View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 a.m., EDT
June 14, 1999

Testimony by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Joint Economic Committee
United States Congress
June 14, 1999

Something special has happened to the American economy in recent years.
An economy that twenty years ago seemed to have seen its better days, is displaying a
remarkable run of economic growth that appears to have its roots in ongoing advances in
technology.
I have hypothesized on a number of occasions that the synergies that have developed,
especially among the microprocessor, the laser, fiber-optics, and satellite technologies, have
dramatically raised the potential rates of return on all types of equipment that embody or utilize
these newer technologies. But beyond that, innovations in information technology—so-called
IT—have begun to alter the manner in which we do business and create value, often in ways that
were not readily foreseeable even five years ago.
As this century comes to an end, the defining characteristic of the current wave of
technology is the role of information. Prior to this IT revolution most of twentieth century
business decisionmaking had been hampered by limited information. Owing to the paucity of
timely knowledge of customers' needs and of the location of inventories and materials flows
throughout complex production systems, businesses required substantial programmed
redundancies to function effectively.
Doubling up on materials and people was essential as backup to the inevitable
misjudgments of the real-time state of play in a company. Decisions were made from
information that was hours, days, or even weeks old. Accordingly, production planning required
costly inventory safety stocks and backup teams of people to maintain quality control and to
respond to the unanticipated and the misjudged.
Large remnants of information void, of course, still persist, and forecasts of future events
on which all business decisions ultimately depend are still unavoidably uncertain. But the recent

-2-

years' remarkable surge in the availability of real-time information has enabled business
management to remove large swaths of inventory safety stocks and worker redundancies, and has
armed firms with detailed data to fine-tune product specifications to most individual customer
needs.
Moreover, information access in real-time—resulting, for example, from such processes as
checkout counter bar code scanning and satellite location of trucks—has fostered marked
reductions in delivery lead-times on all sorts of goods, from books to capital equipment. This, in
turn, has reduced the relative size of the overall capital structure required to turn out our goods
and services.
Intermediate production and distribution processes, so essential when information and
quality control were poor, are being bypassed and eventually eliminated. The increasing
ubiquitousness of Internet web sites is promising to significantly alter the way large parts of our
distribution system are managed.
The process of innovation goes beyond the factory floor or distribution channels. Design
times have fallen dramatically as computer modeling has eliminated the need, for example, of the
large staff of architectural specification drafters previously required for building projects.
Medical diagnoses are more thorough, accurate, and far faster, with access to heretofore
unavailable information. Treatment is accordingly hastened, and hours of procedures eliminated.
In addition, the dramatic advances in biotechnology are significantly increasing a broad range of
productivity-expanding efforts in areas from agriculture to medicine.
Economists endeavor to describe the influence of technological change on activity by
matching economic output against measurable economic inputs: quality adjusted labor and all

-3forms of capital. They attribute the fact that economic growth has persistently outpaced the
contributions to growth from labor and capital inputs to such things as technological innovation
and increased efficiencies of organizations that are made possible through newer technologies.
For example, since 1995 output per labor workhour in the nonfarm business sector—our standard
measure of productivity—has grown at an annual rate of about 2 percent. Approximately
one-third of that expansion appears to be attributable to output growth in excess of the combined
growth of inputs.
Of course, it often takes time before a specific innovation manifests itself as an increase
in measured productivity. Although some new technologies can be implemented quickly and
have an immediate payoff, others may take years or even decades before achieving their full
influence on productivity as new capital is put in place that can take advantage of these creations
and their spillovers. Hence, the productivity growth seen in recent years likely represents the
benefits of the ongoing diffusion and implementation of a succession of technological advances;
likewise, the innovative breakthroughs of today will continue to bear fruit in the future.
The evident acceleration of the process of "creative destruction," which has accompanied
these expanding innovations and which has been reflected in the shifting of capital from failing
technologies into those technologies at the cutting edge, has been remarkable. Owing to
advancing information capabilities and the resulting emergence of more accurate price signals
and less costly price discovery, market participants have been able to detect and to respond to
finely calibrated nuances in consumer demand. The process of capital reallocation has been
assisted through a significant unbundling of risks made possible by the development of
innovative financial products, not previously available. Every new innovation has suggested

-4-

further possibilities to profitably meet increasingly sophisticated consumer demands. Many
ventures fail. But the few that prosper enhance consumer choice.
The newer technologies, as I indicated earlier, have facilitated a dramatic foreshortening
of the lead-times on the delivery of capital equipment over the past decade. When lead times for
capital equipment are long, firms must undertake capital spending that is adequate to deal with
the plausible range of business needs likely to occur after these goods are delivered and installed.
In essence, those capital investments must be sufficient to provide insurance against uncertain
future demands. As lead times have declined, a consequence of newer technologies, firms'
forecasts of future requirements have become somewhat less clouded, and the desired amount of
lead-time insurance in the form of a reserve stock of capital has been reduced.
In addition to shortening lead-times, technology has increased the flexibility of capital
goods and production processes to meet changes in the demand for product characteristics and
the composition of output. This flexibility allows firms to deal more effectively with evolving
market conditions with less physical capital than had been necessary in the past.
Taken together, reductions in the amount of spare capital and increases in capital
flexibility result in a saving of resources that, in the aggregate, is reflected in higher levels of
productivity.
The newer technologies and foreshortened lead-times have, thus, apparently made capital
investment distinctly more profitable, enabling firms to substitute capital for labor and other
inputs far more productively than they could have a decade or two ago. Capital, as economists
like to say, has deepened significantly since 1995.

-5-

The surge in investment not only has restrained costs, it has also increased industrial
capacity faster than the rise in factory output. The resulting slack in product markets has put
greater competitive pressure on businesses to hold down prices.
Technology is also damping upward price pressures through its effect on international
trade, where technological developments and a move to a less constrained world trading order
have progressively broken down barriers to cross-border trade. All else equal, the enhanced
competition in tradeable goods enables excess capacity previously bottled up in one country to
augment worldwide supply and exert restraint on prices in all countries' markets.
Because neither business firms nor their competitors can currently count any longer on a
general inflationary tendency to validate decisions to raise their own prices, each company feels
compelled to concentrate on efforts to hold down costs. The availability of new technology to
each company and its rivals affords both the opportunity and the competitive necessity of taking
steps to boost productivity. This contrasts with our experiences through the 1970s and 1980s,
when firms apparently found it easier and more profitable to seek relief from rising nominal labor
costs through price increases than through cost-reducing capital investments.
The rate of growth of productivity cannot increase indefinitely. While there appears to be
considerable expectation in the business community, and possibly Wall Street, that the
productivity acceleration has not yet peaked, experience advises caution.
As I have noted in previous testimony, history is strewn with projections of technology
that have fallen wide of the mark. With the innumerable potential permutations and
combinations of various synergies, forecasting technology has been a daunting exercise.

-6There is little reason to believe that we are going to be any better at this in the future than
in the past. Hence, despite the remarkable progress witnessed to date, we have to be quite
modest about our ability to project the future of technology and its implications for productivity
growth and for the broader economy.
A key question that we need to answer in order to appropriately evaluate the connection
between technological innovations and productivity growth is why have not the same available
technologies allowed productivity in Europe and Japan to catch up to U.S. levels. While
productivity in some foreign industrial countries appears to have accelerated in recent years, a
significant gap between U.S. productivity and that abroad persists.
One hypothesis is that a necessary condition for information technology to increase
output per hour is a willingness to discharge or retrain workers that the newer technologies have
rendered redundant. Countries with less flexible labor markets than the United States enjoys may
have been inhibited in this regard.
Another hypothesis is that regulations, systems of corporate governance, trade
restrictions, and government subsidies have prevented competition from being sufficiently keen
to induce firms in Europe and Japan to take full advantage of the efficiencies offered by the latest
advances in information technology and other innovations.
Further investigation will be necessary to evaluate the importance of these possible
influences. But at this stage, one lesson seems reasonably clear. As we contemplate the
appropriate public policies for an economy experiencing rapid technology advancement, we
should strive to maintain the flexibility of our labor and capital markets that has spurred the
continuous replacement of capital facilities embodying older technologies with facilities

-7-

reflecting the newest innovations. Further reducing regulatory impediments to competition, will,
of course, add to this process. The newer technologies have widened the potential for economic
well-being. Governments should seek to foster that potential.