View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
9-30 a m EDT
October 3, 1990

Testimony by

Alan Greenspan

Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Subcommittee on Commerce, Consumer, and Monetary Affairs

of the
Committee on Government Operations

U.S

House of Representatives

October 3, 1990

I am pleased to appear before the Committee to discuss deposit
insurance reform

The issue has increasingly come to the attention of the

Congress and the media as the cost of resolution of failed thrift
institutions becomes more apparent, and as various government and private
reports focus on the potential liabilities facing the Bank Insurance Fund
Last year the Congress mandated a study of the issues by the Treasury
This study, in which the Federal Reserve, the FDIC, the OCC, the OTS, and
other agencies will be active participants, will be published later this
year or early next

But hearings on the issues now by this and several

other Committees of the Congress will, I hope, sharpen the focus on the
need for legislation promptly after the release of the Treasury report
Your letter of invitation, Mr

Chairman, focuses on the issues

associated with the feasibility, benefits, and risks of some reduction in
insurance coverage and the associated potential for enhanced depositor
discipline

The Board has considered these highly complex and important

questions on several occasions

My statement today will summarize our

views on this approach to the problem, but the Board believes it is
important for the Congress to review options other than reduced insurance
coverage in order to address the root cause of the taxpayer exposure and
the potential financial market distortions associated with our present
deposit insurance and supervisory approaches
As you know, Mr

Chairman, the Board also believes that deposit

insurance reform is intimately related to the pressing need to modernize
our banking system in other ways.

The erosion of the domestic and

international competitive position of U S. banks must be addressed by

- 2 expanded permissible activities and wider geographical branching powers,
and we believe that legislation in this area should be joined with deposit
insurance reform

I have presented the Board's proposals on these

subjects before the Senate and House Banking Committees this summer.
Given the narrower focus of the hearings today, and the additional
witnesses this morning/ I have omitted a detailed delineation of the
Board's modernization proposals, but I nevertheless want to underline
their importance, with the strong endorsement that these issues should, in
the Board's view, be considered jointly with deposit insurance reform by
this Committee and by both Houses of the Congress
The fundamental problems with our current deposit insurance
program are clearly understood and are, I believe, subject to little
debate among those with drastically different prescriptions for reform
The safety net—deposit insurance, as well as the discount window—has so
lowered the risks perceived by depositors as to make them relatively
indifferent to the soundness of the depository recipients of their funds,
except in unusual circumstances

With depositors exercising insufficient

discipline through the risk premium they demand on the interest rate they
receive on their deposits, the incentive of some banks' owners to control
risk-taking has been blunted.

Profits associated with risk-taking accrue

to owners, while losses in excess of bank capital that would otherwise
fall on depositors are absorbed by the FDIC
Weak depositor discipline and this moral hazard of deposit
insurance have two important implications

First, the implicit deposit

insurance subsidy has encouraged banks to enhance their profitability by
increasing their reliance on deposits rather than capital to fund their

- 3 assets.

In effect, the deposit insurance funds have been increasingly

substituted for private capital as the cushion between the asset
portfolios of insured institutions and their liabilities to depositors

A

hundred years ago, the average equity-capital-to-asset ratio of U S banks
was almost 25 percent, approximately four times the current level

Much

of the decline over the past century no doubt reflects the growing
efficiency of our financial system.

But it is difficult to believe that

many of the banks operating over recent decades would have been able to
expand their assets so much, with so little additional investment by their
owners, were it not for the depositors' perception that, despite the
relatively small capital buffer, their risks were minimal

Regulatory

efforts over the last 10 to 15 years have stabilized and partially
reversed the sharp decline in bank equity capital-asset ratios. This has
occurred despite the sizable write-off of loans and the substantial buildup in loan-loss reserves in the last three years or so

But the capital

ratios of many banks are still too low.
Second, government assurances of the liquidity and availability
of deposits have enabled some banks with declining capital ratios to fund
riskier asset portfolios at a lower cost and on a much larger scale, with
governmental regulations and supervision, rather than market processes,
the major constraint on risk-taking.

As a result, more resources have

been allocated to finance risky projects than would have been dictated by
economic efficiency.
In brief, the subsidy implicit in our current deposit insurance
system has stimulated the growth of banks and thrifts.

In the process the

safety net has distorted market signals to depositors and bankers about

- 4 -

the economics of the underlying transactions

This has led depositors to

be less cautious in choosing among institutions and has induced some
owners and their managers to take excessive risk

In turn, the expanded

lending to risky ventures has required increased effort and resources by
supervisors and regulators to monitor and modify behavior
But in reviewing the list of deficiencies of the deposit
insurance system, particularly if an increased role for depositor
discipline is contemplated, we should not lose sight of the contribution
that deposit insurance has made to macroeconomic stability

The existence

and use of the safety net has shielded the broader financial system and
the real economy from instabilities in banking markets.

More

specifically, it has protected the economy from the risk of deposit runs,
especially the risk of such runs spreading from bank to bank, disrupting
credit and payment flows and the level of trade and commerce

Confidence

in the stability of the banking and payments system has been the major
reason why the United States has not suffered a financial panic or
systemic bank run in the last half century
There are thus important reasons to take care as we modify our
deposit insurance system

Reform is required.

So is caution.

The ideal

is an institutional framework that, to the extent possible, induces banks
both to hold more capital and to be managed as if there were no safety
net, while at the same time shielding unsophisticated depositors and
minimizing disruptions to credit and payment flows.
The congressional increase in the deposit insurance level in 1980
from $40,000 to $100,000 was intended to permit depository institutions to

- 5 have access to deposits not subject to the rate ceilings then in force.
Disintennediation especially suggested the need to facilitate the access
of thrifts to funds that would substitute for the retail deposits that
were at the time bleeding off to higher yielding market instruments at
rates that thrift portfolios would not permit them to match

Large time

deposits—defined by the regulators as those over $100,000—were exempt
from rate ceilings on the thought that their size—over twice the then
insured level—implied sophisticated holders familiar with market
instruments and the evaluation of financial assets.

It was argued that an

increase in deposit insurance coverage to the level that would exempt such
deposits from rate ceilings would open up access by smaller and weaker
depository institutions to large denomination time deposits that
previously had been limited to a smaller set of depositories for whom the
market was willing to provide significant uninsured funding.

Such funding

at market rates, it was contemplated/ would not require raising yields for
the retail depositors willing to remain at lower rates

The extension of

deposit insurance was thus an increase in a subsidy in lieu of the removal
of regulations that were phased out some time later by the Depository
Institutions Deregulation Act. But, as in virtually all other cases, the
subsidy remained.
If we were starting from scratch, the Board believes it would be
difficult to make the case that deposit insurance coverage should be as
high as its current $100,000 level

However, whatever the merits of the

1980 increase in the deposit insurance level from $40,000 to $100,000, it
is clear that the higher level of depositor protection has been in place
long enough to be fully capitalized in the market value of depository

- 6 institutions, and embedded in the financial decisions of millions of
households

The associated scale and cost of funding have been

incorporated into a wide variety of bank and thrift decisions, including
portfolio choices, staffing, branch structure, and marketing strategy.
Consequently, a return to lower deposit insurance coverage—like any
tightening of the safety net—would reduce insured depository market
values and involve significant transition costs.

It is one thing

initially to offer and then maintain a smaller degree of insurance
coverage, and quite another to reimpose on the existing system a lower
level of insurance, with its associated readjustment and unwinding costs
This is why the granting of subsidies by the Congress should be considered
so carefully,

they not only distort the allocation of resources, but also

are extremely difficult to eliminate, imposing substantial transition
costs on the direct and indirect beneficiaries

For such reasons, the

Board has concluded that, Bhould the Congress decide to lower deposit
insurance limits, a meaningful transition period would be needed.
Another relevant factor that should be considered in evaluating
the $100,000 insurance limit is the distribution of deposit holders by
size of account. Unfortunately, data to analyze this issue by individual
account holder do not exist

However, we have been able to use data

collected on an individual household basis in our 1983 Survey of Consumer
Finances to estimate the distribution of account holders

While these

data are seven years old, they are the best available until results from
our 1989 Survey of Consumer Finances become available this fall

I have

attached as an appendix to this statement summary tables and descriptive
text of the 1983 survey results

Briefly, the survey suggests that in

- 7 1983 between 1.0 and 1.5 percent of U S. households held deposit balances
in excess of $100,000. The demographic characteristics of these account
holders suggest that they are mainly older, retired citizens with most of
their financial assets in insured accounts.

These characteristics of

heads of households owning deposits are remarkably stable as the size of
deposits declines to $50,000.
A 1988 survey of small and medium-size businesses—described in
the second appendix to this statement—suggests that 7.1 percent of such
businesses had at least one account in excess of $100,000. These firms
are generally of modest size those with uninsured deposits had median
sales of $3.2 million, had less than 50 employees, and over 10 percent of
these entities were proprietorships or partnerships

The 1986 small

business survey suggests a sharp drop-off in the size of firms as the
maximum deposit declines to, say, $50,000.
Some have suggested a reduction of deposit insurance to that
level and the available evidence suggests that persons and small
businesses with $50,000 of deposits would probably be as capable as
current depositors with over $100,000 of assessing the health of their
banks or thrifts. As I noted, the demographics of the two household
groups are similar, although the business units with balances between
$50,000 and $100,000 have significantly smaller scale than those with
balances over $100,000

In addition, it is arguable that, should the

insured deposit limit be reduced to $50,000, and policies adopted which
make losses by uninsured depositors much more likely than they are today,
-uninsured depositors with a strong preference for safety would be able to
purchase evaluations of banks and thrifts from professional analysts

- 8 Such depositors would also have access to alternative safe investments,
especially Treasury securities
Nevertheless, the characteristics of households and small
businesses with deposits between $50,000 and $100,000 do not suggest that
they, compared to many other market participants, have the most resources
and greatest abilities to bring market discipline to bear on depository
institutions. Thus it seems reasonable to question whether such
depositors should be assigned a key role in deposit insurance reform
Moreover, as discussed above/ the benefits of lowering deposit insurance
coverage at this time must be balanced against the readjustment and
unwinding costs imposed on individuals, institutions, and markets that
have adapted to the $100,000 deposit insurance level.
A decision by Congress to leave the $100,000 limit unchanged,
however, should not preclude other reforms that would reduce current
inequities in, and abuses of, the deposit insurance system, often
thwarting its purpose. Serious study should be devoted to the cost and
effectiveness of policing the $100,000 limit so that multiple accounts are
not used to obtain more protection for individual depositors than Congress
intends.

He at the Federal Reserve believe that it is administratively

feasible—but not costless—to establish controls on the number and dollar
value of insured accounts per individual at one depository institution, at
all institutions in the same holding company, and perhaps—at sharply
rising cost and complexity—even across unrelated depositories

But we

are concerned about the cost and administrative complexity of such
schemes, and would urge the careful weighing of benefits and costs before
adopting any specific plan

- 9 The same study could consider the desirability of limiting passthrough deposit insurance—under which up to 9100,000 insurance protection
is now explicitly extended to each of the multiple beneficiaries of some
large otherwise uninsured deposits

Brokered accounts of less than

$100,000 also have been used to abuse deposit insurance protection,
particularly by undercapitalized institutions

However, the study should

keep in mind the power Congress hae already provided the agencies to
constrain misuse of brokered accounts.
No matter what the Congress decides on deposit insurance limits,
we must be cautious of our treatment of uninsured depositors—whether
defined as those in excess of $50,000 or $100,000

Such depositors should

be expected to assess the quality of their bank deposits just as they are
expected to evaluate any other financial asset they purchase

Earlier I

noted that our goal should be for banks to operate as much as possible as
if there were no safety net.

In fact, runs of uninsured deposits from

banks under stress have become commonplace.
So far, the pressure transmitted from such episodes to other
banks whose strength may be in doubt has been minimal

Nevertheless, the

clear response pattern of uninsured depositors to protect themselves by
withdrawing their deposits from a bank under pressure raises the very real
risk that in a stressful environment the flight to quality could
precipitate wider financial market and payments distortions.

These

systemic effects could easily feed back to the real economy, no matter how
open the discount window and how expansive open market operations

Thus,

while deposits in excess of insurance limits should not be protected by
the safety net at any bank, reforms designed to rely mainly on increased

- 10 market discipline by uninsured depositors raise serious stability
concerns
An example of one such approach is depositor co-insurance or a
deductible under which a depositor at a failed institution receives most,
but not all, of his or her deposit in excess of a reduced (or the current)
insurance limit. This option has some attractions, coupling depositor
market discipline with relatively modest possible losses to depositors.
The Board believes, however, that an explicit policy that requires
imposition of uninsured depositor loss—no matter how small—is likely to
increase the risk of depositor runs and to exacerbate the depositor
response to rumors.
Another option to rely more on private-market incentives without
necessarily reducing the size of insurance coverage is the use of private
deposit insurance as a replacement for FDIC insurance

This would

require, of course, that all relevant supervisory information—much of
which is now held confidential—be shared with private insurers who would
be obligated to use that information only to evaluate the risk of
depositor insurance and not for the purposes of adjusting any of their own
portfolio options

In addition, it is clearly unreasonable to impose on

private insurers any macro-stability responsibilities in their commercial
underwriting of deposit insurance.

Private insurers' withdrawal of

coverage in a weakening economy, or their unwillingness to forebear in
such circumstances would be understandable but counterproductive

Private

insurers' inability to meet their obligations after an underwriting error
would be disruptive at best and involve taxpayer responsibility at worst
Private insurance and public responsibility unfortunately are not always

- 11 compatible. Many of these concerns are mitigated if private insurance is
used as a supplement to FDIC insurance, say to cover a co-insurance
portion above some minimum.

However, we would remain concerned about

mutual assurance among groups of banks who would seek to evaluate each
other's risk exposure and discipline overly risky entities by expulsion
from their mutual guarantee syndicate.

In addition, a system of mutual

guarantees by banks could raise serious anti-competitive issues
There has also been support for the increased use of subordinated
debentures in the capital structure of banking organizations

Intriguing

attractions of this option are the thoughts that non-runable, but serially
maturing, debt would provide both enhanced market discipline and a
periodic market evaluation of the bank

The Board continues to support

the use of subordinated debt for these reasons, as well as the fact that
it provides supplementary capital to act as an additional buffer to the
FDIC over and above that provided by the owners' equity capital

But, in

our view, subordinated debentures can only be supporting players and not
be awarded the central role in reform.

This is a limited source of

capital and one that may prove difficult and expensive to obtain when
advertised as having limited returns like debt, but whose holders are
expected to absorb losses for the FDIC like equity

Adding features to

make it more attractive adds complications which perhaps are best met
directly by additional pure equity and other reforms
A promising approach that seeks to simulate market discipline
with minimal stability implications is the application of risk-based
deposit insurance premiums by the FDIC.

The idea is to make the price of

- 12 insurance a function of the bank's risk, reducing the subsidy to risktaking and spreading the cost of insurance more fairly across depository
institutions.

In principle, this approach has many attractive

characteristics, and could be designed to augment risk-based capital.

For

example, banks with high risk-based capital ratios might be charged lower
insurance premiums.

But the range of premiums necessary to induce genuine

behavioral changes in portfolio management might well be many multiples of
the existing premium, thereby raising practical concerns about its
application.

Risk-based premiums also would have to be designed with some

degree of complexity if they are to be fair and if unintended incentives
are to be avoided

In any event, the potential additional benefits on top

of an internationally negotiated risk-based capital system, while
positive, require further evaluation.
Another approach that has induced increasing interest is the
insured narrow bank.

Such an institution would invest only in high

quality, short-maturity, liquid investments, recovering its costs for
checking accounts and wire transfers from user fees.

The narrow bank

would thus require drastic institutional changes, especially for thousands
of our smaller banks and for virtually all households using checking
accounts

Movement from the present structure for delivery of many bank

services would be difficult and costly, placing U.S. banks at a
disadvantage internationally

In addition, this approach might shift and

possibly focus systemic risk on larger banks

Banking organizations would

have to locate their business and household credit operations in nonbank
affiliates funded by uninsured deposits and borrowings raised in money and
capital markets

Only larger organizations could fund in this way and

- 13 these units, unless financed longer term than banks today, would, even
with the likely higher capital ratio imposed on them by the market, be
subject to the same risks of creditor runs that face uninsured banks, with
all of the associated systemic implications

If this were the case, we

might end up with the same set of challenges we face today, refocused on a
different set of institutions

He at the Board believe that while the

notion of a narrow bank to insulate the insurance fund is intriguing, in
our judgment further study of these systemic and operational implications
is required.
If, in fact, proposals that rely on uninsured depositor
discipline, private insurance, subordinated debentures, risk-based
premiums, and structural changes in the delivery of bank services raise
significant difficulties, reform should then look to other ways to curb
banks' risk appetites, and to limit the likelihood that the deposit
insurance fund, and possibly the taxpayer, will be called on to protect
depositors. The Board believes that the most promising approach is to
reform both bank capital and supervisory policies. This would build upon
the groundwork laid in FIRREA, in which Congress recognized as key
components of a sound banking system the essentiality of strong capital
plus effective supervisory controls.
value of the insurance subsidy.

Both would be designed to reduce the

Neither would rule out either concurrent

or subsequent additions to deposit insurance reform, such as the changes
discussed previously, other proposals, or new approaches that may emerge
in the years ahead

In fact, higher capital, by reducing the need for,

and thereby the value of, deposit insurance would make subsequent reform
easier

There would be less at stake for the participants in the system

- 14 At the end of this year, the phase-in to the International
Capital Standards under the Basle Accord will begin

This risk-based

capital approach provides a framework for incorporating portfolio and offbalance sheet risk into capital calculations.

Most U.S. banks have

already made the adjustment required for the fully phased-in standard that
will be effective at the end of 1992

However, the prospective

increasingly competitive environment suggests that the minimum level of
capital called for by the 1992 requirements may not be adequate,
especially for institutions that want to take on additional activities
As a result of the safety net, too many banking organizations, in our
judgment, have travelled too far down the road of operating with modest
capital levels.

It may well be necessary to retrace our steps and begin

purposefully to move to capital requirements that would, over time, be
more consistent with what the market would require if the safety net were
more modest

The argument for more capital is strengthened by the

necessity to provide banking organizations with a wider range of service
options in an increasingly competitive world

Indeed, projections of the

competitive pressures only intensify the view that if our financial
institutions are to be among the strongest in the world, let alone avoid
an extension of the taxpayers' obligation to even more institutions, we
must increase capital requirements

Our international agreements under

the Basle Accord permit us to do so
There are three objectives of a higher capital requirement
First, higher capital would strengthen the incentives of bank owners and
managers to evaluate more prudently the risks and benefits of portfolio
choices because more of their money would be at risk

In effect, the

- 15 moral hazard risk of deposit insurance would be reduced.

Second, higher

capital levels would create a larger buffer between the mistakes of bank
owners and managers and the need to draw on the deposit insurance fund
For too many institutions, that buffer has been too low in recent years
The key to creating incentives to behave as the market would dictate, and
at the same time creating these buffers or shock absorbers, is to require
that those who would profit from an institution'a success have the
appropriate amount of their own capital at risk.

Third, requiring higher

capital imposes on bank managers an additional market test

They must

convince investors that the expected returns justify the commitment of
risk capital

Those banks unable to do so would not be able to expand

He are in the process in the Federal Reserve System of developing
more specific capital proposals, including appropriate transition
arrangements designed to minimize disruptions
would like to anticipate several criticisms.

However, at the outset I
For many banks, raising

significant new capital will be neither easy nor cheap

Maintaining

return on equity will be more difficult, and those foreign banks that only
adhere to the Basle minimuma may have lower capital costs relative to some
-US

banks.

Higher capital requirements also will tend to accelerate the

move toward bank consolidation and slow bank asset growth

However, these

concerns must be balanced against the increasing need for reform now, the
difficulties with all the other options, and both the desire of, and
necessity for, banking organizations to broaden their scope of activities
in order to operate successfully
More generally, many of the arguments about the competitive
disadvantages of higher capital requirements are short-sighted

Highly

- 16 leveraged banks are less able to respond to rapidly changing situations.
In fact, well-capitalized banks are the ones best positioned to be
successful in the establishment of domestic and foreign long-term
relationships, to be the most attractive counterparties for a large number
of financial transactions and guarantees, and to expand their business
activities to meet new opportunities and changing circumstances

Indeed,

many successful U.S. and foreign institutions would today meet
substantially increased risk-based capital standards

In addition, the

evidence of recent years suggests that U.S. banks can raise sizable
equity.

The dollar volume of new stock issues by banking organizations

has grown at a greater rate since the late 1970s than the total dollar
volume of new issues by all domestic corporate firms.

The recent declines

in bank stock prices, reflecting market concerns about the quality of bank
assets, will make the capital building process more difficult and costly.
However, over tune, banks with sound management policies will be able to
continue to build their capital base.
Higher capital standards should go a long way toward inducing
market-like behavior by banks.

However, the Board believes that, so long

as a significant safety net exists, additional inducements will be needed
through an intensification of supervisory efforts to deter banks from
maintaining return on equity by acquiring riskier assets.

Where it is not

already the practice, full in-bank supervisory reviews—focusing on asset
portfolios and off-balance sheet commitments—should occur at least
annually, and the results of such examinations should promptly be shared
with the board of directors of the bank and used to evaluate the adequacy
of the bank's capital

The examiner should be convinced after a rigorous

- 17 and deliberate review that the loan-loss reserves are consistent with the
quality of the portfolio

If they are not, the examiner should insist

that additional reserves be created with an associated reduction in the
earnings or equity capital of the bank
This method of adjusting and measuring capital by reliance on
examiner loan evaluations does not depend on market value accounting to
adjust the quality of the aeaets. Some day, perhaps, we may be able to
apply generally accepted market value accounting precepts to both the
assets and liabilities of a financial going concern with a wide spectrum
of financial assets and liabilities

But the Board is not comfortable

with the process as it has developed so far, either regarding market value
accounting's ability accurately to reflect market values over reasonable
periods or to avoid being overly sensitive to short-run events

For most

banks, loans are the predominant asset, assets that do not have ready
secondary markets but that the examiners can evaluate in each of the
proposed annual in-bank supervisory reviews

He at the Federal Reserve

believe that the examiners' classification of loan quality should, as I
noted, be fully reflected in the banks' loan loss reserves by a diversion
of earnings or a reduction in capital

If the resultant capital is not

consistent with minimum capital standards, the board of directors and the
bank's regulators should begin the process of requiring the bank either to
reduce those assets or to rebuild equity capital.
If credible capital raising commitments are not forthcoming, and
if those commitments are not promptly met, the authorities should pursue
such responses as lowered dividends, slower asset growth or perhaps even
asset contraction, restrictions on the use of insured brokered deposits,

- 18 if any, and divestiture of affiliates with the resources used to
recapitalize the bank

What is important is that the supervisory

responses occur promptly and firmly and that they be anticipated by the
bank

This progressive discipline or prompt corrective action of a bank

with inadequate capital builds on our current bank supervisory procedures
and is designed to simulate market pressures from risk-taking—to link
more closely excessive risk-taking with its costs—without creating market
disruptions.

It is also intended to help preserve the franchise value of

a going concern by acting early and quickly to restore a depository to
financial health

In this way, the precipitous drop in value that normally

occurs when a firm is placed in conservatorship or receivership would, for
the large majority of cases, be avoided.
While some flexibility is certainly required in this approach,
the Board believes there must be a prescribed set of responses and a
presumption that these responses will be applied unless the regulator
determines that the circumstances do not warrant them

Even though prompt

corrective action implies some limit on the discretion of supervisors to
delay for reasons that they perceive to be in the public interest, the
Board is of the opinion that it-would be a mistake to eliminate completely
the discretion of the regulator
Accordingly, the Board believes that a system that combined a
statutorily prescribed course of action with an allowance for regulatory
flexibility would result in meaningful prompt resolution

For example, if

a depository institution failed to meet minimum capital requirements
established by its primary regulatory agency, the agency might be required
by statute to take certain remedial action, unless it determined on the

- 19 basis of particular circumstances that such action was not required.

The

presumption would thus be shifted toward supervisory action, and delay
would require an affirmative act by the regulatory agency.
The prescribed remedial action required in a given case would be
dependent upon the adequacy of the institution's capital

As the capital

fell below established levels, the supervisor could be required, for
example, to order the institution to formulate a capital plan, limit its
growth, limit or eliminate dividends, or divest certain nonbank
affiliates.

In the event of seriously depleted capital, the supervisor

could require a merger, sale, conaervatorship or liquidation
In adopting such a statutory framework, Congress should consider
designing the system so that forced mergers, divestitures and, when
necessary, conservatorships could be required while there is still
positive equity capital in the depository institution

While existing

stockholders should be given a reasonable period of time to correct
deteriorating capital positions, Congress should specifically provide the
bank regulators with the clear authority, and therefore explicit support,
to act well before technical insolvency in order to minimize the ultimate
resolution costs

The presence of positive equity capital, even if at low

levels, when combined with any tier 2 capital, would limit reorganization
and liquidation costs.
In the Board's view, most of the remedial actions discussed above
can be taken, and have been taken, by bank regulators under the current
legal framework

Under current law, however, action is discretionary and

dependent upon a showing of unsafe or unsound conditions or a violation of
law, and implementation of a supervisory remedial action can be extended

- 20 over a protracted period of time where the depository institution contests
the regulator's determination

What is needed is legislation that would

permit a systematic program of progressive action based on the capital of
the institution, instead of requiring the regulator to determine on a
case-by-case basis, as a precondition to remedial action, that an unsafe
or unsound practice exists

This program would introduce a greater level

of consistency of treatment into the supervisory process, place investors
and managers on notice regarding the expected supervisory response to
falling capital levels, and reduce the likelihood of protracted
administrative actions challenging the regulator's actions
The Board is in the process of developing the parameters,
processes and procedures for prompt corrective action

One of the

principles guiding our efforts is the need to balance rules with
discretion.

In addition, as is the case for higher capital standards,

the Board is mindful of the need for an appropriate transition period
before fully implementing such a change in supervisory policy.
Higher capital and prompt corrective action would increase the
cost and reduce the availability of credit from insured institutions to
riskier borrowers

In effect, our proposal- would reduce the incentive

some banks currently have to overinvest in risky credits at loan rates
that do not fully reflect the risks involved

This implies that the

organizers of speculative and riskier ventures will have to restructure
their borrowing plans, including possibly paying more for their credit, or
seek financing from noninsured entities

Some borrowers may find their

proposals no longer viable. However, it is just such financing by some
insured institutions that has caused so many of the current difficulties,

- 21 and it is one of the objectives of our proposals to cause depositories to
reconsider the economics of such credits. As insured institutions
reevaluate the risk-return tradeoff, they are likely to be more interested
in credit extensions to less risky borrowers, increasing the economic
efficiency of our resource allocation
Despite their tendency to raise the average level of bank asset
quality, higher capital requirements and prompt corrective action will not
eliminate bank failures

An insurance fund will still be needed, but we

believe that, with a fund of reasonable size, the risk to taxpayers should
be reduced substantially.

As I have noted, higher capital requirements

and prompt corrective action imply greater caution in bank asset choices
and a higher cushion to the FDIC to absorb bank losses

In addition, an

enhanced supervisory approach will not permit deteriorating positions to
accumulate.
But until these procedures have been adopted and the banking
system has adjusted to them, circumstances could put the existing
insurance fund under severe pressure. As Chairman Seidman has indicated,
the fund is already operating under stress, as its reserves have declined
in reaent years and now stand, as a percentage of insured deposits, at
their lowest level in history

At the same tine, there remain all too

many problems in the banking system, problems that have been growing of
late as many banks, including many larger banks, have been experiencing a
deterioration in the quality of their loan portfolios, particularly real
estate loans.

It thus seems clear that the insurance fund likely will

remain under stress for some time to come

Moreover, pressures would

- 22 intensify if real estate market conditions were to weaken further or a
recession were to develop in the general economy.
It should, however, be clearly underlined that the size or
adequacy of the insurance fund does not change the quality of the deposit
insurance guarantee made by the federal government; it does allocate the
cost of meeting any guarantee between the banking industry, that pays the
insurance premiums, and the taxpayers as a whole

It should, in our view,

be the policy of the government to minimize the risk to taxpayers of the
deposit insurance guarantee, and we believe that our proposal does that.
While some increase in insurance premiums is in all likelihood necessary,
we must be concerned that attempts to accomplish this end by substantially
higher insurance premiums may well end up—especially if accompanied by
higher capital requirements—simply making deposits so unattractive that
banks are unable to compete

Indeed, the Board is concerned that the

levels of premiums contemplated in some quarters will exacerbate both the
short- and the long-run problem by reducing the profitability of banks,
and hence their ability to attract capital. Avoiding taxpayer costs and
maintaining a competitive banking system are just two more reasons why
basic deposit insurance reform is so urgent.
Among the deposit insurance reforms that might be considered on
the basis of both strengthening the insurance fund and fairness to smaller
and regional banks is the assessment of insurance premiums on the foreign
branch deposits of U S banks.
of the largest U.S

A substantial proportion of the deposits

banks are booked at branches outside the United

States, including offshore centers in the Caribbean.
deposits could yield significant revenue for the FDIC

Assessing auch
However, foreign

- 23 deposits may be quite sensitive to a small decline in their yields

Thus

imposing premiums on them could lead to deposit withdrawals and funding
problems at some U.S

banking organizations, and possibly inhibit the

ability of these organizations to raise capital
Even if no adjustment is made in the insurance assessment on
foreign deposits, held almost solely by large banks, other deposit
insurance reforms should be equally applicable to banks of all sizes. No
observer is comfortable with the inequities and adverse incentives of an
explicit or implicit program that penalizes depositors, creditors, and
owners of smaller banks more than those of larger ones.

The Board

believes no bank should assume that its scale insulates it from market
discipline, nor should any depositor with deposits in excess of the
insurance limit at the largest of U.S. banks assume that he or she faces
no loss should their bank fail.
Nevertheless, it is clear that there may be some banks, at some
particular times, whose collapse and liquidation would be excessively
disruptive to the financial system.

But it is only under the very special

conditions, which should be relatively rare, of significant and
unavoidable risk to the financial system that our policies for resolving
failed or failing institutions should be relaxed

The benefits from the

avoidance of a contagious loss of confidence in the financial system
accrue to us all. But included in the cost of such action is the loss of
market discipline that would result if large banks and their customers
presume a kind of exemption from loss of their funds

The Board's

policies of prompt corrective action and higher capital are designed to
minimize these costs. Under these policies, the presumption should always

- 24 be that prompt and predictable supervisory action will be taken.

For no

bank is ever too large or too small to escape the application of the same
prompt corrective action standards applied to other banks

Any bank can

be required to rebuild its capital to adequate levels and, if it does not,
be required to contract its assets, divest affiliates, cut its dividends,
change ita management, sell or close offices, and the resultant smaller
entity can be merged or sold to another institution with the resources to
recapitalize it.

If this is not possible, the entity can be placed in

conservatorship until it is
It is, by the way, the largest U S. banks that would be required
under our proposals to raise the most additional capital, both absolutely
and proportionally.

Most banks with assets less than $1 billion already

meet capital requirements considerably above the fully phased-in Basle
Capital Accord minimums.

In addition, it bears emphasizing that no

deposit insurance reform that truly reduces the subsidy existing in the
current system will be costless for banks. The issue really is one of
achieving maximum benefit from reform at minimum cost. He believe that
our proposals achieve this goal
In summary, events have made it clear that we ought not to permit
banks, because of their access to the safety net, to take excessive risk
with inadequate capital

Even if we were to ignore the potential taxpayer

costs, we ought not to permit a system that is so inconsistent with
efficient market behavior

In the process of reform, however, we should

be certain we consider carefully the implications for macroeconomic
stability

The Board believes that higher capital and prompt corrective

action by supervisors to resolve problems will go a long way to eliminate

- 25 excessive risk-taking by insured institutions, and would not preclude
additional deposit insurance reform/ now or later

Finally, in

considering all proposals, we should remind ourselves that our objective
is a strong and stable financial system that can deliver the beat services
at the lowest cost and compete around the world without taxpayer support.
This requires the modernization of our financial system and the weaning of
some institutions from the unintended benefits that accompany the safety
net.

Higher capital requirements may well mean a relatively leaner and

more efficient banking system, and they will certainly mean one with
reduced inclinations toward risk.
As I noted in my opening remarks, the Board believes that these
reforms should be coupled with the modernization of our financial system.
As we address reductions in the subsidy to banks from deposit insurance,
we should also authorize wider activities for well-capitalized banking
organizations and eliminate the outdated statutes that prohibit banks from
delivering interstate services in the most cost-effective way, through
branching.

These combined reforms will go a long way toward ensuring a

safer and more efficient financial system and lay the groundwork for other
modifications in the safety net in the years ahead.

-26-

Appendix 1
Selected Characteristics of Household Account Holders

This appendix provides supporting material on the distribution
of household ownership of insured deposits

The most recent reliable

disaggregated information available on the size and ownership of
accounts comes from the 1983 Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF)
survey consists of interviews with 4,103 U.S
sampling frames

This

households drawn from two

a randomized geographic sample to provide good coverage

of broadly distributed characteristics, and a special sample of wealthy
households constructed from data at the Statistics of Income Division of
the IRS to provide better representation of more narrowly distributed
characteristics, such as ownership of corporate stock.

Survey experts

agree that the SCF provides very reliable estimates of the distribution
of financial characteristics

The standard error due to sampling

error for a figure of ten percent estimated from the entire survey
population is about one-half percent.
The 1983 SCF was sponsored by the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, the Department of Health and Human Services, the
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, the Office of the Comptroller of
the Currency, the Federal Trade Commission, the Department of Labor, and
the Department of the Treasury

Data were collected through in-person

interviews between February and August of 1983 under a contract with the
Survey Research Center at the University of Michigan.

1. The survey is discussed in detail in an evaluation study "Measuring
Health with Survey Data An Evaluation of the 1983 Survey of Consumer
Finances," by Robert B Avery, Gregory E Elliehaueen, and Arthur B
Kenniclcell, Review of Income and Wealth, December 1988

-27For the financial data collected in the survey, the unit of
observation lies between the standard Census Bureau definition of a
"family" plus "single individuals" and a "household " Generally, the
survey excludes information only for individuals who are not related by
blood or marriage to the economically dominant core of the household
Among other items, the survey gathered information on the
amount of money held in each of a household's accounts as well as the
types of institutions where those accounts were held
important limitations in the survey data

There are three

First, there is no informa-

tion on the ownership of deposits within the household.

Second, there

is no information on how many accounts households may have at a given
institution.

Third, information on IRAs and Keoghs and CDs is more

limited than for other deposits

For IRAs and Keoghs, the survey

gathers only total holdings and the types of institutions where these
accounts are held.

For CDs, totals were gathered by term of the

certificate and no institution information was collected.2
There are a number of different account constructs that can be
created for evaluating the distribution of the coverage of household
accounts by deposit insurance.

Two cases are considered here

In the

first case, it is assumed that all accounts held by a given household at
a given type of institution are actually accounts owned by the same
person and that the accounts are held at the same institution.

This

2. In the 1989 SCF, from which preliminary information is expected
around the end of October, more detailed institutional data were
collected
In that survey, it will be possible to identify accounts
that are held by households at the same institution
In addition, the
institutions where certificates of deposit are held will be known
However, it will still not be possible to disaggregate accounts by
different owners within the household

-28construct is referred to below as the "synthetic account" definition
In the second case, it is assumed that all accounts are either owned by
different household members or are held at different financial institutions.

This measure is referred to below as the "individual account"

definition

The former construct will almost surely overstate the

amount of uninsured deposits; while the second may understate that
number

Because of data limitations noted below, the second construct

is not quite a polar case
Synthetic Account Definition
In the synthetic account measure, accounts and institution are
synonymous

The creation of this account proceeds in several steps

First, all checking, savings, and money market deposit accounts are
summed by the type of institution where the account was held

Second,

IRA and Keogh accounts are allocated equally to each type of institution
where the accounts were held

Finally, because no information is

available on the institutions where CDs were held, it is assumed that
they were held at the institution type that otherwise had the largest

3 For example, suppose a household had four such accounts, one of
$50,000 at a commercial bank, one of $30,000 at a savings and loan, and
two accounts of $20,000 (one belonging to the head of the household and
the other to his mother) at a credit union
In this case, the household
would then have synthetic accounts of $50,000 at a commercial bank,
$30,000 at a savings and loan, and $40,000 at a credit union
4. Continuing the example of the previous footnote, suppose the
household has a total of $50,000 in IRA and Keogh accounts and that
those accounts are held at commercial banks and savings and loans
Then
$25,000 is attributed to both the commercial bank and the savings and
loan synthetic accounts for a total of $75,000 in commercial banks,
$55,000 in savings and loans, and $40,000 in credit unions

-29level of deposits
Table 1 presents information based on this account concept
Households are classified in the columns by the largest of their
synthetic accounts.

As shown in rows 1 and 2, only 2 6 percent (2 2

million) households are estimated to have an account of $75,000 or more
at an insured institution

However,

as shown by row 6, this same group

is estimated to hold 38 6 percent of all deposits owned by households
Even when compared to the universe of deposits (computed as gross
deposits from the June 1983 call reports for the appropriate types of
institutions), the same group is estimated to hold 14 5 percent of all
deposits (row 7)

7

This group is also estimated to hold 27 7 percent

of insured household deposits (row 9)

Note that the aggregation of

accounts will tend to understate the amount of insured deposits held by
these groups
Data in rows 11 to 26 of table 1 provide other characteristics
of the classes of account holders

The data indicate that households

with an account of $75,000 or more tend to have higher income, financial
assets, and net wealth than the whole population (shown in the last

5 Again, continuing the example, suppose the household has CDs
totaling $125,000 ($110,000 in short-term certificates and $15,000 in
long-term certificates). Because the largest synthetic account at this
stage of aggregation is the commercial bank account, the entire amount
of the CDs is added to this account for a total oC $200,000
6. In the example, the household would be included in the column
">100K" because its largest synthetic account (the commercial banks
account) is $200,000.
7 The call report is a regular report of balance sheet, income, and
other data made by depository institutions to the regulatory agencies
8 "Insured deposits" includes only the part of accounts that is
$100,000 or less. In the example, the household has total deposits at
insured institutions of $295,000 of which $195,000 ($55,000 in savings
and loans, $40,000 in credit unions/ and the first $100,000 of the
$200,000 in commercial banks) would be insured deposits.

-30-

column)

While they hold a substantial part of their financial assets

and net wealth in insured depository accounts, as a group they are also
much more likely than the general population to have diversified their
holdings into corporate stock, a business, or investment real estate
The top two groups also tend to be older and more likely to be retired
The groups with their largest accounts between $25,000 and
$75,000 are more like the top groups than like the group with accounts
under $25,000 and the group with no accounts

The principal differences

between the $25f000-$75,000 group and the top two groups are the facts
that their levels of financial assets and net worth are lower

Like the

top two groups, they are more likely to be older and retired and to have
a diversified portfolio
Individual Account Definition
In the individual account definition, each reported account is
treated separately so far as the data allow

Each checking, savings,

and money market deposit account is counted as a separate account for
purposes of deposit insurance coverage.

As before, IRAs and Keoghs

are divided equally by the number of types of institutions where such
accounts were held

Finally, long-term and short-term CDs are

allocated to the type of institution where the household otherwise had
ita largest account

1

Note that this definition does not constitute

9 For example, assuming the same household-level data as in the
example beginning in footnote 3, the household would have four accounts,
one of $50,000 at a commercial bank, one of $30,000 at a savings and
loan, and two of $20,000 each at a credit union.
10. Thus, in the example, the household would now have six accounts,
including the four described in the last footnote and two additional
accounts of $25,000 each
11 In the example, the household would now have eight accounts, the two
additional accounts being one of $110,000 and one of $15,000 and both
held at commercial banks

-31-

the opposite of the synthetic account definition since there is still
some aggregation of accounts in the treatment of the IRA and Keogh
accounts and the CDs
Table 2 presents estimates using thia second definition that
are comparable in structure to the estimates reported in table 1

As

would be expected, there is an overaLl shift of households away from the
top groups compared to table 1

By the individual account definition,

1 4 percent (1 1 million) of all households have accounts of $75,000 or
more (rows 1 and 2)

Correspondingly, the estimated amount of insured

deposits increases to $865 9 billion (row 8)

While there is some

shifting of the characteristics reported in the bottom two blocks of the
table, the overall picture is very similar to that in table 1
Estimated Household Share of Insured and Uninsured Deposits
Table 3 gives the estimated coverage of deposit insurance for
the current and lower hypothetical ceilings on insurance coverage for
each of the two account definitions.

According to the synthetic account

measure (which provides the greatest understatement of the amount of
insured deposits), at the current ceiling of $100,000, 84.8 percent of
total household accounts are estimated to have been covered in 1983

If

the ceiling were dropped to $50,000, it is estimated that 72.3 percent
would still have been covered

By the individual account measure, the

12 In the example, the household has $295,000 of deposits at insured
institutions as before, of which $285,000 would be insured (the sum of
the initial $50,000 account at a commercial bank, $30,000 at a savings
and loan, two accounts of $20,000 at a credit union, two accounts of
$25,000 each at a commercial bank and a savings and loan, one CD of
$15,000 at a commercial bank, and the first $100,000 of the $110,000 CD
at a commercial bank)

-32percent of household deposits insured at the current ceiling rises to
91 3 percent
Household accounts represent only a part of insured deposits
As noted in the last column in row 7 of either of the first two tables,
roughly 37 6 percent of total deposits was held by households in 1983
According to call report data tabulated in the 1988 Annual Report of the
FDIC, in 1983 deposits of $1,268 billion out of $1,691 billion (75 0
percent) at commercial banks were insured
deposits was 75 1 percent in 1988
definition of insured deposits

The proportion of insured

However, this is a limited

The underlying data contain no

information on either multiple accounts at one institution or passthrough accounts, and thus, on net may overstate the amount of insured
deposits

Using the closest possible survey definition, the individual

account definition of table 2, the data suggest that $63.6 billion (not
shown in the tables), or 15 0 percent of the F D I C s estimate of
uninsured deposits at commercial banks, may belong to households

14

However, this estimate is rather rough. The figure may tend to
overstate the true amount of uninsured household deposits by the limited
FDIC definition because of the aggregation of IRAs and Keoghs and CDs,
but may also tend to understate the true figure because of
underreporting in the survey

13 The total of insured deposits is the sum of all accounts of $100,000
and under and $100,000 for each account of more than $100,000
14. Call report data are not available for the calculation of the
household share of potentially uninsured deposits for hypothetical lower
insurance ceilings

Table 1
Selected Characteristics of Household Account Holders
By Size of Largest Synthetic Account at an Insured Institution
1983 Survey of Consumer Finances
Item
1
2

Size of largest synthetic: account at an insured institution
$25K-50K $50K-75K $75K-100K>$100K,
No account $1-25K
44
65 1
1.9
Num of h'holds in grp ($ mil) 10 3
09
13
5.2
11
23
% of all h'holds in group
12 3
77 6
1.5

3
4

# of acc'ts held by group (mil)
Amount of deposits held by
group ($ bil)
5 Mean account size ($ thou.)
6 % of all household deposits
held by group
7 % of all deposits held by group
8 Amount of insured deposits held
by group ($ bil)
%
of
all insured h'hold
9
deposits held by group
10 Amount of uninsured deposits
held by group ($ bil)

11 Median h'hold income ($ thou.)

All h'holds
83 9
1000

00

90 8

6.7

29

14

20

103.8

00
00

298 9

118 2
408

81.0
57 9

285 6
142 8

948.8

3.3

165 1
24.6

00
0.0

315
119

17 4
65

12 5

85

301

4.7

32

11.3

100.0
37.6

0.0

298 9

165.1

1182

810

141.6

804 8

0.0

37.1

20.5

14 7

10.1

17.6

100.0

00

00

0.0

0.0

00

144 0

144.0

7.1

210

30 0

28.8

32.4

49 0

19.5

26

42.6

76.1

100 5

234.0

2.4

100.0
34 6

96.2
134.7

88.0
183.7

91.9
193 3

914
457.1

99.1
34 3

63
210

34.0
57.9

191

47 1
56.3
34 3

40.3
59.6

14 3

26.3
45.0
29 2

361

21.6
14 2

18 7

34.2

371

28.2

42.8

18 8

42

60

65

65

65

44

12

12

13

12

15

12

160

33.1

405

47 6

88

63

10 6

43 5
14 3

52

19 6
111

27 6

36 1

267

210

346

25 4

463
13
100 0

21.6

18 2
40
100 0

20.0
12
100.0

8.0
46
1000

42 4
15
100 0

12 Median h'hold financial
assets ($ thou.)
00
13 Median % of h'hold financial
assets in insured accounts
00
14 Median h'hold net worth ($ thou.) 1.0
15 Median % of h'hold net worth
in insured institutions
00
16 % of h'holds owning stocks/bonds 1.4
17 % of h'holds owning business
22
18 % of h'holds owning real estate
other than prin. residence
5.6

42
19 Median age of head of h'hold
20 Median years of education
10
of head of h'hold
% of group with head of h'hold
in various occupations
Retired
21
27 3
22
Other not working
28 9
23
Professionals, managers,
administrators
56
24
Sales, clerical, craftsmen,
laborers, military
37 6
25
Fanners
0.6
26
All occupations
100.0

2.9
100.0

9.1

56

Table 2
Selected Characteristics of Household Account Holders
By Size of Largest Individual Account at an Insured Institution
1983 Survey of Consumer Finances
Size of largest individual account at an Insured institution
$25K-50K
$50K-75K $75K-100K>$100K
No Account $1-25K
67 4
38
13
03
1 Num of h' holds in grp. ($ mil) 10 3
08
80.3
% of all h'holds in group
12.3
45
15
0.4
1.0
Item

All h'holds
83 9

100.0

00

194 5

17 5

63

15

43

224.1

0.0
0.0

379.2
19

197.9
113

109.8
17 4

40.9
27.3

221.0
51.4

9488
42

0.0
00

400
150

20 8
78

116
44

4.3

1.6

23.3
8.8

100.0
37 6

00

379.2

197 9

109 8

40.9

138.1

865,9

00

43.8

22.9

127

4.7

15.9

100.0

0.0

00

00

0.0

0.0

82 9

82.9

11 Median h'hold income ($ thou) 7.1
12 Median h'hold financial
00
assets ($ thou.)
13 Median % of h'hold financial
assets in insured accounts
00
14 Median h'hold net worth ($ thou.) 1 0
15 Median % of h'hold net worth
0.0
in insured institutions
16 % of h'holds owning stocks/bonds 14
22
17 % of h'holds owning business
18 % of h'holds owning real estate
other than prin residence
5.6

211

26.8

313

38.0

50.4

19.5

2.8

62 2

1013

214.7

2518

2.4

100 0
36.5

92 6
167 0

89.8
198.4

65.2
285.3

93 8
457.1

99.1

6.6
21.6
14.9

28.7
54.2
244

442
507
291

366
66.7
34.7

45.9
60.1
30.4

5.6

216
142

19.1

37.1

37.1

31.9

40.0

188

42

43

64

65

65

65

44

10

12

12

12

14

16

12

27 3
289

162

42.9

42 3

86

101

10 8

35 6
11.3

54 4
36

19 6
11.1

56

281

27.6

29 8

22.4

32.2

25.4

37 6

45.7

16 0

12 5

27 4

0.6

14

3.4

46

33

75
23

100.0

1000

100.0

100.0

100 0

42 4
15
100 0

3 # of acc'ts held by group (mil)
4 Amount of deposits held by
5
6
7
8
9
10

group ($ bil)
Mean account size ($ thou)
% of all household deposits
held by group
% of all deposits held by group
Amount of insured deposits held
by group ($ bil.)
% of all insured h'hold
deposits held by group
Amount of uninsured deposits
held by group ($ bil)

19 Median age of head of h'hold
20 Median years of education
of head of h'hold

34.3

% of group with head of h'hold
21

22
23
24
25

26

in various occupations
Retired
Other not working
Professionals, managers,
administrators
Sales, clerical, craftsmen.
laborers, military
Farmers
All occupations

100 0

- 35 Table 3
Estimated Percent of Household Deposits Covered by Deposit Insurance
Various Hypothetical Deposit Insurance Ceilings
Synthetic Account Definition and Individual Accounts Definition
Account definition
definition

'

Hypothetical deposit insurance ceiling
$25K
$50K
$75K
$100K

$50K

$25K

Synthetic accounts

56 5

72.3

Synthetic accounts

56 5
713
713

72.3

Individual accounts

Individual accounts

83 5

83 5

$75K $100K
80.3
848
80.3
84 8
88 2
913
88 2
913

APPENDIX 2
SELECTED CHARACTERISTICS OF SMALL AND MEDIUM-SIZED
BUSINESS OWNERS OF INSURED DEPOSITS
This appendix presents information on the ownership of insured
checking and other deposit accounts by small and medium-sized business
firms

The information is from the National Survey of Small Business

Finances (NSSBF), a survey of a nationally representative sample of
3,404 small and medium-sized firms conducted during 1988-89

!

The

NSSBF represents the population of small and medium-sized businesses
more accurately and covers their financial relationships more thoroughly
than any other available survey
is only partially complete

Editing of the survey data, however,

Therefore, statistics presented in this

appendix should be viewed as preliminary and used with caution
The National Survey of Small Business Finances is a survey of the
use of financial services and financial institutions by small and
medium-sized businesses

The survey was sponsored by the Board of

Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the Small Business

1. For a detailed description of the survey, see Brenda G. Cox, Gregory E Elliehausen, and John D Wolken, "The National Survey of Small
Business Finances- Final Methodology Report," RTI Report 4131-00F
(Research Triangle Park, NC. Research Triangle Institute, September
1989).
2
Dollar amounts have received very little editing so far
Extreme
values have been replaced when they appeared to be doubtful, and missing
values have been provisionally estimated by substituting mean account
balances of the reported values for that employment size class
The
dollar estimates are subject to further revision after more rigorous
imputation
Account ownership, financial institution information, and
firm characteristics such as employment, organization form, and industry
are accurate. See Gregory E. Elliehausen and John D Wolken, Banking
Markets and the Use of Financial Services by Small and Medium-Sized
Businesses, Staff Studies 160 (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, 1990)

-2-

Administration

The sample was drawn from the population of all for-

profit, nonagricultural, nonfinancial enterprises listed on the Dun's
Market Identifier file

It consisted of those firms that had fewer than

500 full-time equivalent employees and were in operation at the end of
December 1967.3
Tha Data
The level of detail collected by the N9SBF permits deposit accounts
to be disaggregated to the level of a specific financial institution
Deposit account balances for accounts reported in this appendix are the
sum of all checking, savings and money market deposit accounts, and
certificates of deposit at each depository institution used by the firm
Thus, all of the deposits held by a sample firm in one depository
institution represents one insured account for the purpose of this
survey
The statistics presented here are based on the responses of 3,404
businesses, representing 3 510 million small and medium-axzed businesses

having an estimated 4 157 million deposit "accounts" at commercial banks
and thrift institutions

All statistics are weighted to provide

3
The Dun's file undercovers very new firms, firms with few employees, and sole proprietorships. Nevertheless, the Small Business Administration estimates that the Dun's file accounts for 93 percent of private employment in the United States
See US Small Business Administration, The State of Small Business
A Report of the President (Washington, DC
US Government Printing Office, 1988)
4
Because the unit of observation is the enterprise, account holdings
of subsidiaries and branches of a multiple establishment firm in the
same financial institution are consolidated
Thus, distinct accounts at
a particular financial institution held by different establishments of
the same firm would be counted aa one account. This possibility exists
for the eight percent of sampled firms with multiple establishments
Hence, the estimate of uninsured deposits is slightly biased upward

-3-

appropriate estimates for the population of small and medium-sized
nonagricultural, nonfinancial businesses.

They do not reflect firms

with 500 or more employees, agricultural and financial firms, not-forprofit firms, and firms owned by government entities.
Selected Characteristics of Deposit Accounts and Firms
Table 1 presents the distribution of deposit accounts among small
and medium-sized business firms and selected characteristics of these
firms classified by size of deposit account

As noted above, all

accounts at one institution are combined into one deposit account, the
resulting accounts are included in the table for each institution at
which the firm has an account.

Thus, for example, 2 771 million small

and medium-sized business firms (row 1, column 2) are estimated to have
3.255 million accounts with balances under $25,000 (row 3, column 2)
Distribution of Accounts

Among small and medium-sized businesses,

large balance accounts are relatively infrequent

About 246,000 (7 l

percent) of these businesses have deposit accounts of $100,000 or more
(rows 1 and 2, respectively)

Another 76,000 (2 2 percent) have

accounts between $75,000 and $99,999.

Some small and medium-sized

businesses have multiple accounts (that is, they have deposits at more
than one institution)

The 246,000 businesses with balances of $100,000

or more have 297,000 accounts in this account size group, the 76,000
firms in the $75,000 to $99,999 group have 83,000 accounts of this size
(row 3)
Nearly two-thirds of the total deposits of small and medium-sized
firms are in large balance accounts.

The 297,000 accounts with balances

of $100,000 or more are estimated to sum to $82 billion (row 5, column

-4-

6), about 63 percent of all deposits owned by small and medium-sized
businesses (row 6, column 6)

Most of these holdings are uninsured at

the current deposit insurance limit of $100,000

Only $29.7 billion of

the total deposits in this group are insured (row 8, column 6 ) , the
remaining $52.3 billion are uninsured (row 10, column 6)
Although a large proportion of small and medium-sized business
deposits are in the $100,000 or more group, these deposits account for
only 2 2 percent of total deposits at commercial banks and thrift
institutions (row 7, column 6).

Indeed, all deposit account balances

of small and medium-size businesses, regardless of size, account for 3 5
percent of total deposits, (row 7, column 7)
Characteristics of Account Owners.

Data in rows 11 through 19 of

table 1 present some demographic characteristics of small and mediumsize firms holding different sized deposit accounts.

Firm size

—

whether measured by sales, total assets, or number of full-time
equivalent employees —

distinguishes owners of low balance accounts

from owners of large balance accounts.

For example, mean sales for

firms owning deposit accounts under $25,000 is $657,000 (row 14, column
2).

In contrast, firms with deposit account balances of $100,000 or

more have mean sales of $8 4 million dollars (row 14, column 6)
Organization form also varies by account size

Owners of deposit

accounts with balances under $25,000 are divided almost evenly between

5
Total deposits of commercial banks and thrift institutions,
obtained from the Call Report, was $3,725 billion in December 1987
6. Statistics from the flow of funds accounts suggest that all nonfarm, nonfinancial businesses held no more than 10 4 percent of total
deposits at commercial banks and thrift institutions at the end of 1987

-5-

sole proprietorships and corporations (rows 17 and 19, respectively).
In the $100,000 or more group, however, only 5.4 percent of the firms
are sole proprietorships, while 86 8 percent are corporations
Share of Deposits Covered Under Alternative Deposit Insurance Ceilings
Table 2 presents the estimated share of small and medium-sized
business deposits that would be covered under various hypothetical
deposit insurance ceilings

For example/ the last column of table 2

estimates the insured deposit distribution with the current $100,000
deposit insurance level

The estimates in the column indicate that all

small and medium-sized businesses have insured deposit balances
equalling $77.9 billion and that $52.3 billion of small and medium-sized
business deposits are uninsured.

Thus only 59 8 percent of total

small and medium-sized business deposits are insured at the current
ceiling

At a $50,000 ceiling, the estimated percentage of small and

medium-sized business deposits covered would fall to 45 2 percent

As

shown in the last row of table 2, a reduction in the insurance level to
$50,000 would about double the number of firms with uninsured balances
from 246,000 to 474,000 small and medium-sized businesses.

7 The $77 9 billion is the same value shown in column 7, row 8 of
table 1.

Table 1
Selected Characteristics of Deposit Account Ownership by Small and Mediun-sized Businesses
By Size of Account at Insured Depository Institution
1988 National Survey of Small Business Finances
Size of Account at Insured Institution

Item

Bo account

$1-25K

$25K-50K

$50K-75K

$75K-l00K

>$l00K

All Sm Bus

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

1 Num of sm & med bus (thou)
2 % of all sm & med bus

149
4 2

2771
78.9

317
9.0

184
5.2

76
2.2

246
7 1

3510
100.0

Account
characteristics
3 * of acc'ts held (thou)
4 Mean account size ($thou)

0 0
0 0

3255
5.96

331
32 87

191
56 73

83
84.20

297
277 58

4157
31 30

5
6

Amount of deposits held($bil)
% of all sm & med bus deposits

0.0
0 0

19 4
14.9

10 9
84

10.9
8 4

7 0
5 4

82 0
63 0

130 2
100 0

7

% of all deposits

0.0

0 5

0 3

0.3

0.2

2 2

3 5

8
9

Amount of insured deposits($bil)
% of all insured sm & med bus
deposits

0 0

19 4

10 9

10.9

7.0

29 7

77.9

0.0

24.9

14.0

14 0

9.0

38 1

100.0

10 Amount of uninsured deposits($bil)

0.0

0.0

0 0

0.0

0 0

52 3

52 3

11 Median 1987 sales($ thou)
12 Median 1987 assets($thou)
13 Median employees

10
12
1

200
75
3.5

771
250
7.5

1127
450
14 5

1320
525
13.5

3200
1300
23 5

237
100
4

14 Average 1987 sales($thou)
15 Average 1987 assets($thou)
16 Average employees

77
273
3.2

657
479
8.3

2170
1100
19.9

3442
1280
27.9

3479
1860
27.8

8449
3007
46 3

1262
521
11.2

17 % Proprietorships
18 % Partnerships
19 % Corporations

64.8
14 2
20.9

43.9
8.5
47.6

18 9
5 9
75 3

14 0
4.8
81.2

14.7
5.5
79.9

5 4
79
86 6

39 9
8 3
51 8

Firm characteristics

1 Sum is greater than total because businesses may own multiple accounts.
2

Full-time equivalent employees defined as the sum of full time employees plus one half part time employees

Table 2
Estimated Percent of Small and Medium-sized Business Deposits
Covered by Deposit Insurance at
Various Hypothetical Deposit Insurance Ceilings
1988 National Survey of Small Business Finances

Insured Deposits
Deposits($bil)
($bil)

ceiling
Hypothetical deposit insurance ceiling
$25K
$25K
$50K
$75K
58 8
41 99
58
69 7

$100
77 9

Uninsured Deposits($bil)
Deposits($bil)

88 33

71 44

60 5

52 3

Percent of Small Business
Deposits Covered

32 2

45 2

53 5

59 8

Number of Small Businesses
Accounts
with Uninsured Accounts
(thou)

753

474

308
308

246