View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 A.M.EDT
October 1,1998

Statement by

Alan Greenspan

Chairman

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

before the

Committee on Banking and Financial Services

U.S. House of Representatives

October 1,1998

Introduction
Mr. Chairman and other members of the Committee, I thank you for this opportunity to
report on the Federal Reserve's role in facilitating the private-sector refinancing of the large hedge
fund, Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM). In my remarks this morning, I will attempt to put
into some perspective the events of the past few weeks and discuss some questions of importance
to public policy makers that they raise.
The Federal Reserve Bank of New York's efforts were designed solely to enhance the
probability of an orderly private-sector adjustment, not to dictate the path that adjustment would
take. As President McDonough just related, no Federal Reserve funds were put at risk, no promises
were made by the Federal Reserve, and no individual firms were pressured to participate. Officials
of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York facilitated discussions in which the private parties arrived
at an agreement that both served their mutual self interest and avoided possible serious market
dislocations. Financial market participants were already unsettled by recent global events. Had the
failure of LTCM triggered the seizing up of markets, substantial damage could have been inflicted
on many market participants, including some not directly involved with the firm, and could have
potentially impaired the economies of many nations, including our own. With credit spreads
already elevated and the market prices of risky assets under considerable downward pressure,
Federal Reserve officials moved more quickly to provide their good offices to help resolve the
affairs of LTCM than would have been the case in more normal times. In effect, the threshold of
action was lowered by the knowledge that markets had recently become fragile. Moreover, our
sense was that the consequences of a fire sale triggered by cross-default clauses, should LTCM fail
on some of its obligations, risked a severe drying up of market liquidity. The plight of LTCM might
scarcely have caused a ripple infinancialmarkets or among federal regulators 18 months ago—but in
current circumstances it was judged to warrant attention.

-2What is remarkable is not this episode, but the relative absence of such examples over the
past five years. Dynamic markets periodically engender large defaults.
Events of the Past Few Weeks
LTCM is a hedge fund, or a mutual fund that is structured to avoid regulation by limiting its
clientele to a small number of highly sophisticated, very wealthy individuals and that seeks high rates
of return by investing and trading in a variety of financial instruments. Since its founding in 1994,
LTCM has had a prominent position in the community of hedge funds, in part because of its
assemblage of talent in pricing and tradingfinancialinstruments, as well as its large initial capital
stake. In its first few years of business, it earned an enviable reputation by racking up a string of
above-normal returns for its investors.
LTCM appears principally to have garnered those returns by making judgments on interest
rate spreads and the volatilities of market prices. In its search for high return, LTCM levered its
capital through securities repurchase contracts and derivatives transactions, relying on sophisticated
mathematical models of behavior to guide those transactions. As long as the configuration of
returns generally mimicked their historical patterns, LTCM's mathematical models of asset pricing
could be used to ferret out temporary market price anomalies. Their trading both closed such price
gaps and earned an extra bit of return on capital for them. But it is the nature of the competitive
process drivingfinancialinnovation that such techniques would be emulated, making it ever more
difficult to find market anomalies that provided shareholders with a high return. Indeed, the very
efficiencies that LTCM and its competitors brought to the overall financial system gradually reduced
the opportunities for above-normal profits. Indeed, LTCM acknowledged this when returning
$2-3/4 billion of capital to investors at the end of 1997. To counter these diminishing
opportunities, LTCM apparently reached further for return over time by employing more leverage

-3and increasing its exposure to risk, a strategy that was destined to fail. Unfortunately for its
shareholders, LTCM chose this exposure just as financial market uncertainty and investor risk
aversion began to rise rapidly around the world.
In that environment—so at variance with the experience built into its models—LTCM's
embrace of risk on a large scale produced stunning losses. As we now know, by the end of August
the firm had lost half its capital base. And as September unfolded, the bleeding continued. The
firm, however, apparently did not unwind its positions significantly.
In our dynamic market economy, investors and traders, at times, make misjudgments.
When market prices and interest rates adjust promptly to evidence of such mistakes, their
consequences are generally felt mostly by the perpetrators and, thus, rarely cumulate to pose
significant problems for the financial system as a whole. Indeed, the operation of an effective
market economy necessitates that investment funds committed to capital projects that do not
accurately reflect consumer and business preferences should incur losses and ultimately be
liquidated. What value is left needs to be redirected to profitable uses—those that more accurately
reflect market preferences. By such winnowing of inefficiencies, productivity is enhanced and
standards of livings expand over time.
Financial markets operate efficiently only when participants can commit to transactions with
reasonable confidence that the risk of nonpayment can be rationally judged and compensated for.
Effective and seasoned markets pass this test almostallof the time. On rare occasions, they do not.
Fear, whether irrational or otherwise, grips participants and they unthinkingly disengage from risky
assets in favor of those providing safety and liquidity. The subtle distinctions that investors make,
so critical to the effective operation offinancialmarkets, are abandoned. Assets, good and bad, are
dumped indiscriminately in circumstances of high uncertainty and fear that are not conducive to

-4planning and investment. Such circumstances, were they generalized and persistent, would be
wholly inconsistent with the functioning of sophisticated economies supported by long-term capital
investment.
Quickly unwinding a complicated portfolio that contains exposure to all manner of risks,
such as that of LTCM, in such market conditions amounts to conducting a fire sale. The prices
received in a time of stress do not reflect longer-run potential, adding to the losses incurred. Of
course, a fire sale that transfers wealth from one set of sophisticated market players to another,
without any impact on the financial system overall, should not be a concern for the central bank.
Moreover, creditors should reasonably be expected to put some weight on the possibility of a large
market swing when making their risk assessments. Indeed, when we examine banks we expect
them to have systems in place that take account of outsized market moves. However, a fire sale
may be sufficiently intense and widespread that it seriously distorts markets and elevates uncertainty
enough to impair the overall functioning of the economy. Sophisticated economic systems cannot
thrive in such an atmosphere.1
The scale and scope of LTCM's operations, which encompassed many markets, maturities,
and currencies and often relied on instruments that were thinly traded and had prices that were not
continuously quoted, made it exceptionally difficult to predict the broader ramifications of
attempting to close out its positions precipitately. That its mistakes should be unwound and losses
incurred was never open to question. How they should be unwound and when those losses
incurred so as to foster the continued smooth operation of financial markets was much more

1

At the same time, not all fire sales are without merit. The Resolution Trust Corporation
earlier this decade chose to offer commercial real estate in what might be termed a fire sale because
it was the only way an otherwise seized-up market could be galvanized. Some level of market prices
had to be established—even if below "intrinsic" or longer-run value in order to re-establish a twoway market. This was a special case.

-5difficult to assess. The price gyrations that would have evolved from a fire sale would have
reflected fear-driven judgments that could only impair effective market functioning and generate
losses for innocent bystanders.
While the principle that fire sales undermine the effective functioning of markets may be
clear, deciding when a potential market disruption rises to a level of seriousness warranting central
bank involvement is among the most difficult judgments that ever confronts a central banker. In
situations like this, there is no reason for central bank involvement unless there is a substantial
probability that a fire sale would result in severe, widespread, and prolonged disruptions to financial
market activity.
It was the judgment of officials at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, who were
monitoring the situation on an ongoing basis, that the act of unwinding LTCM's portfolio in a
forced liqudiation would not only have a significant distorting impact on market prices but also in
the process could produce large losses, or worse, for a number of creditors and counterparties, and
for other market participants who were not directly involved with LTCM. In that environment, it
was the FRBNY's judgment that it was to the advantage of all parties—including the creditors and
other market participants—to engender if at all possible an orderly resolution rather than let the firm
go into disorderly fire-sale liquidation following a set of cascading cross defaults.
As President McDonough has detailed, officers of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York
contacted a number of creditors and asked if there were alternatives to forcing the firm into
bankruptcy. At the same time, FRBNY officers informed some of their colleagues at the Federal
Reserve Board, the Treasury, and other financial regulators of their ongoing activities. The troubles
of LTCM were not a complete surprise to its counterparties. After all, LTCM's earlier statements
regarding its August losses were well known, and sophisticated counterparties understood the

-6difficulties in closing out large losing positions. In addition, the commercial banks among its
creditors had already begun taking normal precautionary measures associated with exposure to
counterparties whose condition is deteriorating. Still, creditors as a whole most likely
underestimated the size and scope of the market bets that LTCM was undertaking, an issue that is
currently under review.
On September 23, the private sector parties arrived at an agreement providing a capital
infusion of about $3-1/2 billion in return for substantially diluting existing shareholders' stake in
LTCM. Control of the firm passed from the current management to a committee determined from
the outside by the new investors. Those investors intend to shrink LTCM's portfolio so as to
reduce risk of loss and return the remaining capital to the investors as soon as practicable. I do not
rule out the possibility that the new owners of what is left of LTCM may decide to keep part of it in
business. That is their judgment to make.
This agreement was not a government bailout, in that Federal Reserve funds were neither
provided nor ever even suggested. Agreements were not forced upon unwilling market participants.
Creditors and counterparties calculated that LTCM and, accordingly, their claims, would be worth
more over time if the liquidation of LTCM's portfolio was orderly as opposed to being subject to a
fire sale. And with markets currently volatile and investors skittish, putting a special premium on
the timely resolution of LTCM's problems seemed entirely appropriate as a matter of public policy.
Of course, any time that there is public involvement that softens the blow of private-sector
losses—even as obliquely as in this episode-the issue of moral ha2ard arises. Any action by the
government that prevents some of the negative consequences to the private sector of the mistakes
it makes raises the threshold of risks market participants will presumably subsequently choose to
take. Over time, economic efficiency will be impaired as some uneconomic investments are

-7undertaken under the implicit assumption that possible losses may be borne by the government
But is much moral hazard created by aborting fire sales? To be sure, investors wiped out in
a fire sale will clearly be less risk prone than if their mistakes were more orderly unwound. But is
the broader market well served if the resulting fear and other irrational judgments govern the degree
of risk participants are subsequently willing to incur? Risk taking is a necessary condition for wealth
creation. The optimum degree of risk aversion should be governed by rational judgments about the
market place, not the fear flowing from fire sales.
The Federal Reserve provided its good offices to LTCM's creditors, not to protect LTCM's
investors, creditors, or managers from loss, but to avoid the distortions to market processes caused
by afire-saleliquidation and the consequent spreading of those distortions through contagion. To
be sure, this may well work to reduce the ultimate losses to the original owners of LTCM, but that
was a byproduct, perhaps unfortunate, of the process.
I should add that, in order to keep incentives working in their favor, the creditors of LTCM
apparently also understood the importance of some cushioning of the losses to the owners and
managers of the firm. The private creditors and counterparties in the rescue package chose to
preserve a sliver of equity for the original owners-one tenth--so that some of the management
would have an incentive to stay with the firm to assist in the liquidation of the portfolio.
Regrettably, the creditors felt that, given the complexity of market bets woven into a bewildering
arrray of financial contracts, working with the existing management would be far easier than starting
from scratch.
Some Questions for Policy Makers
Without doubt, extensive study will be required to put the events of the past few weeks into
proper perspective. As a member of the President's Working Group on Financial Markets, I

-8support Secretary Rubin's call for a special study on the public policy implications of hedge funds.
While the affairs of LTCM are by no means settled, I would like to pose some tentative questions
that may have to be addressed.
First, how much dependence should be placed on financial modeling, -which, for all its
sophistication, can get too far ahead of human judgment? This decade is strewn with examples of
bright people who thought they had built a better mousetrap that could consistently extract an
abnormal return from financial markets. Some succeed for a time. But while there may
occasionally be misconfigurations among market prices that allow abnormal returns, they do not
persist. Indeed, efforts to take advantage of such misalignments force prices into better alignment
and are soon emulated by competitors, further narrowing, or eliminating, any gaps. No matter how
skillful the trading scheme, over the long haul, abnormal returns are sustained only through
abnormal exposure to risk.
Second, what steps could counterparties have taken to ensure that they had properly
estimated their exposure, particularly in markets that are volatile? To an important degree, the
creditors of LTCM were induced to infuse capital into the firm because they failed to stress test
their counterparty exposures adequately and therefore underestimated the size of the
uncollateralized exposure that they could face in volatile and illiquid markets. In part, this also
reflected an underappreciation of the volume and nature of the risks LTCM had undertaken and its
relative size in the overall market. By failing to make those determinations, its fellow market
participants failed to put an adequate brake on LTCM's use of leverage. To be sure, sometimes
decisions are based on judgments about the soundness of borrowers that are accepted from third
parties or, possibly in this case, that are founded on the impressive qualifications of LTCM's
principals. In some cases, such truncated risk appraisals may be accurate, but they are not a

substitute for a rigorous analysis by the lender of the borrower's overall credit worthiness and risk
profile.
Third, in this regard what lessons are there for bank regulators? Domestic commercial bank
exposure to LTCM included both direct lending and acting as counterparties to the firm in
derivatives contracts. A preliminary review of bank dealings with LTCM suggests that the banks
have collateral adequate to cover most of their current mark-to-market exposures with LTCM. The
unexpected surge in risk aversion and the dramatic opening up of interest rate spreads in August
obviously caught LTCM wrong footed. Counterparties, including banks, continued to collect
collateral for marks to market. What they were not collateralized against was the losses that might
have occurred when prices moved even further and market liquidity dried up in a fire sale.
Supervisors of banks and security firms must assess whether current procedures regarding
stress testing and counterparty assessment could have been improved to enable counterparties to
take steps to insulate themselves better from LTCM's debacle. More important will be the
assessment of whether those procedures are adequate for the future. But this is an area in which
much work has been ongoing. During the fourth quarter of 1997 and the first quarter of 1998,
supervision staff of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York and the Board met with managers at
several major New York banking institutions to discuss their current relationships with hedge funds,
updating a similar study conducted 3-1/2 years earlier.
Fourth, does the fact that investors have lost most of their capital and creditors may take
some losses on their exposure to LTCM call for direct regulation of hedge funds? It is questionable
whether hedge funds can be effectively directly regulated in the United States alone. While their
financial clout may be large, hedge funds' physical presence is small. Given the amazing
communication capabilities available virtually around the globe, trades can be initiated from almost

-10-

any location. Indeed, most hedge funds are only a short step from cyberspace. Any direct U.S.
regulations restricting their flexibility will doubtless induce the more aggressive funds to emigrate
from under our jurisdiction. The best we can do in my judgment is what we do today: Regulate
them indirectly through the regulation of the sources of their funds. We are thus able to monitor
far better hedge funds' activity, especially as they influence U.S financial markets. If the funds move
abroad, our oversight will diminish.
In the first line of risk defense, if I may put it that way, are hedge funds' lenders and
counterparties. Commercial and investment banks especially have the analytic skills to judge the
degree of risk to which the funds are exposed. Their self interest has, with few exceptions but
including the one we are discussing today, controlled the risk posed by hedge funds. Banking
supervisors are the second line of risk defense in their examination of lending procedures for safety
and soundness. We neither try, nor should we endeavor, to micro-manage bank lending activity.
We have nonetheless built up significant capabilities in evaluating the complex lending practices in
OTC derivatives markets and hedge funds. If, somehow, hedge funds were barred worldwide, the
American financial system would lose the benefits conveyed by their efforts, including arbitraging
price differentials away. The resulting loss in efficiency and contribution to financial value added
and the nation's standard of living would be a high price to pay—to my mind, too high a price.
Fifth, how much weight should concerns about moral hazard be given when designing
mechanisms for governmental regulation of markets? By way of example, we should note that were
banks required by the market, or their regulator, to hold 40 percent capital against assets as they did
after the Civil War, there would, of course, be far less moral hazard and far fewer instances of firesale market disruptions. At the same time, far fewer banks would be profitable, the degree of
financial intermediation less, capital would be more costly, and the level of output and standards of

-11living decidely lower. Our current economy, with its wide financial safety net, fiat money, and
highly leveraged financial institutions, has been a conscious choice of the American people since the
1930s. We do not have the choice of accepting the benefits of the current system without its costs.
Conclusion
For so long as there have been financial markets, participants have had on occasion to
weigh the costs and, especially, the externalities associated with fire-sale liquidations of troubled
entities against short-term assistance to tide the firms over for a time. It was such a balancing of
near-term costs and longer-term benefits that presumably led J.P. Morgan to convene the leading
bankers of his age—both commercial and investment—in his library in 1907 to address the severe
panic of that year. Such episodes were recognized as among those rare occasions when otherwise
highly effective markets seize up and temporary ad hoc responses were required. The convening of
LTCM investors and lenders last week at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York could be viewed
in that long tradition. It should similarly be viewed as a rare occasion, warranted because of the
potential for serious disruptions to markets. We must also remain mindful where to draw the line at
which public-sector involvement ends. The efforts last week were limited to facilitating a privatesector agreement and had no implications for Federal Reserve resources or policies.