View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For Release on Delivery
10 00 A M. EDT
October 19, 1993

Testimony by

Alan Greenspan

Chairman

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs

U S

House of Representatives

October 19, 1993

I appreciate this opportunity to provide my views
on the appropriate degree of disclosure by the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC)
The issue of fuller or more immediate disclosure of
FOMC discussions and decisions has been a controversial one
historically
In Congress, the financial markets, and
academia, this topic has been debated repeatedly over the
years
The FOMC itself has reviewed its policies and
procedures in this area frequently and has revised its
practices several times
At the heart of this issue is
balance. The appropriate degree of openness comes from
striking the right balance between the public's right to
know and the need for effective policymaking and
implementation
In a democratic society, public-policy decisions
should be in the open, except where exposure impedes the
primary function assigned to an institution by law
Accordingly, the Federal Reserve makes its decisions public
immediately, except when doing so could undercut the
efficacy of policy or compromise the integrity of the policy
process
When we change the discount rate or reserve
requirements, those decisions are announced at once
When
we establish new ranges for money and credit growth, those
ranges are set forth promptly in our reports to Congress
Moreover, we publish our balance sheet every week with just
a one-day lag, enabling analysts to review our operations in
considerable detail
What we do not disclose immediately are the
implementing decisions with respect to our open market
operations
However, any changes in our objectives in
reserve markets are quickly and publicly signalled by our
open market operations
And we publish minutes of the
policy deliberations and decisions from each FOMC meeting
shortly after the next regular meeting has taken place

-2These minutes, a copy of which for the meeting of February,
1993, I have attached to this statement, can run from 15 to
more than 30 pages, presenting a comprehensive record of the
economic factors and analysis and alternative policy
approaches considered in reaching our decisions
Nevertheless, the Federal Reserve, like other
central banks, has a reputation of being secretive
I
suspect this is largely a result of the nature of a central
bank's mission
The operations of central banks have a
direct impact on financial and foreign exchange markets,
therefore, these institutions often find themselves in the
position where complete openness and disclosure could
inhibit or even thwart the implementation of their public
purpose
Suppose, for example, a central bank that operated
by targeting the foreign exchange rate decided that it might
be appropriate to change the target rate at a given point in
the future
Or, to bring the discussion closer to home, say
that the central bank phrased its policies in terms of
contingency plans--that is, if certain economic or financial
conditions prevailed, a particular action would be taken
If those decisions were made public, markets would tend to
incorporate the changes immediately, preventing the policies
from being effectively carried out as planned
More broadly, immediate disclosure of these types
of contingencies would tend to produce increased volatility
in financial markets, as market participants reacted not
only to actual Federal Reserve actions but also to possible
Federal Reserve actions
It is often the case that the FOMC
expresses a predisposition toward a policy change in its
directive to the Open Market Desk
Such a predisposition,
for example toward easing, implies that the FOMC is more
concerned about developments that would dictate an easing of
policy rather than a tightening, and therefore wants to

-3respond relatively promptly to information suggesting the
need for such action
We often express this predisposition
without any change in instrument settings in fact resulting
In such circumstances, the release of those directives
during the period they are in force would only add to
fluctuations in financial markets, moving rates when no
immediate change was intended
As a consequence, a disclosure requirement would
impair the usefulness of the directives, as Committee
members, concerned about the announcement effect of a
directive biased either toward ease or tightening, would
tend to shy away from anything but a vote of immediate
change or of no change at the meeting
An important element
of flexibility in the current procedures would be lost,
which can scarcely serve the public interest
Immediate
disclosure of the directive would change the nature of
monetary policymaking, and it would not be a change for the
better
To repeat, as a general matter, it is desirable for
public institutions to conduct their business in the open
The Federal Reserve endorses this principle and adheres to
it, except when doing so would prevent us from fulfilling
our fundamental mission of producing sound public policy
Holding open meetings of the FOMC or releasing a
videotape, audio tape, or transcript of them would so
seriously constrain the process of formulating policy as to
render those meetings nearly unproductive
The candid
airing, of views, the forthright give and take, and the
tentative posing of new ideas likely would disappear
Monetary policy would suffer, and the economy with it
A number of important items currently discussed at
FOMC meetings simply could not be mentioned in open forum
We would no longer have the benefit of sensitive information
from foreign central banks and other official institutions

-4or of proprietary information from private-sector sources,
as we could not risk the publication of information given us
in confidence
Moreover, to avoid creating unnecessary volatility
in financial and foreign exchange markets, the FOMC might
have to forgo explorations of the full range of policy
options
Our discussions would, in effect, become selfcensored to prevent the voicing of any views that might
prove unsettling to the markets
Even a lag in releasing a
verbatim record of the meetings would not eliminate this
problem, but only attenuate it
Unconventional policy
prescriptions and ruminations about the longer-term outlook
for economic and financial market developments might never
be surfaced at meetings, for fear of igniting a speculative
reaction when the discussion was disclosed
Let me take a moment to describe more fully the
process followed at FOMC meetings to reach decisions on
monetary policy
After staff presentations of recent
developments and emerging economic trends, a roundtable
discussion of all nineteen participants begins
The Reserve
Bank presidents describe conditions and developments within
their districts, and both they and the members of the Board
of Governors go on to evaluate the outlook for the U S
economy
All members bring in, where relevant, international economic and financial considerations
In light of
this discussion, we then consider whether the stance of
monetary policy needs to be adjusted, either immediately, or
possibly in the future under particular circumstances
A considerable amount of free discussion and
probing questioning by the participants of each other and of
key FOMC staff members takes place
In the wide-ranging
debate, new ideas are often tested, many of which are
rejected
Ideas initiated by one participant are frequently

-5built upon by others
This type of discourse is an
invaluable ingredient of our policymaking process.
As I indicated before this Committee last week, the
prevailing views of many participants change as evidence and
insights emerge
This process has proven to be a very
effective procedure for gaining a consensus around which a
directive to the Open Market Desk can be crafted
It could
not function effectively if participants had to be concerned
that their half-thought-through, but nonetheless potentially
valuable, notions would soon be made public
I fear in such a situation the public record would
be a sterile set of bland pronouncements scarcely capturing
the necessary debates which are required of monetary
policymaking
A tendency would arise for one-on-one premeetmg discussions, with public meetings merely announcing
already agreed-upon positions, or for each participant to
enter the meeting with a final position not subject to the
views of others
Such a record would be far less
informative than the minutes we currently publish
It has been averred that, because the minutes we
release do not indicate which individuals voiced which views
at the meetings, the FOMC members themselves escape
accountability for their actions
This is contrary to fact
The vote of each FOMC member is recorded, by name, and the
reasons for that vote are also recorded
In the case of a
dissent from the majority, the reasoning behind the vote is
generally explained separately
In the case of a vote cast
with the majority, the members review drafts of the minutes
to assure themselves that the record will accurately reflect
their views and the reasons for voting as they did
In both the Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) and
the Government in the Sunshine Act, Congress explicitly
recognized that there were types of information and kinds of
meetings that should be protected from dissemination to the

-6public
Certain exemptions have been provided in FOIA for
information that, for example, is of a confidential
financial nature and in the Sunshine Act for meetings that
would prompt speculation in financial markets
In the
various exempted areas, it was determined that release of
information would not be in the public interest
For
similar reasons, I believe that the consequences of
requiring the prompt release of a verbatim record of FOMC
meetings would most certainly not be in the nation's best
interest
Mr Chairman, in your letter of invitation to this
hearing, you also posed several specific questions related
to the maintenance of notes or records of FOMC meetings and
to the premature release of FOMC information
I would like
to turn now to the answers to those three questions
At FOMC meetings, I take very brief, rough notes on
the views expressed by participants
These notes assist me
in keeping track of Committee sentiment as the meeting
progresses and thus in judging where a consensus may be
reached with respect to monetary policy
After the meeting,
the notes are kept in a locked file cabinet along with other
FOMC materials
Others attending the FOMC meetings may also be
taking notes, and I am sure they will tell you about them in
their own responses
I have suggested to the Reserve Bank
presidents that they respond to your questions regarding
whatever records may be kept at their own Banks, I will
cover records made by the Board staff, and, in particular,
by the FOMC secretariat
Some individual members of the Board staff take
handwritten notes and retain them to help them in
discharging their responsibilities
The meetings are
recorded electronically by the FOMC secretariat
These
audio tapes are used to assist in the preparation of the

-7minutes that are released to the public following the
subsequent meeting, thereafter, the tapes are recorded over
In the process of putting together the minutes, an unedited
transcript is prepared from the tapes, as are detailed notes
on selected topics discussed in the course of the meeting
These materials generally are seen only by the staff
involved in preparing the minutes, and the documents are
kept under lock and key by the FOMC secretariat
With regard to your final query, on the release of
information about FOMC meetings, I would again state my
strong view that any unauthorized release of FOMC decisions
is a very serious matter
Leaks of FOMC proceedings are
clearly unfair to the public, potentially disruptive of the
policymaking process, and undoubtedly destructive of public
confidence in the Federal Reserve
Any leaks that may have occurred were most
assuredly not orchestrated or directed by the FOMC
A
deliberate premature leak of information is repugnant
Our
current policies that call for delayed release of
information are in place for good reasons, as I indicated
previously
They are grounded on an assumption of
confidentiality, leaks undermine these policies
I suspect that, to an extent, what appear to be
deliberate leaks may instead represent something quite
different
In some cases, FOMC participants who speak to
the press may believe they have revealed nothing about
recent monetary policy decisions, but they may in fact have
inadvertently provided enough of a sense of the policy
considerations to allow conclusions to be drawn, especially
for experienced reporters speaking to several sources
This
puts us in a difficult situation
We should not reveal
confidential information about our decisions
At the same
time, we cannot and should not wall ourselves off entirely
from the media, it is our obligation to explain the broad

-8considerations that motivate monetary policy, to correct
certain misimpressions, and to convey as much information as
possible, without roiling markets, creating inequities, or
violating the trust of our colleagues
The FOMC has discussed this issue extensively, and
we have taken several steps that we believe will curb any
further unauthorized release of information
We have reemphasized the necessity of avoiding contact with the press
during the periods surrounding FOMC meetings and of caution
at other times
Moreover, it has been made clear that any
future leak from an FOMC meeting will be followed up very
aggressively--by a full investigation that will include
gathering sworn statements from all attendees
As to whether I personally played a part in past
leaks of FOMC information, I can assure you that I have
never knowingly released to the press or to other members of
the public any information about the results of an FOMC
meeting prior to the formal, scheduled release
I would
include one footnote to this statement, however
From time
to time, I have briefed members of various Administrations
about the outcomes of FOMC meetings, because that knowledge
could assist them in the formulation of government policies
for which they have responsibility
This qualification has
not, however, been a relevant one over the past year or so,
as the Federal Reserve has not altered its instrument
settings
I trust the problem of leaks is behind us
If I am
wrong about this, the FOMC's policy on delayed disclosure of
decisions will have to be reevaluated
Should we have to
change our policy as a result, it would be unfortunate, for
I firmly believe that a shift to prompter disclosure of the
substance of our deliberations will adversely affect our
discussions and decisions and therefore monetary policy
itself