View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM AND
THE FOREIGN EXCHANGES.

JBY
ALBERT

STRAUSS

o f J . & W . SELIGMAN & C o . ,

L

U

b

r

a r v

Bankers.

J

AN ADDRESS T O T H E STUDENTS O F T H E
D E P A R T M E N T O F ECONOMICS O F
PRINCETON U N I V E R S I T Y
JANUARY 21, 1921.

, S 7 n-

i

u b r a r y )

T H E F E D E R A L RESERTI2 SYSTEM A N D
FOREIGN EXCHANGES.
Circumstances did not permit the Federal Reserve
System to develop gradually. The System was carefully planned; it was based 011 a painstaking study of
similar institutions in all parts of the world, but fate
decrced that it should be put into operation at the very
instant when through the outbreak of the European
W a r all precedents were thrown to the wind and when,
everywhere, new methods to meet new emergencies had
to be hurriedly devised. A s a result, the System has
not yet had an opportunity to function in accordance
with the plan of its founders. It passed an uneventful
childhood and, without any intervening period of adolescence, had thrust upon it the full responsibilities of
strenuous manhood. This abnormal development has
not been without its advantages. It was inevitable that
any new system would in practice f r o m time to time
require changes to meet developments which its founders
could not have foreseen. The System, developing as it
did, at first under the threat and later under the stress
of war, was able promptly to secure the legislation
necessary to its development, which, under normal conditions of peace would have involved great effort and
considerable delay.
N o system of banking—in fact n o institution—operates rigidly in accordance with the theory of its constitution. The temperament of the people whom it serves
and of the people who work its machinery is an important element in operation. The theoretically autonomous operation of the British banking system is modified by the personality of the officers of the Bank of
England who, for the purpose of controlling credit, do
n o t rely entirely o n the discount rates of the Bank,
but who use their influence in contact with bankers

£

,18
m

?83

2
whom they meet, either to moderate or, to accelerate
the tendencies that (lie Bank wishes to control or to
promote. The exercise of such personal influence is a
cOmparativly simple matter in a compact banking community like England. It is obvious that its application
will be of an entirely different character in England, a
small, homogeneous country with one financial center
where five or six large banks with thousands of branches
are the dominating factors, from what it must be with
us, confronted by a vast country with thirty thousand
independent banks organized under the laws of almost
fifty separate jurisdictions. Then, too, account must
be taken of the temperament of the people whom it
serves. Methods of control suited to an old community
with traditions built up through hundreds of years of
gradual development, are not suited to a new community filled with the spirit of speculation and adventure and whose people regard each development and
expansion as merely the threshold for further development.
The theory and normal practice of the operation of
central reserve banks in the countries in which those
banks have long existed, require the re-discount rates
of the central bank to be above the market rate in order
that resort may ho had to the central bank only to meet
seasonal or unusual requirements and that such resort
shall always entail to the borrower a higher rate of
interest than he has taken into account in connection
with his normal transactions.
During the war it was naturally impossible for a
central bank to operate on this basis. W a r financing
inevitably entails inflation. It is obvious that if, during
the war, the community had restricted its consumption
to correspond to the expanding needs of the Government, we should have had 110 undue competition in the
purchase of commodities, and hence 110 abnormal prices.

3
The restriction of individual consumption would have
put the individual in possession of surplus purchasing
power which he would have transferred to the Government either through payment of taxes or through the
purchase of Government bonds, and the exercise by the
Government of the purchasing power so transferred
would have met with no competition from the individual.
On the commodity side, there would have been no rise
of prices. On the investment side there would have
been money saved by the individual, available f o r the
payment of taxes o r for investment in Government
bonds.
On the banking side there would, therefore,
have been 110 consequent expansion of loans. A s a matter of fact, such ideal conditions can never be found
in practice.
Our organization for war purposes, on
the financial side as on the military side, was necessarily a growth. A t the time of the armistice, both
A r m y and Navy had reached a point where they were
well prepared to do their part and they had begun
effectively to aid our Associates, and 011 the financial
side, through Government control and through voluntary co-operation, consumption had been marvelously
cut down, prices had been fixed and adjusted, imports
had been restricted and we had probably reached a condition of commercial and industrial equilbrium, where
through the restriction of consumption and the fixing
of prices, further competitive buying between the Government and its citizens would have been avoided. T o
the extent to which the individual who bought Liberty
Bonds did not reduce his consumption and save, to
that extent when he purchased Government securities,
he was compelled to borrow from banks. l i e did indeed
transfer purchasing power to the Government, but at
the same time he replaced that purchasing power by
borrowing from the banks and then with that newly

4
created purchasing power he entered the commodity
market as a competitor with the Government.
Thus
did the causes operate that advanced prices after our
entry into the w a r ; before that time, prices were put
up by the purchases here of the Entente Powers, who
bought freely in our commodity markets. They made
payment in part by the shipment of gold and in part
by placing here loans whose marketing was facilitated
by the improved reserve position of our banks which,
in turn, was the result of the gold these Powers had
themselves sent into this country in payment of
commodities.
This brief outline contains for you nothing new. The
position is summarized here only to emphasize the fact
that a certain amount of expansion or inflation was, as a
consequence of the war, inevitable. This inevitable expansion necessarily involved re-discounts with the Federal Reserve Banks, which were not seasonal or extraordinary, but which were for (lie time a necessary reliance
on which the banks had to depend to permit the people
of this country to assist the Government in raising (ho
funds necessary for the prosecution of the war.
In
those circumstances to have raised the Federal Reserve
re-discount rates above the rates borne by Government
securities would have involved continuous and heavy
interest losses to all banks and to all borrowers from
banks, without in any degree checking the
expansion
ichich, in the circumstances
of the case, was not only
unavoidable
but necessary.
There was no question,
therefore, of using rates to control the expansion of
credit. The expansion of credit was necessary and to
have checked it would have been to check onr ability
t o place Liberty Bonds.
During the earlier portion of the post-armistice
period, expenditures continued practically on a war

5
basis. Troops had to be maintained until they could
be brought home; the expenses of bringing the troops
back had to be met; contracts theretofore entered into
for arms and munitions had to be settled or compromised; expenditures in connection with the Navy, Shipping Board, Railroads, etc., continued.
When these expenditures finally began to fall off and
the expansion of Government debt ceased, a different
Rituation confronted us. In a mood of reaction from
wartime restrictions, and with wages 011 a level never
theretofore reached, the community indulged itself in
a" wild burst of extravagant buying.
Price advances
during this period were accentuated by the fact that
advances to European countries stimulated our exports,
which rose to unprecedented heights; the purchase of
commodities for export to meet the undoubted needs of
Europe and to replace the depleted commodity stocks
of South America and the Orient, competed with the
wild purchasing by our own people. During this period
the holder ftf commodities could exact any price he
chose; all elements of cost, including the cost of money,
had only to be added to the selling price, which was
cheerfully paid by the buyer. A glance at the causes
in operation, make it obvious that during this period
it was impossible, through any change in discount rates,
to check the excesses of the community. As a matter
of fact, our return t o a rational frame of mind was
finally brought about and a definite check to expansion
was finally given, not through changes in discount
rates, but through the realization by the community
that we were approaching the point where, through the
decline in our reserve percentage, credit might soon be
unobtainable at any price. It so happened that the increase by (lie Federal Reserve Banks of their discount
rates, coincided in point of time with the decline in our

6
reserve percentage, and it was natural that this should
be so. The check to our expansion, however, it is clear
to me, resulted from the decline in the reserve percentage, with its implication of a complete failure of new
supplies of credit, and not f r o m the costliness of the
comparatively moderate increase in re-disconnt rates.
This falling reserve, it will be remembered, was the result of a considerable export of gold principally to
Japan, China, India and South America, following the
removal of the embargo on the export of the precious
metals in June, 1919. Undoubtedly the increase in the
re-discount rates served to emphasize the warning given
by the falling reserves but, in my judgment, that increase was not the cause that turned our faces toward
sanity.
The re-discount rates of the Federal Reserve Banks
ure not yet above the market rates for money, but the
time is now approaching when for the first time since
the System became a factor in the money market, a
normal relation between re-discount rates find market
rates may gradually be established.
A s in the case of discount rates, so also in regard to
the exchanges. The Federal Reserve System has never
assumed its normal relation to the foreign exchanges.
This does not mean that the Federal Reserve Board
has not been active in the control of the foreign exchanges. Proceeding in conjunction with the Treasury
and at times also with the W a r Trade Board, the Federal Reserve Board was an active factor in dealing with
the foreign exchange difficulties that arose during the
war and during the armistice period. It will perhaps
be of interest to deal in outline with some of these relations, which, it should be remembered, were the joint
product of the activity and ingenuity of the Treasury
and of the Federal Reserve Board, but before doing so

7
it may be well to spend a moment 011 the normal functioning of the foreign exchanges and 011 the relations t o
the foreign exchanges which the Federal Reserve Board
and Banks may normally be exx^ected to bear.
The normal relation between the currencies of gold
standard countries is based on the relative amount of
tine gold in the standard coin of the respective currencies. A British sovereign contains 4.8665 times as much
gold as a United States gold dollar, and hence the par
of exchange between the dollar and the sovereign is
4.8665 dollars to the sovereign. W h e n the free movement of gold between the two countries is unimpeded,
it is evident that $4,866.50 of United States gold coin
laid down in England will produce £1,000 Sterling. T o
this must be added the cost of freight, insurance, loss of
interest, abrasion on the coin and mint charges. It is
obvious that the quotation for Sterling in the United
States cannot under those circumstances ever rise above
$4.8665, plus the above charges and pins a small margin
of profit on the transaction; that it cannot rise above
say 4.89. Reversing the process, it is evident that a
thousand gold sovereigns sent f r o m England to tlio
United States will produce $4,866.50 of United States
money less the cost of freight, insurance, loss of interest,, abrasion and mint charges, as well as a small margin of profit; that it cannot fall below say $4.83. The
limit of fluctuation between gold currencies in free gold
markets is, therefore, well defined and the range of
fluctuation would ordinarily between markets not too
remote from each other, be well under 2 % . W i t h these
maximum and minimum points definitely established,
the losses and profits of dealings in foreign exchange are
fixed between narrow limits and thus permit transactions of large volume to be undertaken without risk of
serious loss. This is an important consideration as ifc

8
tends to broaden the market in foreign exchange and
to permit trading transactions on a large scale. The
tendency of these transactions is to keep exchange on a
level within the extreme limits of the " g o l d points."
The foreign exchange market is the medium through
which not only international purchases and sales of
commodities are settled, but as well international investments, remittances of interest, payment of freights,
etc. Apart from such transactions, the consummation
of which influence the exchange market but are, broadly
speaking, not influenced by it, there is a class of strictly
financial transactions called into being by and based
purely upon fluctuations in the exchange market, and
which act as automatic equalizers or cushions in that
market. T o illustrate by means of what is perhaps the
simplest instance of such transactions: the summer
period is ordinarily the time when the demand here for
remittance abroad is at its maximum. A t that time
comparatively little exchange is offered for sale as the
agricultural products that we export have not yet been
harvested, while the demand for exchange to meet the
expenditures of travelers, etc., are apt to reach important totals. Exchange is, therefore, normally high
at that time. It is well known that early in the fall
large shipments of cotton and grain will go abroad and
the exchange to pay for those shipments will then come
on the market. W e encounter, therefore, high exchange
rates in the summer with the chances strongly in favor
of lower rates two or three months later. Taking advantage of these circumstances, it has for years been
the practice for bankers during the summer to draw
upon their correspondents abroad, ninety-day bills
which they sell upon the New York market. T o the
banker the transaction is a simple one. 'He draws his
ninety-day bill because exchange is high and because

9
ho expects to be able ninety days later, at the time of
its maturity, to cover his bill by the purchase of exchange at a lower price. The proceeds of his bill he
lends in the American market. If he wishes to limit
his risk beyond the safety afforded by the gold points,
it is possible for him at the time of drawing his bill
to purchase for future delivery, and at lower rates,
cotton export or grain export bills, and also to lend
the proceeds of his drawings at fixed rates for ninety
days. The transaction, therefore, so far as he is concerned, can be made a closed transaction on which the
margin of profit is actually fixed. Such a transaction
viewed from the broader aspect of the community in
general, means the use by the banker of his credit f o r
the purpose of creating exchange when exchange is in
demand, and the corresponding absorption by him of
exchange ninety days later when it is in oversupply,
and in the meantime the availability in the American
market of sums which would otherwise have gone abroad
in the summer and been returned later.
Other
similar transactions arc constantly entered into by
bankers under the actuating impulse of an expected
profit. Their tendency always is to cushion the fluctuations of exchange and ail intelligent nse of these
trading devices by dealers redounds to the benefit of
the whole community. Another instance of the manner
in which profit-seeking operations of bankers, result
in economy to the business community, is afforded by
exchange arbitrage transactions. Such a transaction,
for instance, is the purchase in the London market of
exchange on Paris, the remittance of that exchange
t o Paris, the drawing of a d r a f t from New Y o r k 011 the
French balance thus created and the use of the proceeds of that draft in New York in the purchase of exchange 011 London, which exchange is then applied in

10
London to pay for the original purchase of French
exchange. W h a t this amounts to is a remittance of
money through the exchange market from New Y o r k
to London, thence to Paris, where it is in turn remitted
back to New York. Such a t ransaction must, of course,
be entered into by cable and with practical simultaneity
in the different markets and will not be attempted unless it promises a margin of profit. Such an operation
is not limited to three markets; nimble operators can
spread their transactions over four or five different
markets. The effect of such operations is the gam?'as
is the compensation of transactions involving a chain
of people, where the ultimate settlement takes places
only between the end parties. Let us assume that 011
balance of payments the Paris market is indebted to
the New Y o r k market, and the New Y o r k market is in
turn indebted to the London market. The balances
could, of course, be settled by shipment of gold from
Paris
to New York
and f r o m New Y o r k
to
London.
When
the accounts are in this condition there is an upward tendency in the price
of N e w Y o r k exchange in Paris and at the same
time the pressure for remittance from New York to
London tends to raise (he price of London exchange in
New York. The exchange operator, therefore, would
see a margin of profit by selling in Paris, exchange on
New York, which is high and investing the proceeds in
Paris, in exchange 011 London. At the same time he
would in New Y o r k sell London exchange, which is high
in New Y o r k and use the proceeds to meet the draft on
New Y o r k drawn and sold by him in Paris. As the last
step, the draft drawn by him in New York will be met
in London, through the remittance to London of the
bills which he originally purchased in Paris. Thus the
principal of his transactions cancels out. It will be

11
observed that these transactions have a tendency
through reducing the rate on New York in Paris, to
prevent the shipment of gold f r o m Paris to New Y o r k ;
through lowering the rate in New York 011 London, to
prevent the shipment of gold from New Y o r k to L o n d o n ;
and by raising Ihe rate 011 London in Paris t o cause
the shipment of gold from Paris to London. In other
words, a position which might have led to the shipment
of gold from Paris to New York and thence to London,
will be liquidated through the shipment of gold from
Paris direct (o London. This, it is clear, involves considerable economic saving, which is brought about by
no planning, but by the trader's instinctive pursuit of
a profit.
In these international financial transactions, the current rate for money in different markets is an important factor in determining the flow of credit. A high
money rate in New York, with a low money rate in LonLondon, will cause an immediate advance in New York
exchange rates in London, or, which is the same thing,
an immediate decline of London exchange rates in New
York, with the resulting tendency to keep down money
rates in New York and to advance them in London.
This has a tendency to bring about an equalization of
interest rates between different money markets and the
exchange rate between the markets is an important
element in determining these movements.
In transmitting credit in this way from a low money center to
a high money center the banker undertaking the transaction must have in mind not only the advantage in
the rate of interest that he can obtain in the higher
money markets, but also the possibility of a loss in
exchange when the time comes for calling his money
home. No purpose is served by multiplying these instances.

12
Tlie relation of the Federal Reserve System under
normal circumstances to the exchange market arises,
therefore, in two ways,—either through the relation of
the Federal Reserve Bank to interest rates or through
direct transactions by the Federal Reserve Banks in
the exchange market. The influence which it is possible
to exert through interest rates has been roughly indicated above. The Federal Reserve Bank in raising
its rates, will, under normal circumstances, be an important influence in raising the rate of interest in the
money market and the tendency of such action will be to
draw funds f r o m foreign centres to the United States,
or, which is the same thing, to depress the rates of these
foreign exchanges in tlie American market. On the
other hand, through a more liberal discount rate, the
reverse result can be accomplished. Under the Federal
Reserve A c t the Federal Reserve Banks have ample
power to enter the foreign exchange market direct as
purchasers and sellers and it is, therefore, in their power
t o influence rates by direct action in the market. I
should expect that under normal conditions, the power
of the Federal Reserve Banks would rather be exerted
indirectly through their influence on the money market,
than directly in the foreign exchange market itself, except, indeed, on occasions when the Federal Reserve
Banks as Fiscal Agents for the Treasury may have remittances or collections to make abroad on account of
transactions for the United States Treasury.
The competition of commercial banks in foreign exchange is so keen that the margin of profit is reduced
to a minimum and the occasion, therefore, for direct
action by the Federal Reserve Banks is not likely to
be frequent.
The above general outline is based on conditions as
they existed prior to the war. A t the present time few

13
countries are on a gold basis, but tlie same considerations apply equally to markets not on a gold basis, with
the important difference, however, that the absolute
limit of fluctuations set by the "gold points" is removed
and the risk of operation is thus vastly increased. This
tends to create a Avider margin of profit, commensurate
with fhe greater risk, but in essence fhe transactions
and the motives that underlike them are not different.
The war brought new problems in connection with
the foreign exchanges. Those problems had their origin
in fhe imposition of fhe embargo on the export of gold.
B y stopping the free flow of gold, the limits imposed by
" g o l d points" were removed and the problems that
arose, had their root in the resulting difficulty of our
Government or our citizens, or of both, in making payment for purchases abroad. By 1917, when we entered
the war, practically all other countries had placed an
embargo 011 the export of gold, or if they had not formally placed an embargo 011 its export, they had so
hedged about transactions in gold, that exports thereof
were as a matter of practice impossible.
Therefore,
when gold was required by any country, its natural
course was to secure a balance in dollars and t o procure gold here. That, of course, is only another way
of saying that we maintained a free gold market. But
a free gold market under natural conditions, is quite
another thing* from a free gold market when heavy
foreign loans are being continuously placed on that
market and when a large part of the proceeds of those
loans is exported to pay the borrowers' bills in other
countries.
The loans raised in this country by the Entente prior
to April, 1017, were used, among other things, to peg
their exchanges,—in other words, to maintain them at
a fixed level. A f t e r April G, 1917, the United States
Government began its large advances to its Associates

14
in the w a r : these advances were utilized by them for
expenditures in the United States, including in such
expenditures tlie support of their respective exchanges.
One result of this support of (he exchanges in the United
States was, that the bills on London given by our Associates to settle their indebtedness in other countries,
were sold in the New Y o r k market and the proceeds employed in the purchase on the New Y o r k market of exchange on neutral countries or in the shipment of gold
thither. In the circumstances, the drain of gold became
so heavy, amounting between July 13 and September 21,
101T, to $100,712,090, and the conditions that caused
its export seemed so certain to continue in operation,
that an embargo became necessary to protect our reserves and to forestall (he uneasiness that was likely
t o manifest itself, if the export continued.
As a consequence of this pegging of the exchanges,
the United States and its Associates, in respect of their
balance of payments, constituted a unit group, and the
total indebtedness of this unit group to any one country
outside of the group affected the rate of exchange on
that country in all of the Allied countries.
The pegging of (he exchanges by the Allies was a
sound policy. The moral effect of declining exchanges
would have been serious both in the encouragement to
(he enemy contained in a decline in this generally recognized index of international credit, as in the discouragement to Allied friends and partisans.
Further, the
pegging of the exchanges constituted the cheapest
method of payment for foreign purchases. W i s e administration, under these conditions, required that foreign
purchases by its nationals should be rigidly restricted to
necessaries by a country that was supporting its exchange, as every such purchase added to the burdens
thrown on the exchanges. This fact was recognized
and every effort was made to control such purchases.

15
The statement that the pegging of the exchanges was
a sound policy, must be understood as meaning a sound
war policy. A s soon as normal motives and reactions
began to re-assert themselves, it became a menace, because of the artificial obstacles it opposed to a return
t o normal. The practice was in fact terminated by both
the British and French in March, 1919. In normal
times such a policy is unsound. I t creates foreign debt
instead of domestic debt. It: tends to stimulate imports
when imports should be checked. It checks the normal
stimulus to export commodities and, more important, to
export securities, when exports should be stimulated. It
tends to retard foreign investment in that country and
the carrying of foreign balances there. There has been
much talk about stabilizing exchange. W e must remember—and I need not here expound the matter at
length, as a mere reference to the subject will recall
its essential features—that the exchanges are but the
index of the state of the balance of payments. When
foreign payments exceed foreign receipts on all
heads, visible and invisible, we have a weak exchange,
and vice versa. The exchanges are the thermometer, not
the temperature.
Stabilizing exchange—under whatever alluring guise it may masquerade—always involves
loans to the market whose exchange is being stabilized.
It is the effort to borrow for (he purpose of balancing
an unbalanced account.
"Thank God—that debt is
paid," said the minister when his church settled its indebtedness by giving a mortgage.
The embargo placed by us on the export of gold was
thus a necessary consequence of the pegging of the
British and French exchanges as soon as our advances
to those countries assumed important dimensions.
Otherwise our shipments of gold might have seriously
impaired our reserves. No country was permitting the

16
export of gold except Mexico, to which we permitted
the shipment of an equivalent amount of gold coin, aud
a certain fixed proportion in gold in return for silver
shipped in to us. Some small shipments were also received f r o m countries lacking refineries and mints. W e
had no means of knowing how long the war would last
and the prospect was, that should the war prove of
long duration, our gold losses might well be so great
as to prevent our resuming specie payments at its termination. The amounts that the Orient might absort)
were incalculable. Above all, we had no means of measuring the effect of a continued loss of gold on t7ie confidence of our own people. W e were yet young in war,
and had not accommodated ourselves to its abnormalities. T w o years later we might have seen our last dollar go without pang. A t that early stage, it might have
precipitated a panic and seriously jeopardized oui war
financing.
There were economists—rated as eminent—who implored those responsible for Government financial policies, to resume the export of gold, on the simple ground
that as the import of gold between 191.1 and 1917 had
put up prices, so now its export would send prices down.
Without now stopping to discuss wher.lier the premise
is correct, we can probably agree that the suggested
remedy was childish.
A n inflated system cannot be
cured with the hair of the dog that bit it—and we have
seen that inflation was inevitable.
A word should be said in passing on the policy of several European countries during the war, of either prohibiting the import of gold or of receiving it for coinage
only at a discount. Sweden first prohibited its import,
and then placed a discount of 8 % on gold when reeeiving it for coinage. Spain placed a 0 % discount on gold.
In both cases the purpose was to keep down commodity
prices. In both cases, the device failed, as commodity

'

17
X>rices nevertheless rose because of the scarcity of commodities, while failure to balance their budgets caused
inflation. It is obvious that such a discount (so-called)
on gold is equivalent to an increase in the gold content
of the standard coin. The coin remains the same, but
the amount of gold that must be tendered to obtain it,
is increased. It is the change f o r the time being in the
standard of value.
T o complete this review a word is required on the
removal in June, 1919, of the export embargo on gold.
The Allies had by that time discontinued the pegging of
their exchange: most of the trade restrictions imposed
by the W a r Trade Board had been removed, and it
seemed necessary at the earliest moment consistent with
safety, to put into effect the natural check on credit
expansion imposed by automatic gold movements. However, other countries had as yet not removed the embargo, and there was 110 possible w a y of judging when
or to what extent they would do so. W h i l e a return by
them to their par of exchange seemed remote, it did
seem that gold might, and probably would, be sent by
them to prevent further declines. The most important
factors of uncertainty touching the amount of gold we
would be called on to ship, were the demands of India,
which could not be gauged, and the possible demands of
South American and neutral European countries.
These countries had been unable theretofore to employ
the funds received in payment of their merchandise sales
to us, either 111 shipping gold o r in purchasing commodities to any adequate extent in our market, and, as
a consequence, had accumulated large balances in our
banks. The control we had instituted over exchange
had been so perfected that we had accurate returns
showing just what these balances amounted to, but
we could not judge how they would be employed.

18
A f t e r gauging the situation as carefully as possible,
the embargo was removed with full confidence that it
was a judicious step. A n d so it has proved to be. The
removal of the embargo was followed by an export of
about $445,000,000 gold, before any large amount of
gold began to move toward us. The net loss of gold
through exports between June 1, and December 31,
1919, amounted to $171,000,000 after taking account
of $173,000,000 German gold received by the United
States Grain Corporation in payment of food sold to
Germany, which, while the major part of it was actually
brought into this country, only in October and November, 1920, had theretofore been incorporated in the
reserves of the Federal Reserve Ranks, and had been
held earmarked for their account by the Bank of England. This was, of course, equivalent to an import of
gold.
Gold imports from Europe in appreciable
amounts began in March, 1920.
I t was contended by persons who instinctively felt
that step to herald the beginning of deflation, and who,
in imagination, felt the pinch that deflation involves,
that we were permitting ourselves to be used for the
benefit of other countries: that gold exports to South
America were to a great extent for British or French
account, and that the process should be stopped. These
people failed to realize that a free gold market means,
that anyone who can control a dollar balance must be
permitted to convert it into gold.
The free gold market was, as you know, maintained,
and we have become accustomed to seeing exports without panic, and imports without exultation, successively,
and, at times, simultaneously, regarding both as normal
functions of an international market.
The situation arising out of these conditions, that had
to be met, was the difficulty in making payment abroad

19
f o r our war purchases, at a time when Ave dared not
send gold, and when we could spare only a limited
quantity of commodities. W e did what we could, to
export commodities we could spare. The necessity of
releasing all possible commodities for export for the
purpose of paying our bills, was never lost sight of by
the W a r Trade Board, and while this was, to a certain
extent, feasible in our dealings.with South America and
the Orient, where there was cargo space on returning
ships, it was very difficult in our dealings with Neutral
Europe, where the freight movement was all one way.
Reference to the steps taken during the period of control to meet our foreign indebtedness, with a minimum
of loss and discomfort, must necessarily be brief and
somewhat disjointed. These steps went hand in hand
with the licensing of gold and silver for export, and
with the control of the exchanges, all of which were administered by the Federal Reserve Board in conjunction
with the Secretary of the Treasury.
A n d first as to silver:— •
Purchases of war material in the Orient reached huge
totals during the war. Jute, hides, shellac and other
products from India and China were required for army
and civilian use, and through competitive buying, their
values had reached unprecedented levels.
Silver is, in normal times, by preference the money
metal of India, and it is the only money metal of China,
but silver production during the war did not suffice to
meet the enormous balances of trade in favor of these
countries. The insufficiency of silver to meet this need
led to heavy demands on gold for the purpose of filling
the v a c u u m : the embargo 011 gold cut off this method
of payment. In dealing with Oriental populations, it
is impossible, except in a limited way in India, to
utilize paper in place of metallic money, and the provi

20
sion of sufficient silver to meet the debt of tlie Orient
became a pressing problem. This situation was first
dealt with by limiting exports of silver to payment f o r
war necessities, and later by a further limitation on the
export of silver which conlined licenses to silver that
had been purchased at not above $1 per fine o u n c e —
later changed to ^l.OlVa per ounce. This was but a partial solution. A more permanent one was found in the
passage of the Pitt man Act, which authorized tlie Secretary of the Treasury to melt $350,000,000 of standard
silver dollars and to use the proceeds, to quote the
words of the A c t :
" f o r the purpose of conserving the existing stock of
gold in the United States, of facilitating the settlement in silver of trade balances adverse to the
United States, of providing silver for subsidiary
coinage and for commercial use, and of assisting
foreign governments at war with the enemies of the
United States."
This A c t contemplated no permanent change in our
currency system, but simply provided for the temporary use of silver dollars, which were in circulation
only through the silver certificates that represented
them, and which for all practical purposes were lying
unused in the Treasury. It contemplated in due time
the repurchase of tlie silver at the price of
per line
ounce and its recoinage into standard silver dollars.
Standard silver dollars could be melted only after the
corresponding silver certificates had been withdrawn
from circulation and, as stated above, provision was
made for the ultimate recoinage of the standard silver
dollars. In the meantime, to prevent contraction of the
currency, Federal Reserve Bank notes were to be issu-

21
able in denominations of $1 and $2. Under the provisions of this act 200,000,000 ounces of silver were
sold to the British Government, which, in connection
with the purchase of the silver, undertook to provide
rupee remittances for the war needs of the United
States.
Arrangements thus made stabilized rupee
exchange in the United States f o r the period of the war
and for a considerable period following the armistice,
and by the simple device above outlined, permitted a
difficult and, in many respects, delicate situation to be
successfully dealt with.
Some 31,700,000 ounces of silver have been repurchased under the provisions of the Pittman Act.
During the year 1919 difficulties of a different nature
arose in connection with silver. To quote the report
of the Federal Reserve Board f o r the year 1919:
"Continued and insistent demand for silver in
China and the Orient generally led to a gradual
increase in the price of silver, which on November
25, 1919, sold as high as $1.3875 per ounce. The
bullion value of the silver content of the standard
silver dollar is equal to $1 when silver sells a t
$1,2929 per fine ounce. The bullion value of the
silver content of our subsidiary coinage is equal
to its face value when silver sells at $1.88. It is
evident, therefore, that when silver rises appreciably above $1.29 per ounce, our standard silver
dollars can be exported at a profit, and that should
silver remain for any length of time above $1.38 our
subsidiary silver coinage would be subject to export. Standard silver dollars must, of course, be
delivered on presentation for redemption of silver
certificates, which are in effect trust receipts calling for the delivery of a specified number of stand-

22
ard silver dollars.
A p a r t from silver so held,
however, there is a considerable number of standard silver dollars free 111 the Treasury. In order to
protect our subsidiary coinage from export it was
deemed advisable to utilize the standard silver dollars free in the Treasury in order, so far as possible,
so to control the rates of exchange with silver standard countries as not t o permit the export of our subsidiary silver coinage to become profitable. The
Board, in cooperation with the Treasury Department, accordingly arranged with American banks
having their own branches in the Orient, and included in the arrangement all American banks so
situated, whereby these banks under the direction
of the Division of Foreign Exchange of the Federal
Reserve Board, will be enabled to utilize such
standard silver dollars in meeting Oriental demands. This arrangement was announced by the
Board 011 December (>, 1919, in a statement reading
as f o l l o w s :
'Announcement was made to-day that under
arrangements made between the Treasury and the
Federal Reserve Board, standard silver dollars
that are free in the Treasury will until further notice be delivered against other forms of money to
the Division of Foreign Exchange of the Federal
Reserve Board, which will, through the Federal
Reserve Bank of New York, cooperating with the
branches of American banks in the Orient, employ
such dollars in regulating our exchanges with silverstandard countries.
This arrangement docs not, of course, affect the
redemption of outstanding silver certificates in
standard silver dollars.' "

23
A second class of difficulties arose in our commercial
relations with certain South American countries from
whom we were receiving hides, wool, nitrates and other
essentials, and by whom our associates in the war were
being supplied with grain, beef and other foodstuffs.
The exchanges of ail South American countries rose to
extreme premiums in the United States and the Allied
countries, and the question of dealing with these exchanges became a very difficult and urgent problem.
Negotiations were inaugurated with various of these
countries, and led to arrangements with a number ol
them; with other countries the arrangements were still
under negotiations when the war came to an end. The
general plan suggested in all these cases was the same
in its general principle, although it differed in a number of the details, these differences of detail taking the
line of least resistance and depending to a great extent
011 the views of the Finance Ministers of the Governments involved.
The arrangement can best be illustrated by instancing what was done in the case of the
Argentine.
Parties desiring to remit to the Argentine were permitted to deposit with the Federal Reserve Bank of
New Y o r k f o r credit of the Banco de la Nacion (the
National bank of the Argentine) the amount which they
desired to transmit. The Banco de la Nacion in turn
made payment in the Argentine to the parties desig;
nated by the depositor, at the gold par of exchange less
a deduction of 3 % . This arrangement was to be effective up to $60,000,000. Its effect was to stabilize Argentine exchange required for war purposes at a premium of 3 % . Deposits were received by the Federal
Reserve Bank only in cases approved by the Federal Reserve Board through its Division of Foreign Exchange,
and were limited to deposits made for purposes essential

24
to the prosecution of the war. In other words, there was
no attempt to stabilize exchange generally, the use of
the facilities being confined strictly to war purposes.
This arrangement worked perfectly. It was a part of
the arrangement that within six months after the signing of tlie Treaty of Peace with Germany, the Banco
de la Nacion should be permitted to withdraw from the
Federal Reserve Bank in gold and to ship out of the
country whatever amount then remained to its credit
in this account. A s soon as the embargo on the
export of gold from (his country was raised, the
Argentine Govern men?" was notified that the Banco de
Ja Nacion was free to withdraw its balance f r o m the
Federal Reserve Bank and to ship gold out of the country, so that the limitation on the shipment of the balance in gold, to six months after the conclusion of a
Treaty of Peace was not insisted on. As a matter of
fact, only a portion of the balance was ever actually
shipped in gold. A f t e r the conclusion of the armistice,
our trade relations gradually assumed a more normal
aspect. The W a r Trade Board restrictions on exports
and imports were taken down with great promptness, and
all parts of the world, long deprived of goods through
embargoes, purchased commodities in this country 011 a
large scale. This increase of our exports, together with
the shipment of gold following the removal of the embargo, gradually and steadily brought the exchange rates
of the rest of the world to a discount as compared with
dollars.
In these circumstances, the Argentine exchange rate went to a discount as compared with dollars and the balance to the credit of the Banco de la
Nacion with the Federal Reserve Bank was drawn down
through drafts drawn by the Banco de la Nacion for
the purposes of steadying the Argentine peso in its relation to the dollar and of preventing the peso from go-

25
ing to too great a discount. The entire balance of the
Banco de la Nacion with the Federal Reserve Bank was
withdrawn before the end of 1020.
Arrangements similar in substance were made with
Bolivia and Peru, but the delays in perfecting them
were so great that they had been availed of to only a
limited extent when the end of the war reversed the
position. All those currencies are now at a discount
compared with the dollar.
Three other classes of exchange arrangements were
made during the war. An arrangement with Switzerland placed at the disposal of the United States Treasury some 75,000,000 Swiss francs in return for a corresponding amount of dollars at the par of exchange.
The Swiss francs, under the arrangement, were to the
availed of only in certain fixed instalments at definite
times, and their use was by the arrangement limited to
governmental purposes. The American Expeditionary
Force had made important puchases of supplies in
Switzerland, and the balance thus created was used,
broadly speaking for the purposes of the W a r Department. It will be remembered that one of the chief
problems in connection with the sending abroad of our
troops and their supply on the other side, arose out of
the difficulty of obtaining sufficient shipping, and, therefore, wherever supplies could be purchased abroad the
saving of shipping thus affected, made it imperative
that the purchases should be so made. Payment for these
purchases became a very difficult problem. It was solved
in the case of Switzerland in the manner outlined above.
A different arrangement was entered into in connection with Norway and Sweden. In the case of those
countries, the W a r Trade Board for a short time exacted
from our exporters to those countries as a condition for
the issue to them of export licenses, that the proceeds

26
of the sales in the Swedish and Norwegian countries
should be deposited at ihe par of exchange in the national banks of the respective countries for use of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York. The effect of this
was to raise the price in local currency, to purchasers
of our commodities in the countries concerned. These
last mentioned arrangements might have involved large
sums had the war continued. As it was, they involved
comparatively unimportant amounts.
Lastly, an arrangement of different form and involving a comparatively large amount was concluded by
the Treasury Department with a group of banks in
Spain, acting in conjunction with the Bank of Spain.
The American Expeditionary Force was able to purchase supplies in Spain, such as mules, saddle leather,
fodder, etc., and as Spanish exchange in the United
States was at a premium of perhaps 4 0 % , the method
of payment for those supplies became an extraordinarily
difficult question. T o meet this difficulty, a Commissioner of the United Slates Treasury proceeded to Spain
and arranged there with a group of banks, that they
were to accept drafts drawn by a group of banks in the
United States, to an amount of not exceeding 250,000,000 Spanish pesetas. The drafts so accepted were to
be discounted by banks of the Spanish group, rediscounted by the Bank of Spain and the proceeds placed
at the disposal of the Federal Reserve Bank of New
Y o r k with the Bank of Spain. The drafts so drawn
were secured by United States Certificates of Indebtedness issued and payable in Spanish pesetas.
The
United States Treasury availed itself of this credit
to the extent of 155,000,000 pesetas.
The group
of banks in the United States was formed by the Federal Reserve Board through its Division of Foreign Exchange. This group co-operated heartily with the Fed-

27
f?ral Reserve Board in the entire transaction. The machinery for handling these bankers' bills and securing
their discount was complicated and vexatious. I t was,
however, thoroughly worked out and put through without a hitch. The saving to the United States Government through this arrangement was enormous.
The
•premium on Spanish exchange, as above stated, was 4 0 %
when the transaction was undertaken, and in view of
the large amounts involved, it would probably have been
impossible to complete the transaction even at a very
high premium, without shipment of gold. Undoubtedly
it would have been necessary to ship large amounts of
gold to Spain. This, it was desirable at that time, to
avoid. The bills of exchange drawn under this arrangement, including several renewals, ran for a sufficient
length of time so that after the conclusion of hostilities
it was possible gradually to liquidate them through the
exchange market. The entire transaction was wound
up, not only without any loss to the Government, but at
a very moderate cost f o r interest in respect of the
moneys so raised. Spanish exchange is now at a considerable discount in dollars.
This outline of what was actually accomplished by
the Treasury and the Federal Reserve Board during the
war in meeting extraordinary situations in connection
with the foreign exchanges has, of course, 110 real bearing on the permanent development of the Federal Reserve System in its relation to the foreign exchanges.
It is interesting, however, as showing the flexibility of
the system and its capacity to adapt itself without
strain to extraordinary situations.
A s bearing on the permanent relations of the System
to the foreign exchanges, attention should be called to
reciprocal arrangements that the Federal Reserve
Banks, with the approval of the Federal Reserve Board,

28
have made with the Government banks of various
countries, wlicreby the central or government banks of
those countries are ready to act as correspondents and
agents of the Federal Reserve Banks and the Federal
Reserve Banks in this country reciprocally are ready to
act as agents of the foreign banks. Through the medium
thus established, the foreign banks are in a position to
buy bills in the United States when it suits their general policy to employ funds in this country, and the
Federal Reserve Banks arc placed in a position where
they can employ funds abroad when their general policy
makes this seem desirable. Arrangements have thus
been made with the Bank of England, the Bank of
France, the Bank of Japan, the Nederlandsehe Bank, the
Javasche Bank, and perhaps some others.
In my judgment, wise administration of the Federal
Reserve System will leave the field of foreign exchange
to private initiative, seeking to control the flow of
credit and of the money metals, through changes in the
discount rate, and intervening directly in the foreign
exchange markets only, 011 what 1 believe will prove to
be rare occasions, when commercial banks may be unable
or unwilling to assist in giving effect to the Board's
policies.

32248-