View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:00 P.M. CDT
(2:00 P.M. EDT)
April 16, 1999

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Dallas Ambassadors Forum
Dallas, Texas
April 16, 1999

Technology and Trade
I am pleased to be able to join the City of Dallas and the Greater Dallas Chamber for this
annual series of events to introduce a delegation of more than twenty foreign ambassadors to the
region's economy and the important role international trade plays in it. I am happy, too, to be
among the beneficiaries of a characteristically Texas-sized welcome. We will all go home as
ambassadors for Dallas; no doubt a thought that occurred to the organizers of the first
Ambassadors Forum nineteen years ago.
In the almost two decades since the forward-looking community leaders of Dallas
envisioned the benefits of describing the city a center for international commerce, much of the
nation and many around the globe have caught up to you. In the relatively brief span of years
since the first Ambassadors Forum, our understanding of the important role of global trade and
finance to our own economic well being has changed dramatically. Today, I would like to speak
to you about one aspect of that change.
One of the most impressive and persistent trends of the last half century is the expansion
of international trade. Adjusted for price change, trade across national borders has increased
fourteenfold—far faster than the fivefold increase in world GDP.
The evidence is overwhelmingly persuasive that the massive increase in world
competition—a consequence of broadening trade flows—has fostered markedly higher
standards of living for almost all countries who have participated in cross-border trade. I
include most especially the United States.
Although many forces have been at play, this surge in competitive trade has clearly
owed, in large part, to significant advances in technological innovation.
Since the dawn of the industrial revolution, there has been an inexorable drive to
leverage physical brawn and material resources into ever greater value added or output. New

insights into the laws of nature brought steam and later electric power. The development of a
production quality level that facilitated interchangeable parts brought assembly line production.
And the development of railroads facilitated the evolution of mass markets.
Almost all of the leverage of the physical to higher value added has reflected the
substitution of ideas—new insights—for material bulk and brute human effort.
The resulting more effective organization of material has, of course, inevitably meant
that less of it was needed per unit of output. The insights of metallurgy and architectural and
engineering design, for example, enabled the construction of buildings that use far less physical
material per unit of space than say, a half century ago. The insights that led to central heating,
as well as synthetic fiber, facilitated reduced clothing weight, while the advent of the jet engine
brought far greater annual passenger miles per unit of aircraft size.
But doubtless it has been the advent in recent decades of the synergies of the
microprocessor, lasers, and fiber optics that has fostered a distinct quickening in the
displacement of physical weight of output with concepts. The ability to miniaturize transistor
electronic circuits has displaced huge tonnages of copper and enhanced the speed of calculation
that the miniaturization of circuitry facilitated.
As microprocessors became an increasing part of our national product the relative
physical dimensions of our value added fell dramatically. The physical weight of our gross
domestic product is evidently only modestly higher today than it was fifty or one hundred years
ago.
By far the largest contributor to growth of our price adjusted GDP, or value added, has
been ideas—insights that leveraged physical reality. The consequent downsizing of output, of
course, meant that products were easier, and hence less costly, to move, and most especially
across national borders.

It is thus not surprising that the price adjusted level of international trade, as I indicated
earlier, has expanded at a far faster pace than gains in real domestic demand. Imports of goods
and services as a percent of gross domestic products worldwide, on average, have risen from
approximately 14 percent twenty-five years ago to 24 percent today.
The growth in physical weight of such trade, as with the national product generally, has
been far less. For example, United States data on both exports and imports indicates that the
price adjusted value of our trade per pound has risen by approximately 4 percent per year on
average over those same three decades.
But technology has augmented international trade for reasons beyond the downsizing of
material output. New telecommunications technologies made it very difficult for the autarchic
societies of the former Soviet Union to sustain their isolation in the face of the growing relative
affluence of the West. News could no longer be bottled up. Even in the West, the stultification
of protectionism became increasingly evident as new consumer products entered the world
markets en masse. The political pressures to deregulate moribund industries and open up
borders to trade soon became irresistible. The international trading system that evolved has
enhanced competition and nurtured what Joseph Schumpeter a number of decades ago called
"creative destruction," the continuous scrapping of old technologies to make way for the new.
Standards of living rise because the depreciation and other cash flows of industries employing
older, increasingly obsolescent, technologies are marshaled to finance the newly produced
capital assets that almost always embody the cutting edge technologies. This is the process by
which wealth is created incremental step by incremental step. It presupposes a continuous
churning of an economy in which the new displaces the old.
But there is also no doubt that this transition to the new high-tech economy, of which
rising trade is a part, is proving difficult for a large segment of our workforce that interfaces

with our rapidly changing capital stock day by day. This is most evident in the rising fear of job
skill obsolescence that has induced a marked increase in experienced workers going back to
school—often community colleges—to upgrade their skills for a rapidly changing work
environment. The proportion of all college enrollees over age thirty-five rose from less than
9 percent of total students in 1972 to 18 percent in 1997, and probably still higher today. The
demand for on-the-job training has also understandably expanded substantially.
While major advances in standards of living are evident among virtually all nations that
have opened their borders to increased competition, the adjustment trauma has also distressed
those who once thrived in industries that were then at the cutting edge of technology, but which
have since become increasingly noncompetitive. Economists will say that workers should move
from the steel districts of western Pennsylvania to a vibrant Silicon Valley. And eventually they,
or more likely, their children, will. But the adjustment process is wrenching to an existing
workforce made redundant largely through no fault of their own. It may be argued that all
workers should have the foresight to recognize long-term job opportunity shifts and move in
advance of obsolescence. This regrettably is a skill not in great abundance—among business
managers or the economists who counsel them as well as among workers.
Yet the protectionist propensity to thwart the process of the competitive flow of capital,
from failing technologies to the more productive, is unwise and surely self-defeating. History
tells us that not only is it unwise to try to hold back innovations, it is also not possible over the
longer run. Generation after generation has experienced episodes in which the technologically
obsolescent endeavored to undermine progress, often appealing to the very real short-term costs
of adjusting to a changing economic environment. From the Luddites to the Smoots and the
Hawleys, competitive forces were under attack. In the end they did not prevail and long-term
advances in standards of living resumed.

Indeed, we have an example here in Dallas-Fort Worth of the benefits of trade and
investment sparked by the North American Free Trade Agreement. In some interesting research
done at the Dallas Fed, it was estimated that import and export growth with Mexico is over
16 percent higher per year owing specifically to the effects of NAFTA. Consumers in both
Mexico and the United States have a wider array of less expensive goods and services available
and, hence, higher standards of living.
Nonetheless, the campaign to expand free trade is never won. It is a continuing battle.
While tariffs in industrial countries have come down sharply over the past half century, other
barriers have become more prevalent. Administrative protection in the form of antidumping
suits and countervailing duties is a case in point. While these forms of protection have often
been imposed under the label of promoting "fair trade," oftentimes they are just simple guises for
inhibiting competition. Typically, antidumping duties are levied when foreign average prices
are below average cost of production. But that also describes a practice that often emerges as a
wholly appropriate response to a softening in demand. It is the rare case that prices fall below
marginal cost, which would be a more relevant standard. Antidumping initiatives should be
reserved, in the view of many economists, for those cases where anticompetitive behavior is
involved. Contrary to popular notions about antidumping suits, under U.S. and WTO law, it is
not required to show evidence of predatory behavior, or intention to monopolize, or of any other
intentional efforts to drive competitors out of business.
In the end it is clear that all economic progress rests on competition. It would be a great
tragedy were we to stop the wheels of progress because of an incapacity to assist the victims of
progress.
Our efforts should be directed at job skills enhancement and retraining—a process in
which the private market is already engaged. Thwarting competition, by placing barriers to

imports, will prevent the needed transitions of the productive capital stock of the United States
and other nations that enable it to continuously concentrate on producing those goods and
services most desired by consumers.
Protectionism will also slow the inevitable transition of the workforce to more productive
endeavors. To be sure, an added few years may enable some workers to reach retirement with
dignity, but it will also keep frozen in place younger workers whose better job opportunities
decline with time.
I regret that trade policy has been inextricably linked with job creation. We try to
promote free trade on the mistaken ground that it will create jobs. The reason should be that it
enhances standards of living through the effects of competition on productivity.
It is difficult to find credible evidence that trade has impacted the level of total
employment in this country over the long run. Indeed, we are currently experiencing the widest
trade deficit in history with a level of unemployment close to record lows.
Certainly, the distribution of jobs by industry is affected by international trade, but it is
also affected by domestic trade. It is the relative balance of supply and demand in a competitive
market economy that determines the mix of employment. When exports fall or imports rise,
domestic demand and relative prices have invariably adjusted in the long run to leave total
employment relatively unaffected. As economists like to say, all imports are eventually paid for
with exports.
I also regret that, despite the remarkable success over a near half century of GATT, the
General Agreement on Trade and Tariffs, and its successor, the World Trade Organization, in
reducing trade barriers, our trade laws and negotiating practices are essentially adversarial. They
presume that a trade concession extracted from us by our trading partners is to their advantage at
our expense, and must be countered.

Few economists see the world that way. And I am rash enough to suggest that we
economists are correct, at least in this regard: trade is not a zero sum game.
If trade barriers are lowered by both parties, each clearly benefits. But if one lowers
barriers and the other does not, the country that lowered barriers unilaterally would still be better
off having done so. Raising barriers to achieve protectionist equality with reluctant trading
partners would be neither to our benefit, nor to theirs. The best of all possible worlds for
competition is for both parties to lower trade barriers. The worst is for both to keep them up.
For these reasons, I am concerned about the recent evident weakening of support for free
trade in this country. Should we endeavor to freeze competitive progress in place, we will
almost certainly slow economic growth overall, and impart substantial harm to those workers
who would otherwise seek more effective longer-term job opportunities. Protecting markets
from new technologies has never succeeded. Adjustments to newer technologies have been
delayed, but only at significant cost.
Even should our trading partners not retaliate in the face of increased American trade
barriers, an unlikely event, we do ourselves great harm by lessening the vigor of American
competitiveness. The United States has been in the forefront of the postwar opening up of
international markets, much to our, and the rest of the world's, benefit.
It would be a great tragedy were that process reversed.