain the crisis and restore
confidence, it is necessary both for managers and public authorities to be able to deliver the
bad news and be believed by the markets. If there is no tradition of accurate, high quality
information that can be relied on, market participants and bank depositors are likely to
believe that things are substantially worse than they really are and proceed to prove it by
their actions. A culture of transparency and timely, accurate information can serve as an
economic stabilizer in both directions. It can restrain the boom by enabling investors to
assess risk more accurately, and it can cushion over-reaction once a downward slide begins.
But such a culture cannot be built quickly, and even where it exists, has to be assiduously
maintained.
Similarly, prudential supervision of financial institutions may be thought of as primarily
valuable for crisis prevention -- useful for ensuring that financial institutions are adequately
capitalized, don't take unacceptable risks with other people's money, and that the weak ones
are required to shape up or go under. Once a crisis hits, however, it is important to be able to
distinguish strong from weak institutions, those that ought to be rescued from those that
ought to be closed. Unless supervision has been effective on an ongoing basis, however, the
supervisors will not be able to tell strong from weak and will not be able to find out fast
enough to prevent a rout. Good institutions then go down with the bad. It is actually in the
long-run interest of financial institutions that aspire to be the survivors of a shake-out to
insist that supervisors are well informed and applying a high standard.
Another lesson of recent events in Asia has been the importance of clear, enforceable

bankruptcy laws in dealing with a crisis, as well as helping to prevent one. Bankruptcy
provides an opportunity, not only for closing down truly insolvent enterprises in an orderly
way, but for rescuing troubled ones by allowing them to cut a deal with their creditors,
restructure their obligations, and go on operating on a sounder basis. But bankruptcy
procedures cannot be rapidly invented or first tested in a crisis. For bankruptcy procedures
to mitigate crises effectively and help to get survivors on their feet, there has to be a "culture
of bankruptcy" which operates in good times as well as bad. Debtors, creditors, lawyers and
courts have to be used in the process, know what to do, be able, because they have done it
before, to cut the deals that will minimize the damage and keep potentially profitable
enterprises afloat. Asian countries, most obviously Indonesia, found that since their modern
market experience had been primarily one of boom and growth, they had inadequate
bankruptcy laws and little "culture of bankruptcy" to help manage a sudden negative turn of
events.
Improving transparency, supervision and bankruptcy procedures will help emerging market
economies grow more sustainably (albeit perhaps slower) and manage downturns better
when they happen. But the conceptually hard questions involve international collective
action and how it can manage major crises more effectively.
Once a crisis hits one country, especially a country of significant size and linkage with
others, the whole international community has a strong interest in rapid action to isolate
markets and prevent the contagion from spreading and engulfing others. At this moment, the
community looks to the IMF to act quickly, provide liquidity and restore confidence,
especially the confidence that the crises has bottomed out and will not be part of a
continuing downward spiral. Asia in 1997 was a demonstration of how fast the dominoes
could fall.
When the root cause of the problem is inappropriate macro-economic policy, especially big
budget deficits and easy money combined with a pegged exchange rate, it may not be
difficult for the IMF to restore confidence by injecting enough liquidity to pay short-term
claims in foreign currency in return for rapid changes in policy. When macro policy is not
obviously the chief culprit, restoring confidence may be harder and more expensive.
Injecting new money in exchange for reforms may still be the primary answer, but the
patience of taxpayers wears thin as amounts escalate and it is perceived that some classes of
creditors are being bailed out with official international resources -- creditors who should
have calculated the risks more accurately and should bear the cost of not having done so, so
they won't do it again.
Some have asked whether official resources could be saved and moral hazard reduced by
designing an automatic international bankruptcy-like process, known in advance, by which a
standstill could be triggered, followed by a set procedure for sharing the burden among all
the relevant creditors. Serious thought is being devoted to this issue. It is not hard to imagine
such an approach, but all crises are different and applying a cooky cutter solution could well
do more harm than good.
The next few years will be a testing time for what I think of as the "cross border
community," meaning the organizations, public and private, dedicated to making the cross
border relationships (especially business and financial ones) work better. The "cross border
community" includes mega firms that produce goods and deliver financial services on a
worldwide scale, and associations of accountants, lawyers, bankers, securities dealers,

insurance underwriters and various kinds of financial regulators as well as general
international financial institutions (the IMF and the World Bank) and more specialized ones
such as the Bank for International Settlements, and the regional development banks -- to
mention only a few of the more obvious members of a burgeoning species.
The benefits of cross border trade and capital flows for raising the world standard of living
are clear, but so are some of the costs -- especially the costs to ordinary people of being
caught in the backwash when there is a crisis. If these costs are not taken seriously and
methods designed to mitigate and manage financial crises better, a wave of political backlash
against capitalism, foreigners and what we all think is "progress" could result. One lesson of
recent crises is that factories, banks, shiny buildings, and eager investors do not by
themselves create the underpinnings of modern economic society able to withstand shocks
with minimal damage. That takes -- in addition to good fiscal, monetary and other public
policies -- an infrastructure of laws and traditions and expectations that cannot be built
overnight or imposed from the outside. The challenge for the cross-border community will
be to work closely with emerging market economies to help them build this infrastructure in
ways that work for them. Wading in and saying, "do it our way" won't work. The process
will involve continuous interaction and adaptation and may well result in better functioning
economies in the so-called developed world, as well.

Footnotes
1 Tesebonos were technically denominated in pesos.
Return to top
1998 Speeches
Home | News and events
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: April 29, 1998 3:30 PM