View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
lOOOam.EDT
July 24, 1998

Testimony by

Alan Greenspan

Chairman

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Committee on Banking and Financial Services

U S House of Representatives

July 24, 1998

I am pleased to be here today to present the Federal Reserve Board's views on the
regulation of over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives Under Secretary Hawke has already addressed
the specific questions raised in your letter of invitation The Board generally agrees with the
Treasury Department's views on these issues In particular, the Board supports a standstill of
attempts by the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) to impose new regulations on
OTC derivatives as a minimalist approach to our longstanding concerns about CFTC assertions of
authority in this area ' In my testimony I shall step back from these issues of immediate concern
and address the fundamental underlying issue, that is, whether it is appropriate to apply the
Commodity Exchange Act (CEA) to over-the-counter derivatives (and, indeed, to financial
derivatives generally) in order to achieve the CEA's objectives—deterring market manipulation
and protecting investors
The CEA and Its Objectives
The Commodity Exchange Act of 1936 and its predecessor the Grain Futures Act of
1922 were a response to the perceived problems of manipulation of gram markets that were
particularly evident in the latter part of the nineteenth and early part of the twentieth centuries
For example, endeavors to corner markets in wheat, while rarely successful, often led to
temporary, but sharp, mcreases in prices that engendered very large losses to those short sellers of
futures contracts who had no alternative but to buy and deliver grain under their contractual
obligations Because quantities of grain following a harvest are generally known and limited, it is
possible, at least in principle, to corner a market
1

It also supports the legislation to amend the banking and insolvency laws that has been
recommended by the President's Working Group on Financial Markets This legislation would
shore up the infrastructure of U S markets and enhance their competitiveness The legislation
recognizes that the traditional insolvency process can create serious risks to counterparties to
financial transactions because of the price volatility of financial assets

It is not possible to corner a market for financial futures where the underlying asset or
its equivalent is in essentially unlimited supply Financial derivative contracts are fundamentally
different from agricultural futures owing to the nature of the underlying asset from which the
derivative contract is "derived " Supplies of foreign exchange, government securities, and certain
other financial instruments are being continuously replenished, and large inventories held
throughout the world are immediately available to be offered in markets if traders endeavor to
create an artificial shortage Thus, unlike commodities whose supply is limited to a particular
growing season and finite carryover, the markets for financial instruments and their derivatives are
deep and, as a consequence, are extremely difficult to manipulate The type of regulation that is
applied to crop futures appears wholly out of place and inappropriate for financial futures,
whether traded on organized exchanges or over-the-counter, and accordingly, the Federal Reserve
Board sees no need for it
The early legislation on the trading of commodity futures was primarily designed to
discourage forms of speculation that were seen as exacerbating price volatility and hurting
fanners In addition, it included provisions designed primarily to protect small investors in
commodity futures, whose participation had been increasing and was viewed as beneficial The
Commodity Futures Trading Commission Act of 1974 did not make any fundamental changes in
the objectives of derivatives regulation However, it expanded the scope of the CEA quite
significantly In addition to creating the CFTC as an independent agency and giving the CFTC
exclusive jurisdiction over commodity futures and options, the 1974 Act expanded the CEA's
definition of a "commodity" beyond a specific list of agricultural commodities to include "all other

goods and articles, except onions, and all services, rights, and interests in which contracts for
future delivery are presently or in the future dealt in "
Given this broadened definition of a commodity and an equally broad interpretation of
what constitutes a futures contract, a wide range of off-exchange transactions would have been
brought potentially within the scope of the CEA The Treasury Department was particularly
concerned about the prospect that the foreign exchange markets might be found to fall within the
Act's scope Aside from the difficulty of manipulating these markets, Treasury argued that
participants in OTC markets, primarily banks and other financial institutions, and large
corporations, did not need the consumer protections of the Commodity Exchange Act
Consequently, Treasury proposed and Congress included a provision in the 1974 Act, the
"Treasury Amendment," which excluded off-exchange derivative transactions in foreign currency
(as well as government securities, and certain other financial instruments) from the newly
expanded CEA What the Treasury did not envision, and the Treasury Amendment did not
protect, was the subsequent development and spectacular growth of a much wider range of OTC
derivative contracts—swaps on interest rates, exchange rates, and prices of commodities and
securities
Potential Application of the CEA to OTC Derivatives
The vast majority of privately negotiated OTC contracts are settled in cash rather than
through delivery Cash settlement typically is based on a rate or price in a highly liquid market
with a very large or virtually unlimited deliverable supply, for example, LIBOR or the spot dollaryen exchange rate To be sure, there are a limited number of OTC derivative contracts that apply
to nonfinancial underlying assets There is a significant business in oil-based derivatives, for

example But unlike farm crops, especially near the end of a crop season, private counterparties
in oil contracts have virtually no ability to restrict the worldwide supply of this commodity (Even
OPEC has been less than successful over the years) Nor can private counterparties restrict
supplies of gold, another commodity whose derivatives are often traded over-the-counter, where
central banks stand ready to lease gold in increasing quantities should the price rise
To be sure, a few, albeit growing, types of OTC contracts such as equity swaps and
some credit derivatives have a limited deliverable supply However, unlike crop futures, where
failure to deliver has additional significant penalties, costs of failure to deliver in OTC derivatives
are almost always limited to actual damages There is no reason to believe either equity swaps or
credit derivatives can influence the price of the underlying assets any more than conventional
securities trading does Thus, manipulators attempting to corner a market, even if successful,
would have great difficulty in inducing sellers in privately negotiated transactions to pay
significantly higher prices to offset their contracts or to purchase the underlying assets
Finally, the pnces established in privately negotiated transactions are not widely
disseminated or used directly or indiscriminately as the basis for pricing other transactions
Counterparties in the OTC markets can easily recognize the risks to which they would be exposed
by failing to make their own independent valuations of their transactions, whose economic and
credit terms may differ in significant respects Moreover, they usually have access to other, often
more reliable or more relevant sources of information Hence, any price distortions in particular
transactions could not affect other buyers or sellers of the underlying asset
Professional counterparties to privately negotiated contracts also have demonstrated
their ability to protect themselves from losses from fraud and counterparty insolvencies They

have managed credit risks quite effectively through careful evaluation of counterparties, the
setting of internal credit limits, and judicious use of netting and collateral agreements In
particular, they have insisted that dealers have financial strength sufficient to warrant a credit
rating of A or higher This, in turn, provides substantial protection against losses from fraud
Dealers are established institutions with substantial assets and significant investments in their
reputations When they have been seen to engage in deceptive practices, the professional
counterparties that have been victimized have been able to obtain redress under laws applicable to
contracts generally Moreover, the threat of legal damage awards provides dealers with strong
incentives to avoid misconduct
A far more powerful incentive, however, is the fear of loss of the dealer's good
reputation, without which it cannot compete effectively, regardless of itsfinancialstrength or
financial engineering capabilities In these respects, derivatives dealers bear no resemblance to the
"bucket shops" whose activities apparently motivate the exchange trading requirement
I do not mean to suggest that counterparties will not in the future suffer significant
losses on their OTC derivatives transactions Since 1994 the effectiveness of their risk
management skills has not been tested by widespread major declines in underlying asset prices
I have no doubt derivatives losses will mushroom at the next significant downturn as will losses
on holdings of other risk assets, both on and off exchange Nonetheless, I see no reason to
question the underlying stability of the OTC markets, or the overall effectiveness of private
market discipline, or the prudential supervision of the derivatives activities of banks and other
regulated participants The huge increase in the volume of OTC transactions reflects the
judgments of counterparties that these instruments provide extensive protection against undue

asset concentration risk They are clearly perceived to add significant value to our financial
structure, both here in the United States and internationaJIy
Accordingly the Federal Reserve Board sees no reason why these markets should be
encumbered with a regulatory structure devised for a wholly different type of market process,
where supplies of underlying assets are driven by the vagaries of weather and seasons
Inappropriate regulation distorts the efficiency of our market system and as a consequence
impedes growth and improvement in standards of living
Application of the CEA to Centralized Markets for Derivatives
Recently, some participants in the OTC markets have shown interest in utilizing
centralized mechanisms for clearing or executing OTC derivatives transactions For example, the
London Clearing House plans to introduce clearing of interest rate swaps and forward rate
agreements in the second half of 1999, and the Electronic Broking Service, a brokerage system
for foreign exchange contracts, reportedly is planning to begin brokering forward rate agreements
The latter service may not be offered in the U S , however, because of the threat of application of
the CEA
Even some who argue that privately negotiated and bilaterally settled derivatives
transactions should be excluded from the CEA, nonetheless believe that such transactions should
be subject to the CEA if they are centrally executed or cleared, for fear that such facilities can
foster price manipulation Leaving aside our concern about the regulatory regime of financial
futures generally, the Federal Reserve Board is particularly concerned that the vast majority of the
instruments currently traded in the OTC markets not be subject to the CEA, even if they become
sufficiently standardized to be centrally executed or cleared To be sure, OTC contracts between

counterparties would then have many similarities to exchange-traded contracts But, they would
still retain distinct characteristics that would leave them economically far short of standardization
For example, participants in trade execution systems may seek to retain counterparty credit limits,
and participants in clearing systems likely will resist constraints on their ability to customize the
economic terms of contracts To force full standardization would reduce the economic value of a
bilateral contract to both parties, and to the marketplace as a whole The 1992 Act as we read it
authorized exemption of all OTC derivatives transactions between professional counterparties
from the CEA, whether or not they are centrally executed or cleared Even with centralized
execution or clearing, the most relevant attributes of these markets would not resemble those of
the agricultural futures markets and hence would not be susceptible to manipulation
Harmonizing Regulation of the OTC Markets and Futures Exchanges
Beyond question, the centralized execution and clearing of what to date have been
privately negotiated and bilaterally cleared transactions would narrow the existing differences
between exchange-traded and OTC derivatives transactions However, that is not a reason to
extend the CEA to cover OTC transactions As we have argued, doing so is unnecessary to
achieve the public policy objectives of the CEA Moreover, as the economic differences between
OTC and exchange-traded contracts are narrowing, it is becoming more apparent that OTC
market participants share this conclusion, their decision to trade outside the regulated
environment implies they do not see the benefits of the CEA as outweighing its costs
Instead, the Federal Reserve believes that the fact that OTC markets function so
effectively without the benefits of the CEA provides a strong argument for development of a less
burdensome regulatory regime for financial derivatives traded on futures exchanges To reiterate,

the existing regulatory framework for futures trading was designed in the 1920s and 1930s for the
trading of grain futures by the general pubbc Like OTC derivatives, exchange-traded financial
derivatives generally are not as susceptible to manipulation and are traded predominantly by
professional counterparties
Indeed, Congress has rejected the notion of a "one-size-fits-all" approach to regulation
of exchange trading The exemptive authority that Congress gave the CFTC in 1992 permitted it
to create a less restrictive regulatory regime for professional trading of financial futures
However, the pilot program proposed by the CFTC evidently has not met the competitive and
business requirements of the futures exchanges—no contracts are currently trading under the
program Last year, the Agriculture Committees of the House and the Senate both attempted to
craft legislation that would spur development of such a new regulatory framework but were
unable to achieve consensus on the best approach In any event, if progress toward a more
appropriate regime is not forthcoming soon, Congress should seriously consider passage of
legislation that would mandate progress
Conclusion
In conclusion, the Board continues to believe that, aside from safety and soundness
regulation of derivatives dealers under the banking or securities laws, regulation of derivatives
transactions that are privately negotiated by professionals is unnecessary Moreover, the Board
questions whether the CEA as currently implemented is an appropriate framework for
professional trading of financial futures on exchanges The key elements of the CEA were put in
place in the 1920s and 1930s to regulate the trading of agricultural futures by the general public
The vast majority offinancialfutures traded simply are not as susceptible to manipulation as
8

agricultural and other commodity futures where supplies are more limited And participants in
financial futures markets are predominantly professionals that simply do not require the customer
protections that may be needed by the general public Regulation that serves no useful purpose
hinders the efficiency of markets to enlarge standards of living In choosing a particular
regulatory regime it is important to remember that no system will fully eliminate mappropnate or
illegal activities Banking examiners, for example, find it difficult to unearth fraud and
embezzlement in their early stages Securities regulators have difficulty ferreting out malfeasance
Even trading on exchanges does not in itself eliminate all endeavors at manipulation, as the Hunt
brothers' 1979-80 fiasco in silver demonstrated The primary source of regulatory effectiveness
has always been private traders being knowledgeable of their counterparties Government
regulation can only act as a backup It should be careful to create net benefits to markets