View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 a.m. EST
January 25, 2001

Statement of
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on the Budget
United States Senate
January 25, 2001

I am pleased to appear here today to discuss some of the important issues surrounding the
outlook for the federal budget and the attendant implications for the formulation of fiscal policy.
In doing so, I want to emphasize that I speak for myself and not necessarily for the Federal
Reserve.
The challenges you face both in shaping a budget for the coming year and in designing a
longer-run strategy for fiscal policy were brought into sharp focus by the release last week of the
Clinton Administration's final budget projections, which showed further upward revisions of
on-budget surpluses for the next decade. The Congressional Budget Office also is expected to
again raise its projections when it issues its report next week.
The key factor driving the cumulative upward revisions in the budget picture in recent
years has been the extraordinary pickup in the growth of labor productivity experienced in this
country since the mid-1990s. Between the early 1970s and 1995, output per hour in the nonfarm
business sector rose about 1-1/2 percent per year, on average. Since 1995, however, productivity
growth has accelerated markedly, about doubling the earlier pace, even after taking account of
the impetus from cyclical forces. Though hardly definitive, the apparent sustained strength in
measured productivity in the face of a pronounced slowing in the growth of aggregate demand
during the second half of last year was an important test of the extent of the improvement in
structural productivity. These most recent indications have added to the accumulating evidence
that the apparent increases in the growth of output per hour are more than transitory.
It is these observations that appear to be causing economists, including those who
contributed to the OMB and the CBO budget projections, to raise their forecasts of the
economy's long-term growth rates and budget surpluses. This increased optimism receives

-2support from the forward-looking indicators of technical innovation and structural productivity
growth, which have shown few signs of weakening despite the marked curtailment in recent
months of capital investment plans for equipment and software.
To be sure, these impressive upward revisions to the growth of structural productivity
and economic potential are based on inferences drawn from economic relationships that are
different from anything we have considered in recent decades. The resulting budget projections,
therefore, are necessarily subject to a relatively wide range of error. Reflecting the uncertainties
of forecasting well into the future, neither the OMB nor the CBO projects productivity to
continue to improve at the stepped-up pace of the past few years. Both expect productivity
growth rates through the next decade to average roughly 2-1/4 to 2-1/2 percent per year-far
above the average pace from the early 1970s to the mid-1990s, but still below that of the past five
years.
Had the innovations of recent decades, especially in information technologies, not come
to fruition, productivity growth during the past five to seven years, arguably, would have
continued to languish at the rate of the preceding twenty years. The sharp increase in prospective
long-term rates of return on high-tech investments would not have emerged as it did in the early
1990s, and the associated surge in stock prices would surely have been largely absent. The
accompanying wealth effect, so evidently critical to the growth of economic activity since the
mid 1990s, would never have materialized.
In contrast, the experience of the past five to seven years has been truly without recent
precedent. The doubling of the growth rate of output per hour has caused individuals' real
taxable income to grow nearly 2-1/2 times as fast as it did over the preceding ten years and

-3resulted in the substantial surplus of receipts over outlays that we are now experiencing. Not
only did taxable income rise with the faster growth of GDP, but the associated large increase in
asset prices and capital gains created additional tax liabilities not directly related to income from
current production.
The most recent projections from the OMB indicate that, if current policies remain in
place, the total unified surplus will reach $800 billion in fiscal year 2011, including an on-budget
surplus of $500 billion. The CBO reportedly will be showing even larger surpluses. Moreover,
the admittedly quite uncertain long-term budget exercises released by the CBO last October
maintain an implicit on-budget surplus under baseline assumptions well past 2030 despite the
budgetary pressures from the aging of the baby-boom generation, especially on the major health
programs.
The most recent projections, granted their tentativeness, nonetheless make clear that the
highly desirable goal of paying off the federal debt is in reach before the end of the decade. This
is in marked contrast to the perspective of a year ago when the elimination of the debt did not
appear likely until the next decade.
But continuing to run surpluses beyond the point at which we reach zero or near-zero
federal debt brings to center stage the critical longer-term fiscal policy issue of whether the
federal government should accumulate large quantities of private (more technically nonfederal)
assets. At zero debt, the continuing unified budget surpluses currently projected imply a major
accumulation of private assets by the federal government. This development should factor
materially into the policies you and the Administration choose to pursue.

-4I believe, as I have noted in the past, that the federal government should eschew private
asset accumulation because it would be exceptionally difficult to insulate the government's
investment decisions from political pressures. Thus, over time, having the federal government
hold significant amounts of private assets would risk sub-optimal performance by our capital
markets, diminished economic efficiency, and lower overall standards of living than would be
achieved otherwise.
Short of an extraordinarily rapid and highly undesirable short-term dissipation of unified
surpluses or a transferring of assets to individual privatized accounts, it appears difficult to avoid
at least some accumulation of private assets by the government.
Private asset accumulation may be forced upon us well short of reaching zero debt.
Obviously, savings bonds and state and local government series bonds are not readily redeemable
before maturity. But the more important issue is the potentially rising cost of retiring marketable
Treasury debt. While shorter-term marketable securities could be allowed to run off as they
mature, longer-term issues would have to be retired before maturity through debt buybacks. The
magnitudes are large: As of January 1, for example, there was in excess of three quarters of a
trillion dollars in outstanding nonmarketable securities, such as savings bonds and state and local
series issues, and marketable securities (excluding those held by the Federal Reserve) that do not
mature and could not be called before 2011. Some holders of long-term Treasury securities may
be reluctant to give them up, especially those who highly value the risk-free status of those
issues. Inducing such holders, including foreign holders, to willingly offer to sell their securities
prior to maturity could require paying premiums that far exceed any realistic value of retiring the
debt before maturity.

-5Decisions about what type of private assets to acquire and to which federal accounts they
should be directed must be made well before the policy is actually implemented, which could
occur in as little as five to seven years from now. These choices have important implications for
the balance of saving and, hence, investment in our economy. For example, transferring
government saving to individual private accounts as a means of avoiding the accumulation of
private assets in the government accounts could significantly affect how social security will be
funded in the future.
Short of some privatization, it would be preferable in my judgment to allocate the
required private assets to the social security trust funds, rather than to on-budget accounts. To be
sure, such trust fund investments are subject to the same concerns about political pressures as
on-budget investments would be. The expectation that the retirement of the baby-boom
generation will eventually require a drawdown of these fund balances does, however, provide
some mitigation of these concerns.
Returning to the broader picture, I continue to believe, as I have testified previously, that
all else being equal, a declining level of federal debt is desirable because it holds down long-term
real interest rates, thereby lowering the cost of capital and elevating private investment. The
rapid capital deepening that has occurred in the U.S. economy in recent years is a testament to
these benefits. But the sequence of upward revisions to the budget surplus projections for several
years now has reshaped the choices and opportunities before us. Indeed, in almost any creditable
baseline scenario, short of a major and prolonged economic contraction, the full benefits of debt
reduction are now achieved before the end of this decade-a prospect that did not seem likely
only a year or even six months ago.

-6The most recent data significantly raise the probability that sufficient resources will be
available to undertake both debt reduction and surplus-lowering policy initiatives. Accordingly,
the tradeoff faced earlier appears no longer an issue. The emerging key fiscal policy need is to
address the implications of maintaining surpluses beyond the point at which publicly held debt is
effectively eliminated.
The time has come, in my judgement, to consider a budgetary strategy that is consistent
with a preemptive smoothing of the glide path to zero federal debt or, more realistically, to the
level of federal debt that is an effective irreducible minimum. Certainly, we should make sure
that social security surpluses are large enough to meet our long-term needs and seriously consider
explicit mechanisms that will help ensure that outcome. Special care must be taken not to
conclude that wraps on fiscal discipline are no longer necessary. At the same time, we must
avoid a situation in which we come upon the level of irreducible debt so abruptly that the only
alternative to the accumulation of private assets would be a sharp reduction in taxes and/or an
increase in expenditures, because these actions might occur at a time when sizable economic
stimulus would be inappropriate. In other words, budget policy should strive to limit potential
disruptions by making the on-budget surplus economically inconsequential when the debt is
effectively paid off.
In general, as I have testified previously, if long-term fiscal stability is the criterion, it is
far better, in my judgment, that the surpluses be lowered by tax reductions than by spending
increases. The flurry of increases in outlays that occurred near the conclusion of last fall's budget
deliberations is troubling because it makes the previous year's lack of discipline less likely to
have been an aberration.

-7To be sure, with the burgeoning federal surpluses, fiscal policy has not yet been unduly
compromised by such actions. But history illustrates the difficulty of keeping spending in check,
especially in programs that are open-ended commitments, which too often have led to much
larger outlays than initially envisioned. It is important to recognize that government expenditures
are claims against real resources and that, while those claims may be unlimited, our capacity to
meet them is ultimately constrained by the growth in productivity. Moreover, the greater the
drain of resources from the private sector, arguably, the lower the growth potential of the
economy. In contrast to most spending programs, tax reductions have downside limits. They
cannot be open-ended.
Lately there has been much discussion of cutting taxes to confront the evident
pronounced weakening in recent economic performance. Such tax initiatives, however,
historically have proved difficult to implement in the time frame in which recessions have
developed and ended. For example, although President Ford proposed in January of 1975 that
withholding rates be reduced, this easiest of tax changes was not implemented until May, when
the recession was officially over and the recovery was gathering force. Of course, had that
recession lingered through the rest of 1975 and beyond, the tax cuts would certainly have been
helpful. In today's context, where tax reduction appears required in any event over the next
several years to assist in forestalling the accumulation of private assets, starting that process
sooner rather than later likely would help smooth the transition to longer-term fiscal balance.
And should current economic weakness spread beyond what now appears likely, having a tax cut
in place may, in fact, do noticeable good.

-8As for tax policy over the longer run, most economists believe that it should be directed
at setting rates at the levels required to meet spending commitments, while doing so in a manner
that minimizes distortions, increases efficiency, and enhances incentives for saving, investment,
and work.
In recognition of the uncertainties in the economic and budget outlook, it is important that
any long-term tax plan, or spending initiative for that matter, be phased in. Conceivably, it could
include provisions that, in some way, would limit surplus-reducing actions if specified targets for
the budget surplus and federal debt were not satisfied. Only if the probability was very low that
prospective tax cuts or new outlay initiatives would send the on-budget accounts into deficit,
would unconditional initiatives appear prudent.
The reason for caution, of course, rests on the tentativeness of our projections. What if,
for example, the forces driving the surge in tax revenues in recent years begin to dissipate or
reverse in ways that we do not now foresee? Indeed, we still do not have a full understanding of
the exceptional strength in individual income tax receipts during the latter 1990s. To the extent
that some of the surprise has been indirectly associated with the surge in asset values in the
1990s, the softness in equity prices over the past year has highlighted some of the risks going
forward.
Indeed, the current economic weakness may reveal a less favorable relationship between
tax receipts, income, and asset prices than has been assumed in recent projections. Until we
receive full detail on the distribution by income of individual tax liabilities for 1999, 2000, and
perhaps 2001, we are making little more than informed guesses of certain key relationships
between income and tax receipts.

-9To be sure, unless later sources do reveal major changes in tax liability determination,
receipts should be reasonably well-maintained in the near term, as the effects of earlier gains in
asset values continue to feed through with a lag into tax liabilities. But the longer-run effects of
movements in asset values are much more difficult to assess, and those uncertainties would
intensify should equity prices remain significantly off their peaks. Of course, the uncertainties in
the receipts outlook do seem less troubling in view of the cushion provided by the recent sizable
upward revisions to the ten-year surplus projections. But the risk of adverse movements in
receipts is still real, and the probability of dropping back into deficit as a consequence of
imprudent fiscal policies is not negligible.
In the end, the outlook for federal budget surpluses rests fundamentally on expectations of
longer-term trends in productivity, fashioned by judgments about the technologies that underlie
these trends. Economists have long noted that the diffusion of technology starts slowly,
accelerates, and then slows with maturity. But knowing where we now stand in that sequence is
difficult—if not impossible—in real time. As the CBO and the OMB acknowledge, they have
been cautious in their interpretation of recent productivity developments and in their assumptions
going forward. That seems appropriate given the uncertainties that surround even these relatively
moderate estimates for productivity growth. Faced with these uncertainties, it is crucial that we
develop budgetary strategies that deal with any disappointments that could occur.
That said, as I have argued for some time, there is a distinct possibility that much of the
development and diffusion of new technologies in the current wave of innovation still lies ahead,
and we cannot rule out productivity growth rates greater than is assumed in the official budget

-10projections. Obviously, if that turns out to be the case, the existing level of tax rates would have
to be reduced to remain consistent with currently projected budget outlays.
The changes in the budget outlook over the past several years are truly remarkable. Little
more than a decade ago, the Congress established budget controls that were considered
successful because they were instrumental in squeezing the burgeoning budget deficit to tolerable
dimensions. Nevertheless, despite the sharp curtailment of defense expenditures under way
during those years, few believed that a surplus was anywhere on the horizon. And the notion that
the rapidly mounting federal debt could be paid off would not have been taken seriously.
But let me end on a cautionary note. With today's euphoria surrounding the surpluses, it
is not difficult to imagine the hard-earned fiscal restraint developed in recent years rapidly
dissipating. We need to resist those policies that could readily resurrect the deficits of the past
and the fiscal imbalances that followed in their wake.