View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY
10 00 a m EDT
September 13, 1990

Testimony by

Alan Greenspan

Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs

United States House of Representatives

September 13, 1990

I am pleased to appear before this Committee to discuss deposit
insurance reform.

Your letter of invitation contained a list of important

issues and questions which I will try to address

Our recent experience

with thrift institutions underlines the pressing need for deposit
insurance reform

Indeed, the Congress recognized that last year's

landmark FIRREA was only a first step when it mandated a Treasury study of
deposit insurance issues

This study, in which the Federal Reserve is an

active participant, will be published late this year or early next

By

holding hearings considerably before that research is complete, I hope
that the Congress will be able to focus on the needed legislation
immediately after the release of the Treasury study
Your letter of invitation suggested that the topic of these
hearings would be solely deposit insurance reform

While this subject is

complex, the Board believes the issue is intimately related to the need
for legislation to also modernize our banking system in other ways

The

Congress and the Board repeatedly are reminded of the erosion of the
competitiveness of our banking system both domestically and
internationally

The Board believes that addressing this problem should

be joined with deposit insurance reform, and my statement will intertwine
both topics
The fundamental problems with our current deposit insurance
program are clearly understood and are, I believe, subject to little
debate among those with drastically different prescriptions for reform
The safety net—deposit insurance, as well as the discount window—has so
lowered the risks perceived by depositors as to make them relatively

- 2 -

indifferent to the soundness of the depository recipients of their funds,
except in unusual circumstances

With depositors exercising insufficient

discipline through the risk premium they demand on the interest rate they
receive on their deposits, the incentive of some banks' owners to control
risk-taking has been dulled.

Profits associated with risk-taking accrue

to owners, while losses in excess of bank capital that would otherwise
fall on depositors are absorbed by the FDIC
Weak depositor discipline and this moral hazard of deposit
insurance have two important implications

First, the implicit deposit

insurance subsidy has encouraged banks to enhance their profitability by
increasing their reliance on deposits rather than capital to fund their
assets

In effect, the deposit insurance funds have been increasingly

substituted for private capital as the cushion between the asset
portfolios of insured institutions and their liabilities to depositors
hundred years ago, the average equity-capital-to-asset ratio of U S
was almoslt 25 percent, approximately four tunes the current level

A

banks
Much

of the decline over the past century no doubt reflects the growing
efficiency of our financial system

But it is difficult to believe that

many of the banks operating over recent decades would have been able to
expand their assets so much, with so little additional investment by their
owners, were it not for the depositors' perception that, despite the
relatively small capital buffer, their risks were minimal.

Regulatory

efforts over the last 10 to 15 years have stabilized and partially
reversed the sharp decline in bank equity capital-asset ratios.

This has

- 3 -

occurred despite the sizable write-off of loans and the substantial buildup in loan-loss reserves in the last three years or so

But the capital

ratios of many banks are still too low.
Second, government assurances of the liquidity and availability
of deposits have enabled some banks with declining capital ratios to fund
riskier asset portfolios at a lower cost and on a much larger scale, with
governmental regulations and supervision, rather than market processes,
the major constraint on risk-taking

As a result, more resources have

been allocated to finance risky projects than would have been dictated by
economic efficiency.
In brief, the subsidy implicit in our current deposit insurance
system has stimulated the growth of banks and thrifts

In the process the

safety net has distorted market signals to depositors and bankers about
the economics of the underlying transactions

This has led depositors to

be less cautious in choosing among institutions and has induced some
owners and their managers to take excessive risk

In turn, the expanded

lending to risky ventures has required increased effort and resources by
supervisors and regulators to monitor and modify behavior
But in reviewing the list of deficiencies of the deposit
insurance system, we should not lose sight of the contribution that both
deposit insurance and the discount window have made to macroeconomic
stability

The existence and use of the safety net have shielded the

broader financial system and the real economy from instabilities in
banking markets

More specifically, it has protected the economy from the

risk of deposit runs, especially the risk of such runs spreading from bank
to bank, disrupting credit and payment flows and the level of trade and

- 4 -

commerce.

Confidence in the stability of the banking and payments system

has been the major reason why the United States has not suffered a
financial panic or systemic bank run in the last half century.
There are thus important reasons to take care as we modify our
deposit insurance system

Reform is required.

So is caution.

The ideal

is an institutional framework that, to the extent possible, induces banks
both to hold more capital and to be managed as if there were no safety
net, while at the same time shielding unsophisticated depositors and
minimizing disruptions to credit and payment flows
If we were starting from scratch, the Board believes it would be
difficult to make the case that deposit insurance coverage should be as
high as its current $100,000 level

However, whatever the merits of the

1980 increase in the deposit insurance level from $40,000 to $100,000, it
is clear that the higher level of depositor protection has been in place
long enough to be fully capitalized in the market value of depository
institutions, and incorporated into the financial decisions of millions
of households

The associated scale and cost of funding have been

incorporated into a wide variety of bank and thrift decisions, including
portfolio choices, staffing, branch structure, and marketing strategy
Consequently, a return to lower deposit insurance coverage—like any
tightening of the safety net—would reduce insured depository market
values and involve significant transition costs

It is one thing

initially to offer and then maintain a smaller degree of insurance
coverage, and quite another to reimpose on the existing system a lower
level of insurance, with its associated readjustment and unwinding costs
This is why the granting of subsidies by the Congress should be considered

- 5 -

so carefully

they not only distort the allocation of resources, but also

are extremely difficult to eliminate, imposing substantial transition
costs on the direct and indirect beneficiaries

For such reasons, the

Board has concluded that, should the Congress decide to lower deposit
insurance limits, a meaningful transition period would be needed
Another relevant factor that should be considered in evaluating
the $100,000 insurance limit is the distribution of deposit holders by
size of account.

Unfortunately, data to analyze this issue by individual

account holder do not exist

However, we have been able to use data

collected on an individual household basis in our 1983 Survey of Consumer
Finances to estimate the distribution of account holders

While these

data are seven years old, they are the best available until results from
our 1989 Survey of Consumer Finances become available this fall

I have

attached as an appendix to this statement summary tables and descriptive
text of the 1983 survey results.

Briefly, the survey suggests that

between 1 0 and 1 5 percent of U S
balances in excess of $100,000.

households held, in 1983, deposit

The demographic characteristics of these

account holders suggest that they are mainly older, retired citizens with
most of their financial assets in insured accounts

These characteristics

of heads of households owning deposits are remarkably stable as the size
of deposits declines to $50,000
A decision by Congress to leave the $100,000 limit unchanged,
however, should not preclude other reforms that would reduce current
inequities in, and abuses of, the deposit insurance system, often
thwarting its purpose

Serious study should be devoted to the cost and

effectiveness of policing the $100,000 limit so that multiple accounts are

- 6 -

not used to obtain more protection for individual depositors than Congress
intends

We at the Federal Reserve believe that it is administratively

feasible—but not costless—to establish controls on the number and dollar
value of insured accounts per individual at one depository institution, at
all institutions in the same holding company, and perhaps even across
depositories of different ownership

But we are concerned about the cost

and administrative complexity of such schemes, and would urge the careful
weighing of benefits and costs before adopting any specific plan
The same study could consider the desirability of limiting passthrough deposit insurance—under which up to $100,000 insurance protection
is now explicitly extended to each of the multiple beneficiaries of some
large otherwise uninsured deposits.

Brokered accounts of less than

$100,000 also have been used to abuse deposit insurance protection,
particularly by undercapitalized institutions

However, we must be

careful to remember that the use of brokered deposits by healthy firms can
be the economy's most efficient way of allocating funds to their most
productive use

The study should keep in mind these considerations, as

well as the power Congress has already provided the agencies to constrain
misuse of brokered accounts
No matter what the Congress decides on deposit insurance limits,
we must be cautious of our treatment of uninsured depositors.

Such

depositors should be expected to assess the quality of their bank deposits
just as they are expected' to evaluate any other financial asset they
purchase

Earlier I noted that our goal should be for banks to operate as

much as possible as if there were no safety net

In fact, runs of

uninsured deposits from banks under stress have become commonplace

- 7 -

So far, the pressure transmitted from such episodes to other
banks whose strength may be in doubt has been minimal

Nevertheless, the

clear response pattern of uninsured depositors to protect themselves by
withdrawing their deposits from a bank under pressure raises the very real
risk that in a stressful environment the flight to quality could
precipitate wider financial market and payments distortions.

These

systemic effects could easily feed back to the real economy, no matter how
open the discount window and how expansive open market operations

Thus,

while deposits in excess of insurance limits should not be protected by
the safety net at any bank, reforms designed to rely mainly on increased
market discipline by uninsured depositors raise serious stability
concerns
An example of one such approach is depositor co-insurance or a
deductible under which a depositor at a failed institution receives most,
but not all, of his or her deposit in excess of a reduced (or the current)
insurance limit

This option has some attractions, coupling depositor

market discipline with relatively modest possible losses to depositors.
The Board believes, however, that an explicit policy that requires
imposition of uninsured depositor loss—no matter how small—is likely to
increase the risk of depositor runs and to exacerbate the depositor
response to rumors
Another option to rely more on private-market incentives is the
use of private deposit insurance as a supplement or replacement for FDIC
insurance.

This would require, of course, that all relevant supervisory

information—much of which is now held confidential—be shared with
private insurers who would be obligated to use that information only to

evaluate the risk of depositor insurance and not for the purposes of
adjusting any of their own portfolio options.

In addition, it is clearly

unreasonable to impose on private insurers any macro-stability
responsibilities in their commercial underwriting of deposit insurance
Private insurers' withdrawal of coverage in a weakening economy, or their
unwillingness to forebear in such circumstances would be understandable
but counterproductive

Private insurers' inability to meet their

obligations after an underwriting error would be disruptive at best and
involve taxpayer responsibility at worst.

Private insurance and public

responsibility unfortunately are not always compatible.

We have similar

concerns with mutual assurance among groups of banks who would seek to
evaluate each other's risk exposure and discipline overly risky entities
by expulsion from their mutual guarantee syndicate

In addition, a system

of mutual guarantees by banks could raise serious anti-competitive issues
There has also been support for the increased use of subordinated
debentures in the capital structure of banking organizations.

Intriguing

attractions of this option are the thoughts that non-runable, but serially
maturing, debt would provide both enhanced market discipline and a
periodic market evaluation of the bank

The Board continues to support

the use of subordinated debt for these reasons, as well as the fact that
it provides supplementary capital to act as an additional buffer to the
FDIC over and above that provided by the owners' equity capital

But, in

our view, subordinated debentures can only be supporting players and not
be awarded the central role in reform

This is a limited source of

capital and one that may prove difficult and expensive to obtain when
advertised as having constrained returns whose holders are expected to

- 9 -

absorb losses for the FDIC

Adding features to make it more attractive

adds complications which perhaps are best met directly by additional pure
equity and other reforms
A promising approach that seeks to simulate market discipline
with minimal stability implications is the application of risk-based
deposit insurance premiums by the FDIC

The idea is to make the price of

insurance a function of the bank's risk, reducing the subsidy to risktaking and spreading the cost of insurance more fairly across depository
institutions

In principle, this approach has many attractive

characteristics, and could be designed to augment risk-based capital.

For

example, banks with high risk-based capital ratios might be charged lower
insurance premiums

But the range of premiums necessary to induce genuine

behavioral changes in portfolio management might well be many multiples of
the existing premium, thereby raising practical concerns about its
application

Risk-based premiums also would have to be designed with some

degree of complexity if they are to be fair and if unintended incentives
are to be avoided

In any event, the potential additional benefits on top

of an internationally negotiated risk-based capital system, while
positive, require further evaluation
Another approach that has induced increasing interest is the
insured narrow bank

Such an institution would invest only in high

quality, short-maturity, liquid investments, recovering its costs for
checking accounts and wire transfers from user fees.

The narrow bank

would thus require drastic institutional changes, especially for thousands
of our smaller banks and for virtually all households using checking
accounts

Movement from the present structure for delivery of many bank

- 10 -

services would be difficult and costly, placing U.S
disadvantage internationally.

banks at a

In addition, this approach might shift and

possibly focus systemic risk on larger banks

Banking organizations would

have to locate their business and household credit operations in nonbank
affiliates funded by uninsured deposits and borrowings raised in money and
capital markets

Only larger organizations could fund in this way and

these units, unless financed longer term than banks today, would, even
with the likely higher capital ratio imposed on them by the market, be
subject to the same risks of creditor runs that face uninsured banks, with
all of the associated systemic implications

If this were the case, we

might end up with the same set of challenges we face today, refocused on a
different set of institutions

We at the Board believe that while the

notion of a narrow bank to insulate the insurance fund is intriguing, in
our judgment further study of these systemic and operational implications
is required
If, in fact, proposals that rely on uninsured depositor
discipline, private insurance, subordinated debentures, risk-based
premiums, and structural changes in the delivery of bank services raise
significant difficulties, reform should then look to other ways to curb
banks' risk appetites, and to limit the likelihood that the deposit
insurance fund, and possibly the taxpayer, will be called on to protect
depositors

The Board believes that the most promising approach is to

reform both bank capital and supervisory policies

This would build upon

the groundwork laid in FIRREA, in which Congress recognized as key
components of a sound banking system the essentiality of strong capital
plus effective supervisory controls

Both would be designed to reduce the

- 11 -

value of the insurance subsidy.

Neither would rule out either concurrent

or subsequent additions to deposit insurance reform, such as the changes
discussed previously, other proposals, or new approaches that may emerge
in the years ahead

In fact, higher capital, by reducing the need for,

and thereby the value of, deposit insurance would make subsequent reform
easier

There would be less at stake for the participants in the system
At the end of this year, the phase-in to the International

Capital Standards under the Basle Accord will begin

This risk-based

capital approach provides a framework for incorporating portfolio and offbalance sheet risk into capital calculations

Most U S. banks have

already made the adjustment required for the fully phased-in standard that
will be effective at the end of 1992

However, the prospective

increasingly competitive environment suggests that the minimum level of
capital called for by the 1992 requirements may not be adequate,
especially for institutions that want to take on additional activities.
As a result of the safety net, too many banking organizations, in our
judgment, have travelled too far down the road of operating with modest
capital levels

It may well be necessary to retrace our steps and begin

purposefully to move to capital requirements that would, over time, be
more consistent with what the market would require if the safety net were
more modest

The argument for more capital is strengthened by the

necessity to provide banking organizations with a wider range of service
options in an increasingly competitive world

Indeed, projections of the

competitive pressures only intensify the view that if our financial
institutions are to be among the strongest in the world, let alone avoid
an extension of the taxpayers' obligation to even more institutions, we

- 12 -

must increase capital requirements

Our international agreements under

the Basle Accord permit us to do so
There are three objectives of a higher capital requirement
First, higher capital would strengthen the incentives of bank owners and
managers to evaluate more prudently the risks and benefits of portfolio
choices because more of their money would be at risk.
moral hazard risk of deposit insurance would be reduced

In effect, the
Second, higher

capital levels would create a larger buffer between the mistakes of bank
owners and managers and the need to draw on the deposit insurance fund
For too many institutions, that buffer has been too low in recent years
The key to creating incentives to behave as the market would dictate, and
at the same time creating these buffers or shock absorbers, is to require
that those who would profit from an institution's success have the
appropriate amount of their own capital at risk

Third, requiring higher

capital imposes on bank managers an additional market test.

They must

convince investors that the expected returns justify the commitment of
risk capital

Those banks unable to do so would not be able to expand

We are in the process in the Federal Reserve System of developing
more specific capital proposals, including appropriate transition
arrangements designed to minimize disruptions
would like to anticipate several criticisms

However, at the outset I
For many banks, raising

significant new capital will be neither easy nor cheap

Maintaining

return on equity will be more difficult, and those foreign banks that only
adhere to the Basle minimums may be put in a somewhat better competitive
position relative to some U.S

banks

Higher capital requirements also

will tend to accelerate the move toward bank consolidation and slow bank

- 13 -

asset growth.

However, these concerns must be balanced against the

increasing need for reform now, the difficulties with all the other
options, and both the desire of, and necessity for, banking organizations
to broaden their scope of activities in order to operate successfully
More generally, many of the arguments about the competitive
disadvantages of higher capital requirements are short-sighted.

Well-

capitalized banks are the ones best positioned to be successful in the
establishment of long-term relationships, to be the most attractive
counterparties for a large number of financial transactions and
guarantees, and to expand their business activities to meet new
opportunities and changing circumstances.

Indeed, many successful U.S

and foreign institutions would today meet substantially increased riskbased capital standards.

In addition, the evidence of recent years

suggests that U S. banks can raise sizable equity

The dollar volume of

new stock issues by banking organizations has grown at a greater rate
since the late 1970s than the total dollar volume of new issues by all
domestic corporate firms
Higher capital standards should go a long way toward inducing
market-like behavior by banks

However, the Board believes that, so long

as a significant safety net exists, additional inducements will be needed
through an intensification of supervisory efforts to deter banks from
maintaining return on equity by acquiring riskier assets

Where it is not

already the practice, full in-bank supervisory reviews—focusing on asset
portfolios and off-balance sheet commitments—should occur at least
annually, and the results of such examinations should promptly be shared
with the board of directors of the bank and used to evaluate the adequacy

- 14 -

of the bank's capital

The examiner should be convinced after a rigorous

and deliberate review that the loan-loss reserves are consistent with the
quality of the portfolio

If they are not, the examiner should insist

that additional reserves be created with an associated reduction in the
earnings or equity capital of the bank
This method of adjusting and measuring capital by reliance on
examiner loan evaluations does not depend on market value accounting to
adjust the quality of the assets

Some day, perhaps, we may be able to

apply generally accepted market value accounting precepts to both the
assets and liabilities of a financial going concern with a wide spectrum
of financial assets and liabilities

But the Board is not comfortable

with the process as it has developed so far, either regarding market value
accounting's ability accurately to reflect market values over reasonable
periods or to avoid being overly sensitive to short-run events.

For most

banks, loans are the predominant asset, an asset that the examiners should
evaluate in each of the proposed annual in-bank supervisory reviews

We

at the Federal Reserve believe that the examiners' classification of loan
quality should, as I noted, be fully reflected in the banks' loan loss
reserves by a diversion of earnings or a reduction in capital.

If the

resultant capital is not consistent with minimum capital standards, the
board of directors and the bank's regulators should begin the process of
requiring the bank either to reduce those assets or to rebuild equity
capital
If credible capital raising commitments are not forthcoming, and
if those commitments are not promptly met, the authorities should pursue
such responses as lowered dividends, slower asset growth or perhaps even

- 15 -

asset contraction, restrictions on the use of insured brokered deposits,
if any, and divestiture of affiliates with the resources used to
recapitalize the bank

What is important is that the supervisory

responses occur promptly and firmly and that they be anticipated by the
bank

This progressive discipline or prompt corrective action of a bank

with inadequate capital builds on our current bank supervisory procedures
and is designed to simulate market pressures from risk-taking—to link
more closely excessive risk-taking with its costs—without creating market
disruptions

It is also intended to help preserve the franchise value of

a going concern by acting early and quickly to restore a depository to
financial health

In this way, the precipitous drop in value that normally

occurs when a firm is placed in conservatorship or receivership would, for
the large majority of cases, be avoided
While some flexibility is certainly required in this approach,
the Board believes there must be a prescribed set of responses and a
presumption that these responses will be applied unless the regulator
determines that the circumstances do not warrant them.

Even though prompt

corrective action implies some limit on the discretion of supervisors to
delay for reasons that they perceive to be in the public interest, the
Board is of the opinion that it would be a mistake to eliminate completely
the discretion of the regulator
Accordingly, the Board believes that a system that combined a
statutorily prescribed course of action with an allowance for regulatory
flexibility would result in meaningful prompt resolution

For example, if

a depository institution failed to meet minimum capital requirements
established by its primary regulatory agency, the agency might be required

- 16 -

by statute to take certain remedial action, unless it determined on the
basis of particular circumstances that such action was not required

The

presumption would thus be shifted toward supervisory action, and
delay would require an affirmative act by the regulatory agency
The prescribed remedial action required in a given case would be
dependent upon the adequacy of the institution's capital

As the capital

fell below established levels, the supervisor could be required, for
example, to order the institution to formulate a capital plan, limit its
growth, limit or eliminate dividends, or divest certain nonbank
affiliates

In the event of seriously depleted capital, the supervisor

could require a merger, sale, conservatorship or liquidation
In adopting such a statutory framework, Congress should consider
designing the system so that forced mergers, divestitures and, when
necessary, conservatorships could be required while there is still
positive equity capital in the depository institution

While existing

stockholders should be given a reasonable period of time to correct
deteriorating capital positions, Congress should specifically provide the
bank regulators with the clear authority, and therefore explicit support,
to act well before technical insolvency in order to minimize the ultimate
resolution costs

The presence of positive equity capital, even if at low

levels, when combined with any tier 2 capital, would limit reorganization
and liquidation costs
In the Board's view, most of the remedial actions discussed above
can be taken, and have been taken, by bank regulators under the current
legal framework

Under current law, however, the actions to be taken are

discretionary and dependent upon a showing of unsafe or unsound conditions

- 17 -

or a violation of law, and implementation of a supervisory remedial action
can be extended over a protracted period of time where the depository
institution contests the regulator' s determination

In cases where an

institution's capital is deteriorating, the progressive discipline
framework described above would establish a systematic program of
progressive action based on the capital of the institution, instead of
requiring the regulator to determine on a case-by-case basis, as a
precondition to remedial action, that an unsafe or unsound practice
exists.

This program would introduce a greater level of consistency of

treatment into the supervisory process, place investors and managers on
notice regarding the expected supervisory response to falling capital
levels, and reduce the likelihood of protracted administrative actions
challenging the regulator's actions
The Board is in the process of developing the parameters,
processes and procedures for prompt corrective action

One of the

principles guiding our efforts is the need to balance rules with
discretion.

In addition, as is the case for higher capital standards,

the Board is mindful of the need for an appropriate transition period
before fully implementing such a change in supervisory policy.
Higher capital and prompt corrective action would increase the
cost and reduce the availability of credit from insured institutions to
riskier borrowers

In effect, our proposal would reduce the incentive

some banks currently have to overinvest in risky credits at loan rates
that do not fully reflect the risks involved.

This implies that the

organizers of speculative and riskier ventures will have to restructure
their borrowing plans, including possibly paying more for their credit, or

- 18 -

seek financing from noninsured entities
proposals no longer viable

Some borrowers may find their

However, it is just such financing by some

insured institutions that has caused so many of the current difficulties,
and it is one of the objectives of our proposals to cause depositories to
reconsider the economics of such credits.

As insured institutions

reevaluate the risk-return tradeoff, they are likely to be more interested
in credit extensions to less risky borrowers, increasing the economic
efficiency of our resource allocation
Despite their tendency to raise the average level of bank asset
quality, higher capital requirements and prompt corrective action will not
eliminate bank failures

An insurance fund will still be needed, but we

believe that, with a fund of reasonable size, the risk to taxpayers should
be reduced substantially

As I have noted, higher capital requirements

and prompt corrective action imply greater caution in bank asset choices
and a higher cushion to the FDIC to absorb bank losses.

In addition, an

enhanced supervisory approach will not permit deteriorating positions to
accumulate.
But until these procedures have been adopted and the banking
system has adjusted to them, circumstances could put the existing
insurance fund under severe pressure

As Chairman Seidman has indicated,

the fund is already operating under stress, as its reserves have declined
in recent years and now stand, as a percentage of insured deposits, at
their lowest level in history

At the same time, there remain all too

many problems in the banking system, problems that have been growing of
late as many banks, including many larger banks, have been experiencing a
deterioration in the quality of their loan portfolios, particularly real

- 19 -

estate loans

It thus seems clear that the insurance fund likely will

remain under stress for some time to come

Moreover, pressures would

intensify if real estate market conditions were to weaken further or a
recession were to develop in the general economy.
It should, however, be clearly underlined that the size or
adequacy of the insurance fund does not change the quality of the deposit
insurance guarantee made by the federal government, it does allocate the
cost of meeting any guarantee between the banking industry, that pays the
insurance premiums, and the taxpayers as a whole

It should, in our view,

be the policy of the government to minimize the risk to taxpayers of the
deposit insurance guarantee, and we believe that our proposal does that
While some increase in insurance premiums is in all likelihood necessary,
we must be concerned that attempts to accomplish this end by substantially
higher insurance premiums may well end up—especially if accompanied by
higher capital requirements—simply making deposits so unattractive that
banks are unable to compete.

Avoiding taxpayer costs and maintaining a

competitive banking system are just two more reasons why basic deposit
insurance reform is so urgent.
Among the deposit insurance reforms that might be considered on
the basis of both strengthening the insurance fund and fairness to smaller
and regional banks is the assessment of insurance premiums on the foreign
branch deposits of U S

banks

A substantial proportion of the deposits

of the largest U.S. banks are booked at branches outside the United
States, including offshore centers in the Caribbean
deposits could yield significant revenue for the FDIC

Assessing such

- 20 -

However, assessing deposit insurance premiums on foreign deposits
would involve some costs
decline in their yields

Such deposits may be quite sensitive to a small
Thus imposing premiums could lead to deposit

withdrawals and funding problems at some U.S. banking organizations, and
possibly inhibit the ability of these organizations to raise capital
Even if no adjustment is made in the insurance assessment on
foreign deposits, held almost solely by large banks, other deposit
insurance reforms should be equally applicable to banks of all sizes

No

observer is comfortable with the inequities and adverse incentives of an
explicit or implicit program that penalizes depositors, creditors, and
owners of smaller banks more than those of larger ones

The Board

believes no bank should assume that its scale insulates it from market
discipline, nor should any depositor with deposits in excess of the
insurance limit at the largest of U.S

banks assume that he or she faces

no loss should their bank fail
Nevertheless, it is clear that there may be some banks, at some
particular times, whose collapse and liquidation would be excessively
disruptive to the financial system.

But it is only under the very

special conditions, which should be relatively rare, of significant and
unavoidable risk to the financial system that our policies for
resolving failed or failing institutions should be relaxed

The benefits

from the avoidance of a contagious loss of confidence in the financial
system accrue to us all

But included in the cost of such action is the

loss of market discipline that would result if large banks and their
customers presume a kind of exemption from loss of their funds

The

Board's policies of prompt corrective action and higher capital are

- 21 -

designed to minimize these costs

Under these policies, the presumption

should always be that prompt and predictable supervisory action will be
taken

For no bank is ever too large or too small to escape the

application of the same prompt corrective action standards applied to
other banks

Any bank can be required to rebuild its capital to adequate

levels and, if it does not, be required to contract its assets, divest
affiliates, cut its dividends, change its management, sell or close
offices, and the resultant smaller entity can be merged or sold to another
institution with the resources to recapitalize it

If this is not

possible, the entity can be placed in conservatorship until it is
It is, by the way, the largest U S

banks that would be required

under our proposals to raise the most additional capital, both absolutely
and proportionally

Most banks with assets less than $1 billion already

meet capital requirements considerably above the fully phased-in Basle
Capital Accord minimums

In addition, it bears emphasizing that no

deposit insurance reform that truly reduces the subsidy existing in the
current system will be costless for banks

The issue really is one of

achieving maximum benefit from reform at minimum cost.

We believe that

our proposals achieve this goal
It is worth noting that in many foreign countries large banks are
considered so important to their economy that it is widely anticipated
that authorities in these countries would support these banks during
financial crises.

In some countries, notably France and Italy, some large

banks are owned by the government, another factor which arguably leads
market participants to doubt that these banks could fail.

Thus the

commitment of foreign authorities presumably extends beyond the rather

- 22 -

limited levels explicitly incorporated into their deposit insurance
systems, and may potentially create the same types of problems that the
United States faces with institutions deemed "too big to fail."
Virtually all of the major industrial countries have instituted a
system of explicit deposit insurance

The character of these systems,

however, varies widely, and most of them are more modest in scope than the
U.S

system

In many cases, especially in Europe, deposit insurance is

not a funded system, but rather an agreement among banks intended to make
money available to protect the small depositors at failed banks

Except

in Germany and Italy, the ceiling on insured deposits is substantially
lower than in the United States.

Membership in the insurance system is

also voluntary in several countries

Though most banks in these countries

join the system, deposit insurance is not viewed as the primary means of
support for large banks

As Europe 1992 is implemented, and full cross-

border banking becomes a European reality, it is quite likely that the
European Community will find itself under pressure to make its deposit
insurance system more explicit and more uniform.
I noted earlier that one response of some U.S. banks to the more
intense competitive environment has been to draw down their capital
buffer

These and other institutions cannot rebuild, strengthen, and

maintain the appropriate level of capital unless they are able to adapt to
the changing competitive and technological environment

The ability to

adapt is crucially dependent on broadening the permissible range of
activities for banking organizations

At the same time, we should be

sensitive to the implications of the potential extension of the safety

- 23 -

net—directly or indirectly—under those markets that banking
organizations are authorized to enter
The Board has for some time held the view that strong insulating
firewalls would both protect banks (and taxpayers) from the risk of new
activities and limit the extension of the safety net subsidy that would
place independent competitors at a disadvantage

However, recent events,

including the rapid spread of market pressures to separately regulated and
well capitalized units of Drexel when their holding company was unable to
meet its maturing commercial paper obligations, have raised serious
questions about the ability of firewalls to insulate one unit of either a
holding company or a bank from funding problems of an affiliate or
subsidiary

Partially as a result, the Board is in the process of

reevaluating both the efficacy and desirability of substantial firewalls
between a bank and some of its affiliates or subsidiaries

It is clear

that high and thick firewalls reduce synergies and raise costs for
financial institutions, a significant problem in increasingly competitive
financial markets

If they raise costs and may not be effective, we must

question why we are imposing these kinds of firewalls at all.

Moreover,

higher capital standards and prompt corrective action at the bank go a
long way to limit the transference of the bank safety net subsidies to
bank affiliates or subsidiaries that firewalls are designed to constrain
And, as such, they should greatly limit the risk of distorted market
signals and excessive risk-taking over an expanded range of markets, as
well as the unfair competition, that might otherwise accompany wider
activities by banking organizations

- 24 -

It may be more realistic to apply more limited firewalls to the
new activities

I have in mind here restrictions such as sections 23A

and B of the Federal Reserve Act, which already limit the financial
transactions between a bank and its affiliates, requiring collateral,
arms-length transactions, and—except when Treasury securities are used as
collateral—quantitative limits based on the bank's capital

Such

limitations could also be applied to transactions between a bank and
certain bank subsidiaries
Even with these, or tighter firewalls, the potential for problems
in one unit of a firm to affect other units raises the question of the
implications of a piecemeal regulatory structure, with no means for
ensuring that the activities of the organization as a whole do not impose
undue risk on the insured entity and hence either the financial system or
the safety net

We believe that, in order to protect the insured entity,

the financial system, and the safety net, some agency should be
responsible for oversight of the entire organization
Authorization to use their expertise over a wider range of
markets might well be limited only to those organizations where the bank
or the holding company meets a new higher capital standard.

Consequently,

Congress might wish to authorize bank supervisors to grant certain of
these activities only to those entities that exceed such a standard.
Those institutions that consistently exceed the capital standard perhaps
could receive more flexibility in supervisory treatment

For example, a

notice requirement could be substituted for formal applications for
activities permitted by law and regulation, provided that such
acquisitions leave the bank or other appropriate entity's capital in

- 25 -

excess of the higher standards

Other reductions in regulatory burden for

highly capitalized banks or banking organizations might also be
appropriate.

Such organizations would, however, still be subject to the

same thorough annual examinations.
As you know, the Board has long supported repeal of the
provisions of the Glass-Steagall Act that separate commercial and
investment banking

We still strongly advocate such repeal because we

believe that technology and globalization have continued to blur the
distinctions among credit markets, and have eroded the franchise value of
the classic bank intermediation process.

Outdated constraints will only

endanger the profitability of banking organizations and their contribution
to the American economy

Beyond investment banking, the Board believes

that highly capitalized banking firms should be authorized to engage in a
wider range of financial activities as a part of the modernization of our
financial structure and the maintenance of strong, profitable financial
institutions that can compete in world markets.

A banking system that

cannot adapt to the changing competitive and technological environment
will no longer be able to attract and maintain the higher capital level
that some of our institutions need to operate without excessive reliance
on the safety net
Firms primarily engaged in the financial activities authorized to
banking organizations should likewise be permitted to operate an insured
bank

Congress, of course, will have to give careful consideration to how

to handle the activities some of these entities are already engaged in
that would not be permitted to banking organizations.

More generally, as

we expand the range of activities available to banks and their

- 26 -

subsidiaries or affiliates, competitive equity suggests the desirability
of functional regulation.

Under such an approach, each area of activity

should be subject to the same regulatory constraints as equivalent or very
similar functions at nonbank firms
As the Congress considers modernization of our banking structure
to meet the needs of the 21st century, it should not only widen the
permissible activities of well-capitalized banking organizations, but also
eliminate outdated statutes that only increase costs.

The McFadden Act

forces state member and national banks to deliver interstate services only
through separately capitalized bank holding company subsidiaries (where
permitted by state law) rather than through branches

Such a system

reduces the ability of many smaller banks to diversify geographically and
raises costs for all banking organizations that operate in more than one
state, a curious requirement as we search for ways to make banks more
competitive and profitable

The McFadden Act ought to be amended to

permit interstate branching by banks
In summary, events have made it clear that we ought not to permit
banks, because of their access to the safety net, to take excessive risk
with inadequate capital.

Even if we were to ignore the potential taxpayer

costs, we ought not to permit a system that is so inconsistent with
efficient market behavior

In the process of reform, however, we should

be certain we consider carefully the implications for macroeconomic
stability

The Board believes that higher capital and prompt corrective

action by supervisors to resolve problems will go a long way to eliminate
excessive risk-taking by insured institutions, and would not preclude
additional deposit insurance reform, now or later.

Moreover, we believe

- 27 -

that with such an approach the Congress should feel comfortable with
authorizing banking organizations to expand the scope of their financial
activities

Indeed, we believe that permitting wider activities is

necessary to ensure that such organizations can remain competitive both
here and abroad.

Increased activities are also required to sustain the

profitability needed if banking firms are to attract capital

To limit

the risks of safety net transference, some new activities might be made
available by banking regulators only to banks with impressive capital
positions

We believe that whatever the regulatory form and structure

under which new activities are permitted, one agency should have oversight
responsibility sufficient to protect the bank from excessive risks taken
in other parts of its broader organization

It is also our view that,

with these suggested reforms, reliance on stringent firewalls would not be
necessary

And the McFadden Act should be amended in order to permit

banks to deliver their services at the lowest possible costs and to more
easily diversify their geographic risks

The Board has shared its views

with the Treasury as part of our continuing consultations on these
matters, especially in the context of their FIRREA-mandated study
Finally, in considering all proposals, we should remind ourselves
that our objective is a strong and stable financial system that can
deliver the best services at the lowest cost and compete around the world
without taxpayer support

This requires the modernization of our

financial system and the weaning of some institutions from the unintended
benefits that accompany the safety net

Higher capital requirements may

well mean a relatively leaner and more efficient banking system, and they
will certainly mean one with reduced inclinations toward risk

However,

- 28 -

the Board believes our proposed reforms—including the authorization of
wider activities by banking organizations—will go a long way toward
ensuring a safer and more efficient financial system and lay the
groundwork for other modifications in the safety net in the years ahead

Appendix
Selected Characteristics of Household Account Holders
This appendix provides supporting material on the distribution of
household ownership of insured deposits The most recent reliable disaggregated
information available on the size and ownership of accounts comes from the 1983 Survey
of Consumer Finances (SCF) This survey consists of interviews with 4,103 U.S.
households drawn from two sampling frames a randomized geographic sample to provide
good coverage of broadly distributed characteristics, and a special sample of wealthy
households constructed from data at the Statistics of Income Division of the IRS to
provide better representation of more narrowly-distributed characteristics, such as
ownership of corporate stock Survey experts agree that the SCF provides very reliable
estimates of the distribution of financial characteristics The standard error due to
sampling error for a figure of ten percent estimated from the enure survey population
is about one-half percent
The 1983 SCF was sponsored by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, the Department of Health and Human Services, the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation, the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, the Federal Trade
Commission, the Department of Labor, and the Department of the Treasury Data were
collected through in-person interviews between February and August of 1983 under a
contract with the Survey Research Center at the University of Michigan
For the financial data collected in the survey, the unit of observation lies
between the standard Census Bureau definition of a "family" plus "single individuals"
and a "household" Generally, the survey excludes information only for individuals who
are not related by blood or marriage to the economically dominant core of the household.
Among other items, the survey gathered information on the amount of money held
in each of a household's accounts as well as the types of institutions where those
accounts were held. There are three important limitations in the survey data Fust,
there is no information on the ownership of deposits within the household Second, there
is no information on how many accounts households may have at a given institution.
Third, information on IRAs and Keoghs and CDs is more limited than for other deposits
For IRAs and Keoghs, the survey gathers only total holdings and the types of
institutions where these accounts are held For CDs, totals were gathered by term of

1 The survey is discussed in detail in an evaluation study "Measuring Wealth with Survey Data
An Evaluation of the 1983 Survey of Consumer Finances," by Robert B Avery, Gregory E
Elhehausen, and Arthur B Kenmckell, Review of Income and Wealth, December 1988

-2-

2

the certificate and no institution information was collected
There are a number of different account constructs that can be created for
evaluating the distribution of the coverage of household accounts by deposit insurance.
Two cases are considered here. In the first case, it is assumed that all accounts held
by a given household at a given type of institution are actually accounts owned by the
same person and that the accounts are held at the same institution This construct is
referred to below as the "synthetic account" definition In the second case, it is
assumed that all accounts are either owned by different household members or are held at
different financial institutions This measure is referred to below as me "individual
account" definition. The former construct will almost surely overstate the amount of
uninsured deposits, while the second may understate that number. Because of data
limitations noted below, the second construct is not quite a polar case
Synthetic Account Definition
In the synthetic account measure, accounts and institution are synonymous The
creation of this account proceeds in several steps. First, all checking, savings, and
money market deposit accounts are summed by the type of institution where the account
was held Second, IRA and Keogh accounts are allocated equally to each type of
institution where the accounts were held Finally, because no information is
available on the institutions where CDs were held, it is assumed that they were held at
the institution type that otherwise had the largest level of deposits
Table 1 presents information based on this account concept Households are

2. In the 1989 SCF, from which preliminary information is expected around the end of October,
more detailed institutional data were collected. In that survey, it will be possible to identify
accounts that are held by households at the same institution. In addition, the institutions
where certificates of deposit are held will be known. However, it will still not be possible to
disaggregate accounts by different owners within the household.
3 For example, suppose a household had four such accounts, one of $50,000 at a commercial bank,
one of $30,000 at a savings and loan, and two accounts of $20,000 (one belonging to the head of
the household and the other to his mother) at a credit union. In this case, the household would
then have synthetic accounts of $50,000 at a commercial bank, $30,000 at a savings and loan, and
$40,000 at a credit union
4 Continuing the example of the previous footnote, suppose the household has a total of $50,000
in IRA and Keogh accounts and that those accounts are held at commercial banks and savings and
loans Then $25,000 is attributed to bom the commercial bank and the savings and loan synthetic
accounts for a total of $75,000 in commercial banks, $55,000 in savings and loans, and $40,000 in
credit unions
5 Again, continuing the example, suppose the household has CDs totaling $125,000 ($110,000 m
short-term certificates and $15,000 in long-term certificates) Because the largest synthetic
account at this stage of aggregation is the commercial bank account, die entire amount of the CDs
is added to this account for a total of $200,000

-3-

6

classified in the columns by the largest of then* synthetic accounts As shown in
rows 1 and 2, only 2 6 percent (2 2 million) households are estimated to have an account
of $75,000 or more at an insured institution However, as shown by row 6, this same
group is estimated to hold 38 6 percent of all deposits owned by households. Even when
compared to the universe of deposits (computed as gross deposits from the June 1983 call
reports for the appropriate types of institutions), the same group is estimated to hold
14.5 percent of all deposits (row 7) This group is also estimated to hold 27.7
percent of insured household deposits (row 9) Note that the aggregation of accounts
will tend to understate die amount of insured deposits held by these groups
Data in rows 11 to 26 of table 1 provide other characteristics of the classes
of account holders The data indicate that households with an account of $75,000 or
more tend to have higher income, financial assets, and net wealth than the whole
population (shown in the last column) While they hold a substantial part of their
financial assets and net wealth in insured depository accounts, as a group they are also
much more likely than the general population to have diversified their holdings into
corporate stock, a business, or investment real estate The top two groups also tend to
be older and more likely to be retired
The groups with their largest accounts between $25,000 and $75,000 are more
like the top groups than like the group with accounts under $25,000 and the group with
no accounts The principal differences between the $25,000-$75,000 group and the top
two groups are the facts that their levels of financial assets and net worth are lower
Like the top two groups, they are more likely to be older and retired and to have a
diversified portfolio
Individual Account Definition
In the individual account definition, each reported account is treated
separately so far as the data allow Each checking, savings, and money market deposit
account is counted as a separate account for purposes of deposit insurance coverage
As before, IRAs and Keoghs are divided equally by the number of types of institutions

6 In the example, the household would be included in the column "^100K" because its largest
synthetic account (the commercial banks account) is $200,000
7 The call report is a regular report of balance sheet, income, and other data made by
depository institutions to the regulatory agencies
8 "Insured deposits" includes only the part of accounts that is $100,000 or less In the
example, the household has total deposits at insured institutions of $295,000 of which $195,000
($55,000 in savings and loans, $40,000 in credit unions, and the first $100,000 of the $200,000
in commercial banks) would be insured deposits
9 For example, assuming the same household-level data as in the example beginning in
footnote 3, the household would have four accounts, one of $50,000 at a commercial bank, one of
$30,000 at a savings and loan, and two of $20,000 each at a credit union

-A-

10

where such accounts were held
Finally, long-term and short-term CDs are allocated to
the type of institution where the household otherwise had its largest account
Note
that this definition does Dot constitute the opposite of the synthetic account
definition since there is still some aggregation of accounts in the treatment of the IRA
and Keogh accounts and the CDs
Table 2 presents estimates using this second definition that are comparable in
structure to the estimates reported in table 1 As would be expected, there is an
overall shift of households away from the top groups compared to table 1. By the
individual account definition, 1 4 percent (11 million) of all households have accounts
of $75,000 or more (rows 1 and 2) Correspondingly, the estimated amount of insured
deposits increases to $865 9 billion (row 8)
While there is some shifting of the
characteristics reported in the bottom two blocks of the table, the overall picture is
very similar to that in table 1
Estimated Household Share of Insured and Uninsured Deposits
Table 3 gives the estimated coverage of deposit insurance for the current and
lower hypothetical ceilings on insurance coverage for each of the two account
definitions. According to the synthetic account measure (which provides the greatest
understatement of the amount of insured deposits), at the current ceiling of $100,000,
84 8 percent of total household accounts are estimated to have been covered in 1983 If
the ceiling were dropped to $50,000, it is estimated that 72 3 percent would still have
been covered By the individual account measure, the percent of household deposits
insured at the current ceiling rises to 91 3 percent
Household accounts represent only a part of insured deposits. As noted in the
last column in row 7 of either of the first two tables, roughly 37.6 percent of total
deposits was held by households in 1983 According to call report data tabulated in the
1988 Annual Report of the FDIC, in 1983 deposits of $1,268 billion out of $1,691 billion
(75.0 percent) at commercial banks were insured
The proportion of insured deposits
was 75.1 percent in 1988. However, this is a limited definition of insured deposits
The underlying data contain no information on either multiple accounts at one
10 Thus, in the example, the household would now have six accounts, including the four described
in the last footnote and two additional accounts of $25,000 each
11 In the example, the household would now have eight accounts, the two additional accounts
being one of $110,000 and one of $15,000 and both held at commercial banks
12 In the example, the household has $295,000 of deposits at insured institutions as before, of
which $285,000 would be insured (the sum of (he initial $50,000 account at a commercial bank,
$30,000 at a savings and loan, two accounts of $20,000 at a credit union, two accounts of $25,000
each at a commercial bank and a savmgs and loan, one CD of $15,000 at a commercial bank, and the
first $100,000 of the $110,000 CD at a commercial bank)
13 The total of insured deposits is the sum of all accounts of $ 100,000 and under and $ 100,000
for each account of more than $100,000

-5-

institution or pass-through accounts, and thus, on net may overstate the amount of
insured deposits Using the closest possible survey definition, the individual account
definition of table 2, the data suggest that $63 6 billion (not shown in the tables), or
15 0 percent of the FDIC's estimate of uninsured deposits at commercial banks, may
belong to households.
However, this estimate is rather rough The figure may tend to
overstate the true amount of uninsured household deposits by the limited FDIC definition
because of the aggregation of IRAs and Keoghs and CDs, but may also tend to understate
the true figure because of underreporting in the survey

14 Call report data are not available for the calculation of the household share of potentially
uninsured deposits for hypothetical lower insurance ceilings

Table 1
Selected Characteristics of Household Account Holders
By Size of Largest Synthetic Account at an Insured Institution
1983 Survey of Consumer Finances

Item

Size of largest synthetic account at an insured institution
$25K-50K $50K-75K $75K-100K >$100K
No account $1-25K
44
65 1
1 Num. of h'holds in grp ($mil.) 10.3
1.9
09
1.3
52
77 6
2 % of all h'holds in group
23
1.1
1.5
12 3
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10

90 8

67

29

14

2.0

103.8

298.9

165 1

810

246

57 9

285 6
142 8

948 8

33

1182
40 8

31.5
119

174
65

125
4.7

85
32

301
113

1000
37.6

298.9

165 1

118.2

810

141.6

804.8

37 1

20.5

14 7

101

17.6

100 0

00

00

00

00

144 0

144 0

7.1

210

30 0

28 8

32 4

49 0

19 5

assets ($ thou.)
00
Median % of h'hold financial
0.0
assets in insured accounts
Median h'hold net worth ($ thou.) 1.0
Median % of h'hold net worth
in insured institutions
0.0
% of h'holds owning stocks/bonds 1.4
% of h'holds owning business
22
% of h'holds owning real estate
other than prin residence
5.6

2.6

42.6

76 1

100 5

234.0

24

100.0
34.6

96.2
134.7

88.0
183 7

91.9
193.3

914

991

457.1

34.3

63
21.0
14 3

26.3
45.0
29.2

34 0
57 9
19.1

47 1
56 3
34.3

40.3
59.6
36.1

56

21.6
14.2

18 7

34.2

37 1

28 2

42 8

18 8

42

42

60

65

65

65

44

10

12

12

13

12

15

12

27.3
28 9

16 0
88

33 1
63

405

10 6

43 5
14 3

47.6
5.2

19.6
11 1

56

27 6

36 1

26.7

210

34 6

25 4

37 6

46 3

216

13

100.0

29
100 0

80
46

100 0

20 0
12
100 0

42 4

0.6

18 2
40
100 0

100 0

1000

00
# of acc'ts held by group (mil.)
Amount of deposits held by
0.0
group ($ bil.)
Mean account size ($ thou)
00
% of all household deposits
held by group
00
% of all deposits held by group 00
Amount of insured deposits held
00
by group ($ bil.)
% of all insured h'hold
0.0
deposits held by group
Amount of uninsured deposits
00
held by group ($ bil)

11 Median h'hold income ($ thou)
12 Median h'hold financial
13

14
15
16
17
18

19 Median age of head of h'hold
20 Median years of education

21
22
23
24
25
26

All h'holds
83.9
1000

of head of h'hold
% of group with head of h'hold
in various occupations
Retired
Other not working
Professionals, managers,
administrators
Sales, clerical, craftsmen,
laborers, military
Farmers
All occupations

91

15

Table 2
Selected Characteristics of Household Account Holders
By Size of Largest Individual Account at an Insured Institution
1983 Survey of Consumer Finances
Item
1
2

Size of largest individual account at an insured institution
$50K-75K $75K-100K>$100K
$25K-50K
No account
$1-25K
Num of h'holds in grp ($mil) 10 3
67 4
1.3
0.8
3.8
0.3
10
12.3
45
1.5
04
% of all h'holds in group
80 3

All h'holds
83.9
100.0

00

194.5

17 5

63

15

43

224 1

00
00

379 2
19

197 9
113

109 8
17.4

409

2210

27 3

514

948 8
42

00
00

40 0
15 0

20 8
78

11.6
44

43
16

23 3
88

100 0
37 6

00

379 2

197 9

109 8

40 9

138 1

865 9

0.0

43 8

22 9

12.7

47

15 9

100 0

00

0.0

00

0.0

00

82 9

82.9

11 Median h'hold income ($ thou) 7.1
12 Median h'hold financial
00
assets ($ thou )
13 Median % of h'hold financial
00
assets in insured accounts
14 Median h'hold net worth ($ thou ) 1.0
15 Median % of h'hold net worth
in insured institutions
0.0
16 % of h'holds owning stocks/bonds 1.4
22
17 % of h'holds owning business
18 % of h'holds owning real estate
other than prin residence
56

21 1

26 8

313

38 0

50.4

19 5

28

62.2

1013

214 7

2518

24

100 0
36.5

92.6
167.0

89 8
198 4

65.2
285.3

93 8
457.1

991
34.3

6.6
216
14 9

28.7
54.2
24.4

44.2
50.7
29.1

36 6
66.7
34.7

45 9
60.1
30.4

5.6
21.6
14.2

19 1

37.1

37.1

31.9

40.0

18 8

43

64

65

65

65

44

12

12

12

14

16

12

16 2
8.6

42 9
10.1

42 3
10 8

35 6
113

54 4
3.6

19 6
11 1

28 1

27 6

29 8

22.4

32 2

25 4

45.7
1.4
100 0

16 0
34
100 0

12 5
46
100 0

27 4
33
100.0

75
23
100 0

42.4
1.5
100.0

3
4

# of acc'ts held by group (mil)
Amount of deposits held by
group ($ bil.)
5 Mean account size ($ thou )
6 % of all household deposits
held by group
7 % of all deposits held by group
8 Amount of insured deposits held
by group ($ bil)
9 % of all insured h'hold
deposits held by group
10 Amount of uninsured deposits
held by group ($ bil)

42
19 Median age of head of h'hold
20 Median years of education
of head of h'hold
10
% of group with head of h'hold
in various occupations
21
Retired
27.3
22
Other not working
28 9
23
Professionals, managers,
administrators
56
24
Sales, clerical, craftsmen,
37 6
laborers, military
25
Farmers
06
26
All occupations
100 0

Table 3
Estimated Percent of Household Deposits Covered by Deposit Insurance
Various Hypothetical Deposit Insurance Ceilings
Synthetic Account Definition and Individual Accounts Definition
Account definition

Hypothetical deposit insurance ceiling
$50K
$25K
$75K
$100K

Synthetic accounts

56 5

72 3

80 3

84.8

Individual accounts

713

83 5

88 2

913