View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
11 00 a m , E D T
July 28, 1995

Testimony by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs
United States Senate
July 28, 1995

I am pleased to be able to appear here today to offer my thoughts on the
status of the SAIF insurance fund, and on deposit insurance more generally
The combination of deposit insurance and a central bank providing discount
window credit has made the contagion of bank runs that often characterized the
19th and the first third of the 20th century an anachronism The United States
has not suffered a financial panic or systemic bank run in the last 50 years In
large part, this reflects the safety net, whose existence, as much as its use, has
helped to sustain confidence
But deposit insurance is not without its costs By relieving depositors of
the consequences of bank failure, government guarantees of bank deposits make
depositors relatively indifferent to bank failure and thus encourage banks to have
larger, nskier asset portfolios than would be possible in a wholly market-dnven
intermediation process Without the safety net, additional risks would have to be
reflected in some combination of higher deposit costs, greater liquid asset
holding, or a larger capital base, and these in turn would constrain risk-taking
In the late 1980s and early 1990s, Congress responded to problems at insured
depository institutions—and their insurance funds—with legislation designed to
induce these entities to be more prudent nsk-takers
Today, we are here to address an evolving competitive imbalance and other
implications of two insurance funds with sharply different premiums But, it is

-2-

critical to underline that even if there were no evolving problem with SAIF, the
existing deposit insurance system, with its reliance on two funds, is inherently
unstable
With deposit insurance, as it is currently administered and funded,
depositors do not move their funds from depository institution to depository
institution based on the soundness of particular insurance funds Depositors are
generally unaware, and indeed should be unconcerned, about BIF versus SAIF In
the mind of the typical depositor, the FDIC provides the insurance, and the
details of one fund versus another receive little attention
Competitive depository institutions cannot differentiate themselves by the
quality of the deposit insurance that is offered because it is the same insurance
regardless of whether it is from BIF or SAIF In either case, it is governmentmandated and government-sponsored deposit insurance For identical insurance, it
is rational that depository institutions seek the one available at the lowest
cost If a substantial difference in deposit premiums exists between SAIF and
BIF, the institutions paying the higher premium will pursue insurance offered by
the other insurance fund unless there is some other reason to remain with their
current fund
While today we are discussing what to do about SAIF, I want to stress that
the problem we are addressing is a general one If there is no substantial

-3-

difference between BIF and SAIF insurance, and if there is no substantial
difference between the advantages granted to BIF institutions or SAIF
institutions, then anytime one deposit insurance fund has difficulties that result
in substantially higher deposit premiums, members will try to shift to the other
deposit insurance fund In the process, the disadvantaged fund becomes
increasingly vulnerable to insolvency as its premium base declines This in turn
engenders a still greater incentive to leave the troubled fund or requires the
payment of still higher premiums to support it Short of effective barriers to
exit, once initiated the downward spiral does indeed lead to fund insolvency
Thus, having two deposit insurance funds creates a mechanism that is prone to
instability now, and probably, in the future Today, the problem is at the SAIF,
it may, at some date in the future, be at the BIF
Congress can attempt to legislate barriers that try to stop institutions
from shifting deposits, but the history of efforts to legislate against such
strong financial incentives is not encouraging We are, in effect, attempting to
use government to enforce two different prices for the same item--namely,
government-mandated deposit insurance Such price differences only create efforts
by market participants to arbitrage the difference In the present case, with
SAIF institutions expected to pay at least five times more per year for the same

-4-

deposit insurance, this arbitrage means that SAIF institutions will pursue all
avenues open to them profitably to move deposits from SAIF to BIF
The difference between paying, say, 24 basis points and paying 4 5 basis
points for deposit insurance translates into about $14 billion per year in
additional premiums paid for SAIF deposits For SAIF institutions, this equals
roughly 18 percent of their 1994 pretax income Given the large potential
financial gains to SAIF institutions if they move deposits to BIF, the current
deposit insurance system will impose a large deadweight loss on the financial
system Many of the political, policy, financial, and legal institutions
concerned with banking issues will be pre-occupied, for the foreseeable future,
with the details of this issue because SAIF institutions will continually strive
to move deposits into BIF and BIF institutions will attempt to thwart such
movements
Indeed, BIF institutions suffer under the current system to the extent that
SAIF members successfully shift their deposits to BIF One way for a SAIF
institution to minimize its cost under the current system is for that institution
either to acquire or to be acquired by a BIF institution The SAIF institution
can be funded from nondeposit sources, while its depositors are encouraged to
shift funds to the BIF institution Current BIF members would almost surely find
their premiums higher than otherwise because the new BIF deposits come without the

-5-

associated insurance fund reserves, requiring older BIF deposits to pay a higher
assessment in order to maintain the required 1 25 percent reserve ratio on both
the new and the old deposits
Using the FDIC's projections of future deposit premiums, a migration of only
$40 to $50 billion per year of SAIF deposits to BIF deposits might yield higher
deposit premiums for existing BIF members than if those members were to
participate in any of a number of proffered solutions to the potential SAIF
problem, each of which would remove incentives to migrate Such a shift of
deposits seems entirely credible if a large deposit premium difference exists
between SAIF and BIF, since $50 billion amounts to only 7 percent of the existing
SAIF assessment base Furthermore, even this relatively small migration suggests
that payments of FICO bond interest funded by SAIF could be put in jeopardy in the
very near future If action is not taken shortly, a future congressional
appropriation for interest on FICO bonds might be required, or further increases
in SAIF premiums on the smaller SAIF deposit base might be necessary, or possibly
even the imposition of higher premiums on both SAIF and BIF deposits might be
needed
Meanwhile, SAIF institutions will be harmed directly by the continuation of
a deposit premium higher than that to be assessed on BIF members, and the returns
on capital of SAIF members will be driven lower than similarly situated

-6competitors As I noted, BIF institutions will be harmed by the inflow of new
deposits shifted from SAIF institutions requiring the BIF members to pay higher
premiums The only winners created by the looming deposit premium difference
between SAIF and BIF deposits will be those depositories able to "game" the
system, and leave SAIF first The solution to this problem is to end this game
and merge SAIF and BIF
A prerequisite is to put SAIF on a sound basis This could be accomplished
if, as has been recommended, the institutions that hold SAIF deposits pay a
special one-time assessment to recapitalize SAIF at the legally mandated 1 25
percent ratio of insured deposits Such a one-time charge is large S AIF-member
institutions would pay $6 2 billion or 85 basis points of their deposit base
This assessment seems unlikely, however, to drive healthy SAIF members into
insolvency and weaker SAIF institutions can be allowed a longer pay-in period
The merging of a recapitalized SAIF with a sound BIF would then consolidate the
FICO bond obligation of SAIF into the new insurance fund and effectively obligate
past BIF members to participate on a pro rata basis
Most bankers would argue, with some justice, that they should not be
responsible for this legacy of the thrift crisis in which they played no role
Many may, nonetheless, conclude that two or two and a half basis points per year
in additional deposit premiums for the FICO interest payments may be a price they

-7-

would willingly pay to finally remove the incentives of SAIF members to shift to
BIF, with the associated increase in the premiums of BIF members.
Even after SAIF is recapitalized, in the years immediately ahead some large
savings and loans, still suffering from the residue of past difficulties, may
continue to represent a risk of relatively large loss to their federal deposit
insurer If SAIF were not merged with BIF, or if that merger were delayed, the
risk of such loss would expose a recapitalized SAIF both to a reserve shortfall
and to a higher deposit insurance premium to once again rebuild its reserves An
industry that had just paid a large one-time premium to recapitalize its insurance
fund would be understandably concerned about that possibility If such losses
were to occur to a merged BIF-SAIF fund, the necessity of reserve building would
be shared among banks and thrifts pro rata—implying a larger dollar burden on the
larger commercial bank industry Banks would be understandably concerned about
such exposure, especially after accepting a pro rata share of the FICO interest
obligation
Both sets of institutions are thus sensitive to the small probability of a
large thrift failure imposing still further costs on them One way to address
these concerns is for the Congress to arrange a catastrophe contingency funding
arrangement over, say, the next five years to bridge the period over which this
risk exists It has been suggested, for example, that over such an interval

-8public funds be made available in any year that losses to the SAIF, or losses
created by present SAIF members to a merged BIF-SAIF, exceed $500 million If
increased budget outlays are with good reason not acceptable to the Congress, one
possibility is that this catastrophe insurance be financed through a small special
insurance fee, paid to the Treasury by SAIF members to cover the potential
taxpayer nsk exposure
Let me conclude by clarifying why the Federal Reserve is concerned about
this problem and believes it is necessary to resolve it The Federal Reserve's
primary concerns are sustainable economic growth and financial stability A
healthy and competitive financial system is critical for maintaining and promoting
economic growth One key component of a healthy financial system is a sound
depository institution system, and an important component of a sound depository
institution system is that depository institutions are not given artificial
incentives to switch between insurance funds or to abandon an insurance fund in
order to gain competitive advantages Such "regulatory arbitrage" wastes scarce
and valuable resources that could be much more productively employed
Furthermore, as we know from our experience in the last recession,
uncertainties about the resolution of insurance fund failures, and the regulatory
policies needed to protect the taxpayer while these uncertainties are resolved,
can only inhibit the willingness of depository institutions to lend While there

-9were many reasons monetary policy encountered strong headwinds during that period,
surely the legislative and regulatory reactions to the taxpayer funding of the
thrift deposit insurance fund and to the depleted nature of the BIF compounded our
problems
Whatever solution is finally adopted, we should not lose sight of first
principles A deposit insurance system that focuses the attention of banks and
thrifts on the relative status of their funds, and a system that rewards those who
can jump ship first, is, to say the least, counterproductive What is needed is a
deposit insurance system whose status is unquestioned so that the depositones can
appropriately focus their attention on the extension and management of credit in
our economy
T*

^^ ~T" ^F rT^ "T*