View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10 00 A M , E S T
February 2, 1989

Statement by

Alan Greenspan

Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Committee on Ways and Means

U S

House of Representatives

February 2, 1989

Mr. Chairman and other members of the Ways and Means Committee,
I am pleased to be here today to discuss corporate restructuring and the
need for reducing the federal budget deficit, issues raised in your
letter of invitation
Corporate Restructuring and Leveraging
The spate of mergers, acquisitions, leveraged buyouts, share
repurchases, and divestitures in recent years has major implications for
the American economy.

While the evidence suggests that the

restructurings of the 1980s probably are improving, on balance, the
efficiency of our economy, the worrisome and possibly excessive degree
of leveraging associated with this process could create a set of new
problems for the financial system
Corporate restructuring is not new to American business

It

has long been a feature of our enterprise system, a means by which firms
adjust to ever-changing product and resource markets, and to perceived
opportunities for gains from changes in management and management
strategies
However, the 1980s have been characterized by features not
present in previous episodes.

The recent period has been marked not

only by acquisitions and mergers, but also by significant increases in
leveraged buyouts, divestitures, asset sales, and share repurchase
programs

In many cases, recent activity reflects the break-up of the

big conglomerate deals packaged in the 1960s and 1970s

Also, the

recent period has been characterized by the retirement of substantial
amounts of equity (more than $500 billion since 1983) mostly financed by
borrowing in the credit markets

-2-

The accompanying increase in debt has resulted in an
appreciable rise in leverage ratios for many of our large corporations.
Aggregate book value debt-equity ratios, based on balance sheet data for
nonfinancial firms, have increased sharply in the 1980s, moving outside
their range in recent decades, although measures based on market values
have risen more modestly
Along with this debt expansion, the ability of firms in the
aggregate to cover interest payments has deteriorated.

The ratio of

gross interest payments to corporate cash flow before interest provision
is currently around 35 percent, close to the 1982 peak when interest
rates were much higher and profits were weak owing to the recession
Lately, profits have been fairly buoyant, the current deterioration has
been due to heavier debt burdens.
A measure of credit quality erosion is suggested by an
unusually large number of downgradings of corporate bonds in recent
years.

The average bond rating of a large sample of firms has declined

fairly significantly since the late 1970s, from A+ to A-.
To fashion an appropriate policy response, if any, to this
extraordinary restructuring/LBO phenomenon, there are some key questions
that must be answered*
movement?

What is behind the corporate restructuring

Why is it occurring now, in the middle and late 1980s, rather

than in some earlier time?
of corporate balance sheets?

Why has it involved such a broad leveraging
And finally, has it been good or bad for

the American economy?
The 1980s has been a period of dramatic economic changes
swings in the exchange value of the dollar, with substantial

large

-3-

consequences for trade-dependent industries; rapid technological
progress, especially in automation and telecommunications; rapid growth
in the service sector; and large movements in real interest rates and
relative prices

Clearly, such changes in the economic environment

imply major, perhaps unprecedented, shifts in the optimal mix of assets
at firms—owing to corresponding shifts in synergies—and new
opportunities for improving efficiency

Some activities need to be shed

or curtailed, and others added or beefed up

Moreover, the long period

of slow productivity growth in the 1970s may have partly exacerbated the
buildup of a backlog of inefficient corporate practices
When assets become misaligned or less than optimally managed,
there is clearly an increasing opportunity to create economic value by
restructuring companies, restoring what markets perceive as a more
optimal mix of assets

But restructuring requires corporate control

And managers, unfortunately, often have been slow in reacting to changes
in their external environment, some more so than others.

Hence, it

shouldn't be a surprise that, in recent years, unaffiliated corporate
restructurers, some call them corporate raiders, have significantly bid
up the control premiums over the passive investment value of companies
that are perceived to have suboptimal asset allocations

If a company

has an optimal mix and is appropriately managed, there is no economic
value to be gained from restructuring and, hence, no advantage in
obtaining control of a company for such purposes

In that case, there

is no incentive to bid up the stock price above the passive investment
value based on its existing, presumed optimal, mix of assets

But in an

economy knocked partially off kilter by real interest rate increases and

-4-

gyrations in foreign exchange and commodity prices, there emerge
significant opportunities for value-creating restructuring at many
companies
This presumably explains why common stock tender offer prices
of potential candidates for restructuring have risen significantly
during the past decade

Observed stock prices generally (though not

always) reflect values of shares as passive investments

But there can

be, for any individual company, two or more prices for its shares,
reflecting the degree of control over a company's mix of assets.
Tender-offer premiums—which represent the price that active
investors are willing to pay for corporate control—ranged from 13 to 25
percent in the 1960s, but have moved to 45 percent and higher during the
past decade, underscoring the evident increase in the perceived profit
to be gained from corporate control and restructuring
Interest in restructuring also has been spurred by the apparent
increased willingness and ability of corporate managers and owners to
leverage balance sheets.

The gradual replacement of managers who grew

up in the Depression and developed a strong aversion to bankruptcy risk
probably accounts for some of the increased proclivity to issue debt
now
Moreover, innovations in capital markets have made the
increased propensity to leverage feasible

It is now much easier than

it used to be to mobilize tremendous sums of debt capital for leveraged
purchases of firms

Improvements in the loan-sale market among banks

and the greater presence of foreign banks in U S

markets have greatly

increased the ability of the banking sector to participate in merger and

-5-

acquisition transactions.

The phenomenal development of the market for

low-grade corporate debt, so-called "junk bonds," also has enhanced the
availability of credit for a wide variety of corporate transactions
The increased liquidity of this market has made it possible for
investors to diversify away firm-specific risks by building portfolios
of such debt
The tax benefits of restructuring activities are, of course,
undeniable, but this is not a particularly new phenomenon.

Our tax

system has long favored debt finance by taxing the earnings of corporate
debt capital only at the investor level, while earnings on equity
capital are taxed at both the investor and corporate levels.

There have

been other sources of tax savings in mergers that do not depend on debt
finance, involving such items as the tax basis for depreciation and
foreign tax credits

And taxable owners benefit when firms repurchase

their own shares, using what is, in effect, a tax-favored method of
paying cash dividends

In any event, the recent rise in restructuring

activity is not easily tied to any change in tax law.
Evidence about the economic consequences of restructuring is
beginning to take shape, but much remains conjectural

It is clear that

the markets believe that the recent restructurings are potentially
advantageous

Estimates range from $200 billion to $500 billion or more

in paper gains to shareholders since 1982

Apparently, only a small

portion of that has come at the expense of bondholders

These gains are

reflections of the expectations of market participants that the
restructuring will, in fact, lead to a better mix of assets within
companies and greater efficiencies in their use

This, in turn, is

-6-

expected to produce marked increases in future productivity and, hence,
in the value of American corporate business.

Many of the internal

adjustments brought about by changes in management or managerial
policies are still being implemented, and it will take time before they
show up for good or ill in measures of performance
So far, various pieces of evidence indicate that the trend
toward more ownership by managers and tighter control by other owners
and creditors has generally enhanced operational efficiency

In the

process, both jobs and capital spending in many firms have contracted as
unprofitable projects are scrapped.

But no clear trends in these

variables are yet evident in restructured firms as a group

For the

business sector, generally, growth of both employment and investment has
been strong.
If what I've outlined earlier is a generally accurate
description of the causes of the surge in restructurings of the past
decade, one would assume that a stabilization of interest rates,
exchange rates, and product prices would slow the emergence of newly
misaligned companies and opportunities for further restructuring

Such

a development would presumably lower control premiums and reduce the
pace of merger, acquisition, and LBO activity.
This suggests that the most potent policies for defusing the
restructuring/LBO boom over the long haul are essentially the same
macroeconoinic policies toward budget deficit reduction and price
stability that have been the principal policy concerns of recent years
Whatever the trends in restructuring, we cannot ignore the
implications of the associated heavy leveraging for broad-based risk in

-7-

the economy.

Other things equal, greater use of debt makes the

corporate sector more vulnerable to an economic downturn or a rise in
interest rates
be affected.

The financial stability of lenders, in turn, also may
How much is another question

The answer depends greatly

on which firms are leveraging, which financial institutions are lending,
and how the financings are structured.
Most of the restructured firms appear to be in mature, stable,
non-cyclical industries

Restructuring activity has been especially

prevalent in the trade, services, and, more recently, the food and
tobacco industries.

For such businesses, a substantial increase in debt

may raise the probability of insolvency by only a relatively small
amount

However, roughly two-fifths of merger and aquisition activity,

as well as LBOs, have involved companies in cyclically sensitive
industries that are more likely to run into trouble in the event of a
severe economic downturn.
Lenders to leveraged enterprises have been, in large part,
those that can most easily absorb losses without major systemic
consequences.

They include mutual funds, pension funds, and insurance

companies, which generally have diversified portfolios and have
traditionally invested in securities involving some risk, such as
equities

To the extent that such debt is held by individual

institutions that are not well diversified, there is some concern

At

the Federal Reserve, we are particularly concerned about the increasing
share of restructuring loans made by banks.
loans could have broader ramifications.

Massive failures of these

-8-

Generally, we must recognize that the line between equity and
debt has become increasingly fuzzy in recent years

Convertible debt

has always had an intermediate character, but now there is almost a
continuum of securities varying in their relative proportions of debt
and equity flavoring

Once there was a fairly sharp distinction between

being unable to make interest payments on a bond, which frequently led
to liquidation proceedings, and merely missing a dividend
distinction is smaller.

Now the

Outright defaults on original issue high-yield

bonds have been infrequent to date, but payment difficulties have led to
more frequent exchanges of debt that reduce the immediate cash needs of
troubled firms

Investors know when they purchase such issues that the

stream of payments received may well differ from the stream promised,
and prices tend to move in response to changes in both debt and equity
markets

In effect, the yields on debt capital rise toward that of

equity capital when scheduled repayments are less secure.
In view of these considerations, and the very limited evidence
on the effects of restructuring at the present time, it would be unwise
to restrict arbitrarily corporate restructuring

We must resist the

temptation to seek to allocate credit to specific uses through the tax
system or through the regulation of financial institutions
Restrictions on the deductibility of interest unavoidably involve an
important element of arbitrariness, one that will affect not only those
types of lending intended but other types as well.

Moreover, foreign

acquirers could be given an artificial edge to the extent that they
could avoid these restrictions

Also, the historical experience with

-9-

various types of selective credit controls clearly indicates that, in
time, borrowers and lenders find ways around them
All that doesn't mean that we should do nothing.

The

contribution of our tax structure to corporate leveraging warrants
attention

The double taxation of earnings from corporate equity

capital has added to leveraging, and thus debt levels are higher than
they need, or should, be.

Our options for dealing with this distortion

are, unfortunately, constrained severely by the federal government's
still serious budget deficit problems, a matter that I will turn to in a
moment

One straightforward approach to this distortion, of course,

would be to substantially reduce the corporate income tax
Alternatively, partial integration of corporate and individual income
taxes could be achieved by allowing corporations a deduction for
dividends paid or by giving individuals credit for taxes paid at the
corporate level.

But these changes taken alone would result in

substantial revenue losses; a rough estimate of IRS collections from
taxing dividends is in the range of $20 to $25 billion annually.
Dangers of risk to the banking system associated with high debt
levels also warrant attention.

As I have noted, the Federal Reserve, in

its role as a supervisor of banks, has particular concerns in this
regard

In 1984, the Board issued supervisory guidelines for assessing

LBO-related loans, which are set forth in an attachment to my text
These guidelines emphasized that the circumstances associated with
highly leveraged deals require that creditors exercise credit judgment
with special care, assessing those risks that are firm-specific as well
as those common to all highly leveraged firms

The Federal Reserve is

-10-

currently in the process of reviewing guidelines regarding the
evaluation of bank participation in highly leveraged financing
transactions, we anticipate that this review will be completed shortly
The Budget Deficit and the Economy
The remainder of my prepared remarks will concentrate on the
budget deficit and the corrosive impact it is having on the economy
It is beguiling to contemplate the strong economy of recent
years in the context of very large deficits and to conclude that the
concerns about the adverse effects of the deficit on the economy have
been misplaced

But this argument is fanciful

The deficit already has

begun to eat away at the foundations of our economic strength.
need to deal with it is becoming ever more urgent

And the

To the extent that

some of the negative effects of deficits have not as yet been felt, they
have been merely postponed, not avoided.

Moreover, the scope for

further such avoidance is shrinking.
To some degree, the effects of the federal budget deficits over
the past several years have been muted by two circumstances, both of
which are currently changing rapidly.

One was the rather large degree

of slack in the economy in the early years of the current expansion.
This slack meant that the economy could accommodate growing demands from
both the private and public sectors

In addition, to the extent that

these demands could not be accommodated from U S

resources, we went

abroad and imported them

This can be seen in our large trade and

current account deficits.

By now, however, the slack in the U S

economy has diminished substantially

And as inflows of foreign saving

are reduced along with our trade deficit, other sources of saving must

-11-

be found, or demands for saving curtailed.

The choices are limited; as

will become clear, the best option for the American people is a further
reduction in the federal budget deficit, and the need for such reduction
is becoming more pressing
Owing to significant efforts by the executive branch and the
Congress, coupled with strong economic growth, the deficit has shrunk
from 5 to 6 percent of gross national product a few years ago to about 3
percent of GNP today
by historical standards

Such a deficit, nevertheless, is still very large
Since World War II, the actual budget deficit

has exceeded 3 percent of GNP only in the 1975 recession period and in
the recent deficit experience beginning in 1982.

On a cyclically

adjusted or structural basis, the deficit has exceeded 3 percent of
potential GNP only in the period since 1983
Government deficits, however, place pressure on resources and
credit markets, only if they are not offset by saving elsewhere in the
economy

If the pool of private saving is small, federal deficits and

private investment will be in keen competition for funds, and private
investment will lose.
The United States deficits of recent years are threatening
precisely because they have been occurring in the context of private
saving that is low by both historical and international standards

In

the 1980s, net personal plus business saving in the United States has
been about 3 percentage points lower relative to GNP than its average in
the preceding three decades

Internationally, government deficits have

been quite common among the major industrial countries in the 1980s, but
private saving rates in most of these countries have exceeded the

-12-

deficits by very comfortable margins

In Japan, for example, less than

20 percent of its private saving has been absorbed by government
deficits, even though the Japanese general government has been borrowing
almost 3 percent of its gross domestic product in the 1980s
contrast, over half of private U S

In

saving in the 1980s has been

absorbed by the combined deficits of the federal and state and local
sectors.
Under these circumstances, such large and persistent deficits
are slowly but inexorably damaging the economy.

The damage occurs

because deficits tend to pull resources away from net private
investment, which damps the growth of the nation's capital stock

This

in turn has meant less capital per worker than would otherwise have been
the case, and this will surely engender a shortfall in labor
productivity growth and, with it, a shortfall in growth of the standard
of living.
All else equal, the higher real interest rates associated with
increased borrowing by the Treasury in the 1980s have reduced private
investment in the aggregate

Moreover, the higher real interest rates

have shifted the composition of investment away from long-lived assets,
such as factories, toward computers and other shorter-lived equipment
The data also underscore a recent decline in the average service life of
consumption as well as investment goods and a systematic tendency for
this average to move inversely with real rates of interest

That is,

the higher are real interest rates, the heavier is the concentration on
short-lived assets

-13-

Not surprisingly, we have already experienced a disturbing
decline in the level of net investment as a share of GNP

Net

investment has fallen to 4.7 percent of GNP in the 1980s from an average
level of 6 7 percent in the 1970s and even higher in the 1960s.
Moreover, it is low, not only by our own historical standards, but by
international standards as well
International comparisons of net investment should be viewed
with some caution because of differences in the measurement of
depreciation and in other technical details.

Nevertheless, the existing

data do indicate that total net private and public investment as a share
of gross domestic product over the period between 1980 and 1986 was
lower in the United States than in any of the other major industrial
countries except the United Kingdom
It is important to recognize as I indicated earlier that the
negative effects of federal deficits on growth in the capital stock may
be attenuated for a while by several forces in the private sector.

One

is a significant period of output growth in excess of potential GNP
growth—such as occurred over much of the past six years—which
undoubtedly boosts sales and profit expectations and, hence, business
investment.

Such rates of output growth, of course, cannot persist,

making this factor inherently temporary in nature
Another factor tending to limit the decline in investment
spending would be any tendency for saving to respond positively to the
higher interest rates that deficits would bring

The supply of domestic

private saving has some interest elasticity, as people put off spending
when borrowing costs are high and returns from their financial assets

-14-

are favorable.

But most analysts find that this elasticity is not

sufficiently large to matter much
Finally, net inflows of foreign saving can be, as recent years
have demonstrated, an important addition to saving.

In the 1980s, our

ability to tap foreign saving has kept the decline in the gross
investment-GNP ratio, on average, to only moderate dimensions (slightly
more than one-half percentage point) compared with the 1970s, while the
federal deficit rose by about 2-1/2 percentage points relative to GNP
Net inflows of foreign saving have amounted, on average, to almost
2 percent of GNP, an unprecedented level
Looking ahead, the continuation of inflows of foreign saving at
current levels is questionable

Evidence for the United States and for

most other major industrial nations over the last 100 years indicates
that such sizable foreign net capital inflows have not persisted and,
hence, may not be a reliable substitute for domestic saving on a
long-term basis.

In other words, domestic investment tends to be

supported by domestic saving alone in the long run
Let me conclude by reiterating that the budget deficit must be
brought down

I do not underestimate the difficult decisions that you

must make if we are to achieve the necessary reduction in the deficit.
But allowing deficits to persist courts a dangerous corrosion of our
economy and risks potentially significant reductions over time in our
standard of living.

ATTACHMENT

The Federal Reserve's directive to examiners on leveraged
buyout loans, issued in 1984, provided the following supervisoryguidance to supplement standard loan review procedures

The nature of leveraged buyouts and, in particular, the level
of debt typically involved in such arrangements give rise to supervisory
concerns over the potential risk implications for bank loan portfolios
The high volume of debt relative to equity that is characteristic of
leveraged buyouts leaves little margin for error or cushion to enable
the purchased company to withstand unanticipated financial pressures or
economic adversity. Two principal financial risks associated with
leveraged buyout financing are (1) the possibility that interest rates
may rise higher than anticipated and thereby significantly increase the
purchased company's debt service burden, and/or (2) the possibility that
the company's earnings and cash flow will decline or fail to meet
projections, either because of a general economic recession or because
of a downturn in a particular industry or sector of the economy
While
either one of these developments can undermine the creditworthiness of
any loan, the high degree of leverage and the small equity cushion
typical of moat leveraged buyouts suggest that economic or financial
adversity will have a particularly large and negative impact on such
companies
Thus, a leveraged buyout arrangement that appears reasonable
at a given rate of interest or expected cash flow can suddenly appear to
be questionable if interest rates rise significantly or if earnings
should fail to provide an adequate margin of coverage to service the
acquisition debt
In addition to unfavorable interest rate movements and earnings
developments, adverse economic conditions may also have a negative
impact on the value of a company's collateral
For example, if a
general economic slowdown reduces a company's sales and earnings, the
marketability and value of its collateral may also suffer
In any
event, given the amount of debt involved in leveraged buyouts, the value
of collateral is extremely important, and the risk that collateral
coverage may be insufficient to protect the bank is a significant factor
in evaluating the creditworthiness of these loans
In light of all of
these considerations, the quality of a purchased company's management is
also extremely important and represents another critical element in the
bank's evaluation of leveraged buyouts
This is because such management
must oversee both the special financial risks associated with the
leveraged buyout form of acquisition financing as well as the normal
day-to-day affairs and operations of the purchased company's business
In the course of on-site examinations, examiners should review
a bank's involvement in leveraged buyout financing as well as the loans
associated with individual leveraged buyouts
The following general

guidelines are provided to underscore and supplement existing loan
review procedures
1. In evaluating individual loans and credit files, particular
attention should be addressed to i) the reasonableness of
interest rate assumptions and earnings projections relied
upon by the bank in extending the loan, ii) the trend of the
borrowing company's and the industry's performance over time
and the history and stability of the company's earnings and
cash flow, particularly over the most recent business cycle,
iii) the relationship between the company's cash flow and
debt service requirements and the resulting margin of debt
service coverage, and iv) the reliability and stability of
collateral values and the adequacy of collateral coverage
2

In reviewing the performance of individual credits,
examiners should attempt to determine if debt service
requirements are being covered by cash flow generated by the
company's operations or whether the debt service
requirements are being met out of the proceeds of additional
or ancillary loans from the bank designed to cover interest
changes

3

Policies and procedures pertaining to leveraged buyout
financing should be reviewed to ensure that they incorporate
prudent and reasonable limits on the total amount and type
(by industry) of exposure that the bank can assume through
these financing arrangements

4

The bank's pricing, credit policies, and approval procedures
should be reviewed to ensure i) that rates are reasonable in
light of the risks involved and ii) that credit standards
are not compromised in order to increase market share.
Credit standards and internal review and approval standards
should reflect the degree of risk and leverage inherent in
these transactions.

5. Total loans to finance leveraged buyouts should be treated
as a potential concentration of credit and if, in the
aggregate, they are sufficiently large in relation to
capital, the loans should be listed on the concentrations
page in the examination report
6. Significant deficiencies or risks regarding a bank's
leveraged buyout financing should be discussed on page 1 of
the examination report and brought to the attention of the
board of directors