View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 a.m. E.S.T.
March 24, 1993

Statement by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on Finance
United States Senate
March 24, 1993

As I have indicated to other committees of the Congress
in recent days, our burgeoning structural budget deficit, unless
addressed, will increasingly threaten the stability of our
economic system.

Time is no longer on our side.

At 5 percent of

GDP, the current deficit is very large by historical standards.
After declining through 1996, the current services deficit starts
on an inexorable upward path again.

On a cyclically adjusted or

structural basis, the deficit has hovered around 3 percent of
potential GDP for the last ten years, a phenomenon without
precedent in our peacetime history.
I am encouraged that the President and the Congress are
making serious efforts to restore a measure of balance to our
fiscal affairs.
It is beguiling to contemplate the downtrend in
inflation in recent years in the context of very large budget
deficits and to conclude that the concerns about their adverse
effects on the economy have been misplaced.
notion is dubious.

Regrettably, this

The deficit is a corrosive force that already

has begun to eat away at the foundations of our economic
strength.

Financing of private capital investment has been

crowded out and, not surprising, the United States has
experienced a lower level of net investment relative to GDP than
any other of the G-7 countries in the last decade.
To some degree, the impact of the federal budget
deficits over the past decade has been muted as we imported
resources to help finance them.

This can be seen in our large

trade and current account deficits.

However, we should n o t —

- 2 indeed, we probably cannot—rely on foreign sources of funds
indefinitely.

If we do nothing, the markets will ultimately

force an adjustment; by acting now to redress our internal
imbalance, we can lower the risk of unpleasant stresses down the
road.
I shall eschew, as I have in previous testimonies,
comments on the specific elements of the deficit-reduction
proposals currently under review by the Congress.

I should like,

nonetheless, to take the time you have made available, Mr.
Chairman, to outline my views on the principles that should
underlie current deliberations.
First, according to both the Office of Management and
Budget and the Congressional Budget Office, deficits are likely
to be held in check by relatively good economic performance over
the next few years.

But from 1997 on, budget outlays under

existing law are projected to rise appreciably faster than the
tax base.

If such trends are not altered, stabilizing the

deficit-to-GDP ratio solely from the receipts side, not to
mention reducing it, will necessarily require ever increasing tax
rates.

This would surely undercut incentives for risk taking and

inevitably damp the long-term growth and tax revenue potential of
our economy.

The gap between spending and revenues will not

close under such conditions.

Thus, there is no alternative to

achieving much slower growth of outlays if deficit control is our
objective.

This implies not only the need to make cuts now, but

to control the growth of future spending, so that it does not

- 3 exceed, and preferably is less than, the projected growth in the
tax base.
The thought expressed by some that we can inflate our
way out of the budget deficit is fanciful.

Aside from its

serious debilitating effects on our economic system, higher
inflation, given the explicit and implicit indexing of receipts
and expenditures, would not reduce the deficit.

As I indicated

in testimony to the Joint Economic Committee in January, there is
a possibility that productivity has moved into a significantly
faster long-term growth channel, which would boost real growth
and tax revenues over time.

But even if that turns out to be the

case, short of an increase beyond anything that we can reasonably
anticipate at this time, productivity, in itself, would not be
enough to resolve the basic long-term imbalance in our budgetary
accounts.

Thus, while economic growth is necessary to contain

budget deficits, it regrettably is not sufficient.
In deciding how to pare a structural budget deficit, it
is important to be clear on the different roles of boosting
taxes, on the one hand, and cutting spending programs on the
other.

All feasible taxes, by their very nature, restrain

business activity.

Hence, excluding so-called sin taxes and

possibly environmental taxes, increases in taxes can only be
justified to finance expenditures that are deemed essential.

The

level and composition of outlays to be financed by revenues is,
in our society, a political matter, as is also the degree of
progressivity and incidence of taxation.

But over the long run,

- 4 it is important to recognize that trying to wholly, or
substantially, address a structural budget deficit by increasing
revenues is fraught with exceptional difficulties, and is more
likely to fail than succeed.
All else equal, reducing the deficit would enlarge the
pool of savings available for private capital investment.

But

investment will not automatically occur unless there are adequate
incentives for risk taking.
A greater willingness of a society to consume less of
its current income should lower real interest rates and spur such
investment.

But if risk taking is discouraged through excessive

taxation of capital or repressive regulation, high levels of
investment will not emerge and the level of saving will fall as
real incomes stagnate.
The process by which government deficits divert
resources from private investment is part of the broader process
of redirecting the allocation of real resources that inevitably
accompanies the activities of the federal government.

The

federal government can preempt resources from the private sector
or direct their usage by a number of different means, the most
important of which are: (1) spending, financed by taxation; (2)
spending, financed by borrowing i.e., deficit spending; (3)
regulation mandating private activities such as investment in
pollution control or safety equipment, which are likely to be
financed through the issuance of debt; and (4) government
guarantees of private borrowing.

- 5 What deficit spending and regulatory measures have in
common is that the preemption of resources, directly or
indirectly, is not sensitive to the rate of interest.

The

federal government, for example, will finance its budget deficit
in full, irrespective of the interest rate it must pay to raise
the funds.

Borrowing with government-guaranteed debt may be

interest sensitive, but the guarantees have the effect of
preempting resources from those without access to riskless
credit.

Government spending fully financed by taxation does, of

course, preempt real resources from the private sector, but the
process works through channels other than through real interest
rates.
Purely private activities, on the other hand, are, to a
greater or lesser extent, responsive to real interest rates.

The

demand for housing, for example, falls off dramatically as
mortgage interest rates rise.

Inventory demand is clearly a

function of short-term interest rates, and the level of interest
rates, as it is reflected in the cost of capital, is a key
element in the decision on whether to expand or modernize
productive capacity.

Hence, to the extent that the demand for

saving exceeds its supply, interest rates will rise until
sufficient excess demand is finally crowded out.
The crowded-out demand cannot, of course, be that of
the federal government, directly or indirectly, because federal
government demand does not respond to rising interest rates.
Rather, real interest rates will rise to the point that private

- 6 borrowing is reduced sufficiently to allow the entire
requirements of the federal government, including its on- and
off-budget deficits and all its collateral guarantees and
mandated activities, to be met.
In these circumstances, there is no alternative to
higher real interest rates diverting real resources from the
private to the public sector.

In the short run, nominal short-

term interest rates may temporarily be held down if the Federal
Reserve accommodates the excess demand for funds through a more
expansionary monetary policy.

But this will only produce greater

inflation and, ultimately, have little, if any, effect on the
allocation of real resources between the private and public
sectors.
In such an environment, inflationary forces too often
lead to increased risk premiums, higher real interest rates, and
a higher cost of capital.

This, in turn, engenders a

foreshortening of the time horizon of investment decisions and a
decreasing willingness to commit to the long term, a commitment
that is so crucial to a modern technologically advanced economy.
Structural budget deficits and excessive collateral credit
preemptions are symptoms of a society overconsuming and
undersaving and underinvesting.
While there is no substitute for political will in
reining in outsized structural budget deficits, there are
changes, I believe, that could make the budget process more
effective.

In particular, it is worth reconsidering sunset

- 7 legislation, which would impose explicit termination dates on
spending programs.

Expiring programs that still have merit

should have no difficulty being reauthorized, but programs whose
justification has become less compelling would not receive the
necessary votes.

Indeed, it is hard to imagine that sunset

legislation would not lead to at least some improvement over the
current situation, quite possibly fostering non-trivial budget
savings.
It also would be useful to take a look at the currentservices methodology for evaluating budget changes.

A baseline

estimate obviously is a necessary ingredient in the budget
process that helps inform policymakers about the impact of policy
proposals.

However, the current services concept assumes that no

further congressional, judicial, or bureaucratic actions will be
taken to alter existing programs.

This is quite unrealistic, but

it would be of no particular significance were it not for the
fact that the bias of such actions is patently toward more
spending rather than less.

Hence, merely owing to ongoing

congressional deliberations, administrative rulings, and
decisions, an add-on to the current services outlay estimates is
required to get a better view of what might be termed the
"expected" deficit of the future.

It is not possible to know in

advance which spending programs will be expanded, except that
some will.

In recent years, congressional current-services

outlay estimates have consistently been adjusted upward in
response to such technical reestimations of program costs.

- 8 Indeed, technical reestimates explain a significant part of the
failure of the deficit to fall as contemplated at the time of
enactment of the Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990.
Finally, while I do not favor a balanced budget
amendment on the grounds that it might be impossible to enforce,
I would support a constitutional amendment, or even a legislative
provision, that stipulates that all revenue and expenditure
initiatives require supermajorities (for example, 60 percent) to
pass both houses of the Congress.

Combined with sunset

legislation, such a procedure could probably go far to neutralize
the obvious propensity of our political system toward structural
deficits.
Let me conclude by reiterating my central message.
deficit is a malignant force in our economy.

The

How the deficit is

reduced is very important; that it be done is crucial.

Allowing

it to fester would court a dangerous erosion of our economic
strength and a potentially significant deterioration in our real
standard of living.
reverse this process.
this process.

Fortunately, we have it in our power to
This Committee has an important role in

Speaking as a citizen, I wish you well.