View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

%

For release on delivery
9:30 A.M., E.S.T.
March 15, 1988

Statement by

Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Joint Economic Committee

March 15, 1988

I am pleased to appear before this Committee to
discuss the current economic situation and the outlook for
1988.

As you know, the Federal Reserve submitted its semi-

annual report on monetary policy to the Congress about three
weeks ago.

That report and the accompanying testimony

discussed in some detail the monetary policy developments of
1987 and the FOMC's policy targets for 1988.

Today, I would

like to summarize briefly the main points of those reports
and then turn to some more general considerations,
particularly the process of external adjustment that is now
underway and the challenge that it poses to our economy.
The overall record shows 1987 to have been another
year of significant economic progress.

Real gross national

product rose nearly 4 percent over the course of the year,
job growth totaled 3 million, and the unemployment rate

-

2

-

declined to 5-3/4 percent, its lowest level of the current
decade.
Some sectors that had lagged earlier in the recovery
exhibited particular strength last year.

Buoyed by rising

exports and a pickup in capital spending, industrial
production in manufacturing surged 5-1/2 percent over the
twelve months of 1987, and capacity utilization rose to its
highest level in nearly eight years.

Capacity use in the

steel business was about 90 percent at the end of 1987, up
from 65 percent a year earlier.

Improvement also was

evident in mining, oil extraction, and agriculture.
The year, however, was not without its setbacks.
Inflation, which had dropped sharply in 1986, increased in
1987, owing to the bounce-back in oil prices and to the

effects of the dollar's decline on prices of imported goods
and their domestic substitutes.

Concerns that these one-

time price changes might trigger a more pronounced and more

- 3 -

deeply-rooted upswing in inflation persisted through late

summer, surfacing, at one time or another, in the form of
upward pressures on commodity prices or rising long-term

interest rates.

Under these conditions, further declines in

the exchange value of the dollar added to the general
uncertainty regarding longer-run price prospects.
For much of the year, Federal Reserve policy leaned

in the direction of countering potential inflationary
tendencies in the economy, while seeking to maintain a
monetary and financial environment compatible with

sustainable growth.

The discount rate was raised on one

occasion, and growth in M2 ran lower than the target range
that the Federal Open Market Committee had established early
in the year.

In view of the very rapid money growth of

1986, the perceived inflation risks, the strength in the

real economy and the marked variations in money velocity in

-

4

-

recent years, modest growth of the monetary aggregates was

viewed as acceptable and appropriate.
The stock market crash of late October shifted the
balance of risks, and the Federal Reserve modified its

approach to monetary policy accordingly.

In particular, we

took steps to ensure adequate liquidity in the financial
system during the period of serious turmoil, and we

encouraged some decline in short-term interest rates as a
precaution against the possibility of a significant

retrenchment by households and businesses.

While some uneasiness still is apparent in the
financial markets, the situation has calmed considerably
since October.

Interest rates have come down noticeably,

and exchange rate pressures have moderated.

In the real

economy a buildup in business inventories late last year,

coupled with the possibility that effects of the stock

market crash might still be working through, suggested at

the turn of the year that the growth of real GNP might slow
in the first part of 1988.

However, employment has

continued to advance early this year, and, at present, deep
or prolonged cutbacks in production do not seem likely.
Consumer spending seems to be holding its own, export
prospects remain favorable, and capital goods orders have
been strong.

Overall, the chances appear relatively good

for maintaining the current expansion through another year.
As of mid-February, the central tendency of FOMC members'
and other Reserve Bank presidents' forecasts was for growth
of real GNP of around 2 to 2-1/2 percent from the fourth
quarter of 1987 to the fourth quarter of 1988; this is a
slower rate of growth than in 1987, but is probably close to
what the economy can maintain on a long-run basis.

Exports

seem likely to provide a major impetus for growth in 1988,
while the growth in domestic demand may be relatively slow.

-

6

-

With respect to inflation, price increases have
picked up in some markets this past year.

However, in

general, business and labor still seem to be exercising a
considerable degree of restraint in their wage and pricesetting behavior, and bottlenecks are not a serious problem
at the present time.

Should the FOMC's forecasts of

moderate growth of real GNP over the coming year be
realized, this situation is not likely to change much.

The

FOMC central tendency forecast was for a rise in prices, as
measured by the GNP deflator, of about 3-1/4 to 3-3/4
percent in 1988—similar to the inflation performance in
most recent years.
The central tendency of our projections for real
GNP growth encompasses the Administration forecast that you
are reviewing today; the central tendency range for
inflation is slightly below the Administration forecast, but
the difference is not significant.

- 7 -

In formulating its policy objectives for 1988, the
Federal Open Market Committee, at its mid-February meeting,
established monetary target ranges of 4 to 8 percent for

both M2 and M3 over the four quarters of 1988.

Expansion of

money within these ranges is expected to support continued
economic growth at a pace that is consistent with progress

over time toward price stability.

In recent years, of

course, the relation of money to income has not been very
stable.

Accordingly, as the coming year unfolds, we will

continue to keep a close eye not only on the behavior of the
aggregates, but also on the overall performance of the
economy.

Although the near-term prospects thus look
reasonably encouraging, major uncertainties remain and we

should not be complacent about the nation's economic future.

To a considerable extent, we still are sailing in uncharted

waters and are facing adjustments that have no precedent in

-

our recent history.

8

-

A couple of decades ago, we still

viewed our economy as being relatively self-contained.

We

thought of business cycles largely in terms of domestic

spending, inventories and production; foreign trade did not

play a major role.

Businesses saw their competition as

being the firm down the road or in the next city or state,

not the producer on the other side of the world.

We

recognized, of course, that American economic activity and
policies materially affected the rest of the world.

Developments outside our borders, however, appeared to have
little impact on economic activity in this country.
This has all changed in recent years.

Our economy

today is being driven by external forces and is coming to
resemble more nearly the open, trade-based economies of

Europe than the insulated economy of our own past.

We are

increasingly affected by developments outside our borders

and need to learn to do business there.

Despite the

attendant complications, our own policies are going to have
to be shaped with close surveillance of what is happening in
the rest of the world.
Particularly striking evidence of a changed
economic climate was the deterioration of our external
balance over the first half of the 1980s, a period in which
import growth far outpaced the rise in exports.

The causes

of this imbalance were complex, but its effects on consumers
and businesses were relatively clear.

Consumers benefitted

from having access to a broad range of good-quality imports,
while the producing sectors that are heavily affected by
foreign trade suffered a loss of market share, both
domestically and worldwide.

In manufacturing, which

accounts for nearly two-thirds of our exports, production
was sluggish, layoffs mounted, and pressures for
protectionism rose.

Agriculture also suffered as the export

boom of the 1970s turned into the export bust of the 1980s.

-

10

-

Overall, from mid-1980 to the summer of 1986, real net
exports of goods and services fell by an amount equal to 6
percent of real GNP.
Fortunately, this situation has started to change.
In volume terms, our external sector has been improving and
accounted for nearly half a percentage point of GNP growth
over the four quarters of 1987.

As I noted earlier,

manufacturing growth was especially robust last year, and
the current backlog of orders suggests that factory output
should be well-maintained over the near-term.
However, just as the deterioration of our external
account created serious dislocations for the domestic
economy in recent years, the swing back toward better
balance also may create difficulties, though of a different
nature.

These adjustments—and the way that we deal with

t h e m — w i l l go far toward shaping the economic outlook for a
number of years to come.

-

11

-

Let me illustrate by drawing some comparisons
between the current situation and other episodes from our
recent economic history.

When real exports bottomed out in

the summer of 1986, the nation's total spending for goods
and services, including inventory investment, exceeded the
comparable domestic production of goods and services by
about 4-1/4 percent, a gap unprecedented for the postwar
period.

By comparison, production and spending were closely

matched throughout much of the 1950s and 1960s; and even in
the more volatile decade of the 1970s, spending did not
depart from production by more than a couple of percentage
points.
Those smaller gaps of the 1970s eventually closed,
largely because of growth in the volume of exports.

But the

transitions back toward external balance were not smooth,
either in the early part of the decade or in the late 1970s.
Rather, the transitions were marked by strongly competing

-

12

-

demands on domestic resources, an overheating of product
markets, and widespread inflationary pressures.
Of course, history does not have to repeat itself, and
in harkening back to these past episodes, I do not mean to
suggest that the economy will inevitably follow a similar
path in the years immediately ahead.

Indeed, the world is

more competitive than it was 10 or 15 years ago, and
recognition by business and labor of the need to stay
competitive may help to quell whatever latent inflationary
tendencies arise 1
What is clear is that a major adjustment is underway.
As part of the move back toward external balance, export
growth could place stronger demands on a domestic resource
base that already is operating at high levels of utilization
in some areas.

To date, lead times in the deliveries of

production materials remain moderate, implying for the
moment little pressure from capacity restraints.

Never-

- 13 -

theless, our experience from the 1970s, when smaller
external adjustments took place, should make us cautious
about thinking that this adjustment can be accomplished
without some upward pressures on prices.

Ideally, one can

conceive of a strengthening of exports meshing neatly with a
slowing of domestic spending in such a way as to maintain
utilization levels for labor and capital without
overheating.

Certainly, if, as I noted earlier, growth is

moderate in the period ahead, bottlenecks should not be a
serious problem.

Realistically, however, one has to

recognize that events in the real world may not mesh as
neatly as contemplated and that the adjustment may not
proceed as smoothly as we would like.
Although the exact path of adjustment cannot be
predicted with precision, we know that there are a number of
actions that can be taken to help make the process smoother
than would otherwise be the case.

- 14 -

Monetary policy needs to remain supportive of the
expansion but also alert to the possibility of a reemergence of inflation.

Policymakers must be especially

mindful that the cost of temporizing in the face of
accumulating price pressures would be a far more serious and
painful adjustment down the road.
After several years of debate, Congress is
understandably tired of wrestling with the budget deficit
issue.

The temptation is great to lay it aside for a year

or permit small retreats from the real progress that has
been achieved to date.

However, there are risks in delaying

or retreating, even a little, on an issue of such great
importance.

It is urgent that the Congress fully implement

the deficit-reduction measures agreed to in December and
continue to consider additional measures that might be taken
to lock in further progress in the outyears.

As part of the coming adjustment, this nation must
find ways of generating sufficient domestic saving to
finance investment and maintain the productivity gains that
are needed to keep us competitive in world markets.

Over

the course of the expansion, the adverse implications of a
low domestic saving rate have been temporarily obscured, as
a large inflow of capital from abroad has made it possible
to finance a large federal deficit and a high level of
consumption and investment spending without undue pressures
on the credit markets.

However, there are limits to how

long a country can depend upon savings from abroad, and at
some point we will have to revert to financing our future
from our own resources.

Indeed, the pressures experienced

in the foreign exchange and financial markets last year
suggest that those limits are closer than they were before.
Nor can we count on a major pickup in private
saving.

We have endeavored in recent decades to implement

-

16

-

tax policies to augment household and business saving;
however, these policies have not been demonstrably
successful.

Accordingly, it will become doubly important

for the federal government to reduce its demands on the
credit markets by cutting the budget deficit.

Indeed, as I

have suggested previously, we may have to consider at some
point whether the nation's inability to boost private saving
argues for a federal budget policy aimed at generating
surpluses.
Foreign governments also must play a part, if the
adjustment process is to work smoothly in the context of a
growing world economy.

During most of this expansion, the

purchases of goods by U.S. businesses and households have
provided a strong impetus for production gains abroad.
that process must work in reverse.

Now

Other countries need to

promote growth in their economies, reduce trade barriers,
and in general ensure receptive markets for exports from the

- 17 -

United States and elsewhere. The chances of attaining access
to markets abroad would be damaged, of course, if the United
States itself were to embrace greater protectionism, a
temptation that I earnestly hope we will avoid.
Let me conclude, Mr. Chairman, by saying that I
view the outlook as satisfactory, but not without risks.
Our economy was dealt a potentially severe shock last
October, and at present, we seem to be weathering that shock
perhaps better than might have been expected.

Looking

ahead, we know that the economy will be heavily influenced
by the ongoing correction of fundamental internal and
external imbalances.

However, the broad contours of the

coming adjustment are relatively clear and should not come
to us as a surprise.

Although our place in the world is

changing, the future can be prosperous if we remain

-

18

-

attentive to the course of events and take those actions

that we know are needed.