View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
8:40 a.m. Mexico City time (9:40 a.m. EST)
November 12, 2002

"The Wealth of Nations Revisited"
Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Banco de Mexico's Second International Conference:
Macroeconomic Stability, Financial Markets and Economic Development
Mexico City
November 12, 2002

More than two hundred years ago, Adam Smith offered the first comprehensive
examination of why some countries are able to grow and have high standards of living
while others make little progress. In The Wealth of Nations, Smith put forward a number
of explanations for the different paths that countries follow. He accurately identified
capital accumulation, free trade, an appropriate—butcirumscribed—

role

for government,

and good "institutional infrastructure" as key drivers of national prosperity. Perhaps
most important, he emphasized the role of personal initiative:
The natural effort of every individual to better his own condition, when
suffered to exert itself with freedom and security, is so powerful a
principle, that it is . . . capable of carrying on the society to wealth and
prosperity.. 1
In his writings, Smith gave us an invaluable start in our efforts to answer
what is probably the most important macroeconomic question, that is, "What
makes an economy grow?" In this very real sense, we are Adam Smith's
intellectual descendants. We are still endeavoring to craft answers to questions
similar to the ones he asked and, we hope, learning what policies and institutions
are best able to create wealth and so enable nations to prosper.
The debate regarding the sources of economic growth has markedly
twisted and turned in recent decades. Following World War II, some countries
seemed to pull back from the free-market paradigm articulated by Adam Smith.
Many observers interpreted the economic turmoil of the Great Depression as a
sign that free markets were flawed, and they increasingly looked to the apparently
successful efforts of wartime planned economies. They thought that perhaps

l

Smith (1776), Vol. II, book IV, chapter V, p.43.

governments could also coordinate the far more complex activities of civilian
economies.
These more interventionist attitudes toward economic policy implied
increased regulation of industry, greater government ownership of productive
assets, higher tax rates to fund broadened social welfare initiatives, and in some
instances controls on wages and prices. These policies were believed to improve
the functioning of markets and to maintain economic stability and growth. Not
until the 1970s—and the economic difficulties of that decade—did the realization
finally take hold that market incentives had been reduced and that we were losing
the dividend of efficient uses of resources that such incentives provide. Even
those observers who derided the more unbridled forms of capitalism became
increasingly aware that attempts to tame the market could be costly in terms of
economic growth and the average living standards of a nation.
Over the past thirty years, as many countries have struggled to liberalize
their economies and improve the quality of their policies, global per capita
income has steadily risen.2 I recognize that poverty rates are notoriously hard to
quantify, but according to a recent study, the share of the world's population
living on less than $1 per day, a commonly used poverty threshold, has fallen
dramatically over the past threedecades—

from

17 percent in 1970 to 7 percent in

1998, representing a decline of 200 million people.3 In addition since 1970, the

2

World Bank (2002)-GDP per capita (constant 1995 dollars).

3

Sala-i-Martin (2002). The $1 per day threshold is measured in 1985 dollars on a
Purchasing Power Parity basis.

infant mortality rate has declined by more than half, school enrollment rates have
risen steadily over the past thirty years, and literacy rates are up.4
While, from a global perspective, wealth and the overall quality of life
have risen, that success has not been evenly distributed across regions or
countries. The economies of East Asia are often-repeated success stories. Some,
including China, Malaysia, South Korea, and Thailand, stand out not only as
growing very strongly, but also as having seen the greatest declines in poverty
rates. Overall, over the past three decades, Asia's $1 per day poverty rate fell by
one measure from 22 percent in 1970 to just 2 percent in 1998.5 Moreover, Asia
was not alone. Per capita incomes in Latin America also expanded during the
period, and poverty rates fell, although progress was somewhat slower.6
But, sadly, the story in Africa has been quite different. Levels of per
capita income in that continent have actually fallen.7 The poverty rate, which in
1970 matched the rate in Asia at the time, is estimated to have doubled to 40
percent by 1998. While Africa's performance has clearly been subpar, some
African countries have had some success. For example, Botswana, Lesotho, and

4

World Bank (2002).

5

Sala-i-Martin (2002).

6

World Bank (2002)--GDP per capita (constant 1995 dollars) for the per capita
income data and Sala-i-Martin (2002) for the poverty data.
7

World Bank (2002)-GDP per capita (constant 1995 dollars).

8

Sala-i-Martin (2002).

more recently Uganda have made some progress in raising per capita income
growth and reducing poverty rates.9
Modern economic analysis has confirmed much of what Adam Smith
inferred from a far less impressive set of data. Today's economists generally
point to three important characteristics influencing growth: (1) the extent of a
country's openness to trade and its integration with the rest of the world, (2) the
quality of a country's institutional infrastructure, and (3) the success of its
policymakers in implementing the measures necessary for macroeconomic
stability.
By openness and integration we generally mean the ability for goods and
services, capital, and more broadly, the flow of information, people, technology,
and ideas to move across the borders of a country. This freedom of movement
may enhance growth by intensifying competitive pressures, increasing
specialization, and allowing access to larger markets.
Free trade allows the more efficient use of resources which, in turn, raises
both the productivity of the domestic workforce and the level of national income.
Adam Smith cited comparative advantage. He observed:
If a foreign country can supply us with a commodity cheaper than we
ourselves can make it, better buy it of them with some part of the produce
of our own industry employed in a way in which we have some
advantage.l0

9

Sala-i-Martin (2002) and World Bank (2002)--GDP per capita (constant 1995

dollars).
l0

Smith (1776), Vol. I, book IV, chapter II, p. 422.

One recent study of the effects of openness on growth demonstrated that
when countries are divided into twogroups—

those

with generally open economies

and those with generally closed economies-open economies have experienced
average growth that is21/2percentage points higher than the growth of closed
economies.l1 Furthermore, when developing economies are ranked according to
their historical record of openness, economies such as Hong Kong, Malaysia,
Singapore, and Thailand are near the top of the list.12 These Asian economies are
some of the same ones that participated in the region's so-called growth miracle.
For another example of a country that has benefited from free trade, we
need look no further thanMexico—

our

host today. During the early 1980s,

Mexico's non-oil merchandise exports were running a bit below $10 billion a
year, or about 5 percent of its gross domestic product. By 2001, however,
Mexico's exports of such goods had soared to more than $145 billion, or nearly
24 percent of GDP. The strength of exports has contributed importantly to the
ongoing transformation of Mexico's economy. A good portion of this export
growth has occurred in the context of the North American Free Trade Agreement,
but the most important effects of NAFTA may be the increased openness of
Mexico's domestic economy and the associated policy reforms.
A second characteristic that economists have identified as influencing a
country's ability to grow is termed its "institutional infrastructure." By this we
mean the institutions that help make an economy work, such as a functioning

"Sachs and Warner (1995).
12

Sachs and Warner (1995).

legal system, which ensures the rule of law and protects property rights. These
institutions are responsible for setting the "rules of the game" and ensuring that
those rules are observed.
Sound institutions provide the backdrop against which markets operate.
They foster confidence that contracts will be honored, that debts will be paid, and
that the gains from sound investments will not be stolen or expropriated.
Researchers in recent years have found that the rule of law-defined as a
system that emphasizes creditor rights and rigorously enforces contractsfacilitates the development of an efficient banking system and financial markets
more generally; this development, in turn, supports growth.13 The quality of the
institutions in a country-such as a sound regulatory environment, political
stability, and the control of corruption—have important effects on growth.14
Economies with a high quality of governance, relative to other economies in their
regions, including Hong Kong and Singapore in Asia, Chile in South America,
and Botswana in Africa, have had some of the fastest growth rates in their
respective regions in recent decades.15
The quality of a country's educational system is clearly a significant part
of its broader institutional infrastructure. Policies that foster the human resources
of a country improve growth. Many studies exhibit a link between education and

13

Levine (1998) and Levine and Zervos (1998).

l4

Kaufmann, Kraay, and Zoido-Lobaton (1999).

15

Kaufmann, Kraay, and Zoido-Lobaton (1999).

growth, with some showing that even a small increase in average education can
lead to a sustained rise in the rate of economic expansion.16
Finally, an undeniable determinant of economic growth is macroeconomic
stability-having fiscal, monetary, and exchange rate policies that are sound and
predictable. A prudent government sets, among other things, the long-run course
of policy variables such as inflation, the government budget deficit, and debt at
levels that are conducive to, or at least do not impede, growth. For developing
countries, the management of debt denominated in foreign currencies has been
especially nettlesome.
In all economies, political constituencies seek to employ the powers of the
state to increase their share of limited national resources. While the record of
developed economies is far from unblemished, they have had greater success in
fending off such demands. One indication of that success is that exchange-rate
regimes have not often been upended by domestic political pressures in these
economies.
Although the range of outcomes has been wide, many emerging-market
nations have had less success in insulating their international financial positions
from domestic political pressures. Those pressures, at times, have become
exceptionally difficult to deal with. To close the gap between the financial
demands of political constituencies and the limited real resources available to
their governments, many countries too often have bridged the difference by
borrowing from foreign investors. In effect, the path of least resistance has been
l6

Barro(1997).

8
external borrowing, usually at the lower interest rates of internationally tradable
currencies, rather than confronting politically difficult tradeoffs.
Periodically, as an economy borrows its way to the edge of insolvency
with debt denominated in foreign currency, government debt-raising capacity
appears to vanish virtually overnight. This vanishing capacity characterizes
almost all financial crises. Lending institutions will provide funds beyond the
immediate visible short-term cash flow of a borrower only if they perceive that
maturing debt will be rolled over. The first whiff of inadequacy in debt-raising
capacity induces a run to the exits—not unlike a bank run. Thus, an economy's
necessary condition for solvency—indeed, a necessary condition for economic
growth—is the maintenance of significant unused financing capacity. Too often
governments have endeavored to contain impending debt crises with inflationary
policies that inhibit growth.
Controlling inflation is essential to creating an environment of sustained
growth. Once inflation gets above a certain point, it has a large negative effect on
growth, according to most research. Stanley Fischer, for example, concluded that
if a country with inflation of 10 percent becomes a country with inflation of 110
percent, its annual growth rate would fall 4 percentage points; the consequences
of this for standards of living can hardly be overemphasized.17 This effect may
help to explain why East Asia, where inflation has been relatively low on average,
has been more successful than Latin America, where many countries have
suffered bouts of hyperinflation.
17

Fischer(1993).

More generally, Latin America provides a good example of both the
deleterious effects of macroeconomic instability and the benefits of putting sound
policies in place. Between 1975 and 1990, when many Latin American countries
struggled with large budget deficits and high inflation, average per capita income
1 ft

in these countries expanded at a pace of just1/2percent per year.

Economic

performance in the region improved markedly in the early 1990s, as these
countries reduced inflation, liberalized their foreign exchange regime, increased
their openness to trade, and developed their financial markets.19 More recently,
while Argentina, Brazil, and several other countries in the region have
experienced economic disruptions, Mexico and Chile have remained relatively
insulated, apparently reflecting market confidence that these countries are
committed to sound policies.
Mexico is a particularly interesting case. In the two decades before 1995,
the Mexican economy suffered several severe crises. Yet in recent years, with the
implementation of NAFTA, a floating exchange rate regime, relatively stable
fiscal policies, and much lower inflation, Mexico's vulnerability appears to have
declined markedly. This country now seems to be viewed by international
investors as a relative "safe haven" within the region.
As Easterly and Levine indicate, much of Africa's plight can also be
linked to macroeconomic instability. Empirical evidence suggests that Africa's
large government budget deficits, underdeveloped financial markets, and black18

World Bank (2002)--GDP per capita (constant 1995 dollars).

19

Easterly(2001).

10
market foreign-exchange premiums (which likely proxy for a host of deficiencies
in the financial and legal system) apparently explain roughly half the growth
divergence between East Asia and Africa over the past several decades. In other
words, these results suggest to Easterly and Levine that growth of per capita
annual income in Africa would have been about 2-1/2 percentage points a year
higher had countries in Africa followed policies adopted by the East Asian
economies.20
Central bank independence has not received a great deal of attention in the
recent literature on growth. Given the importance of keeping inflation under
control, the policies of the central bank~and the freedom of the central bank to set
those policies without political intervention-can play a key role in creating an
environment conducive to growth.
Empirical evidence for industrial countries indicates that countries with a
higher degree of central bank independence are also generally countries with
lower rates of inflation.21 In emerging markets and transition economies, the
evidence of an association between measured central bank independence and
inflation rates is not well-established, although a couple of very recent studies do
find a negative relationship.22
To sum up, none of today's recognized fundamental determinants of
growth—openness, institutional infrastructure, and macroeconomic stability—are

20

Easterly and Levine (1997) cited in Easterly (2001).

21

Alesina and Summers (1993).

22

Gutierrez (2002) and Cukierman, Miller, and Neyapti (2002).

11
recent insights. Adam Smith and his colleagues proffered them more than two
centuries ago. Yet assuming that Smith's complex insights into what creates the
wealth of nations are accurate, why have they been embraced and largely
implemented by some societies and not others? As history amply demonstrates,
unless a broad majority of a population implicitly or otherwise believes that a
competitive free market paradigm advances their welfare, it cannot for long be
imposed on them by an authoritarian or even a democratically elected
government.
That an "invisible hand" converts self-centered behavior into a greater
good is a profoundly abstract notion that—while largely, but by no means fully,
embraced by developed nations—has been held only tentatively, even recently, by
many developing nations. If not in some sense seen as generally equitable and
fair, the distribution of income that emerges from competitive free-market
capitalism will not have the support in law that is a necessary condition for
markets to produce wealth. Now that the central planning paradigm of earlier
decades has been largely discarded, the differential rewards of competitive
markets based on skill do seem to be accepted though rewards from what is
perceived as monopolistic or corrupt are not.
It is hence incumbent on those of us who see broader and market-based
globalization as fundamental to the creation of wealth to defend and advocate the
tenets of Adam Smith.

12
References
Alesina, Alberto, and Lawrence H. Summers (1993), "Central Bank Independence and
Macroeconomic Performance: Some Comparative Evidence," Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking, vol. 25 (May), pp. 151-62.
Barro, Robert J. (1997), Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical
Study, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Cukierman, Alex, Geoffrey Miller, and Bilin Neyapti (2002), "Central Bank Reform,
Liberalization, and Inflation in Transition Economies: An International Perspective,"
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 49 (March), pp. 237-64.
Easterly, William, and Ross Levine (1997), "Africa's Growth Tragedy. Policies and
Ethnic Divisions," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 112 (November), pp. 1203-50.
Easterly, William (2001), The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists' Adventures and
Misadventures in the Tropics, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Fischer, Stanley (1993), "The Role of Macroeconomic Factors in Growth," Journal of
Monetary Economics, vol. 32 (December), pp. 485-512.
Gutierrez, Eva (2002), "Inflation Performance and Constitutional Central Bank
Independence: Evidence from Latin America," IMF Working Paper (June).
Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton (1999), "Governance Matters,"
World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2196.
Levine, Ross (1998), "The Legal Environment, Banks, and Long-Run Economic
Growth," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, vol. 30 (August, pt. 2), pp. 596-613.
Levine, Ross, and Sara Zervos (1998), "Stock Markets, Banks, and Economic Growth,"
American Economic Review, vol. 88 (June), pp. 537-58.
Sachs, Jeffrey, and Andrew Warner (1995), "Economic Reform and the Process of
Global Integration," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1995:1, pp. 1-118.
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (2002), "The World Distribution of Income (Estimated from
Individual Country Distributions)," National Bureau of Economic Research Working
Paper 8933.
Smith, Adam (1776), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, 5th
ed. (edited by Edwin Cannan, 1930), vols. I and II, London: Metheun and Co.
World Bank (2002), World Development Indicators, Washington, D.C.