View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10 0 0 a m E S T
January 30,1998

Statement of
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on Banking and Financial Services
U S House of Representatives
Washington, D C
January 30,1998

The global financial system has been evolving rapidly in recent years New technology
has radically reduced the costs of borrowing and lending across traditional national borders,
facilitating the development of new instruments and drawing in new players One result has been
a massive increase in capital flows Information is transmitted instantaneously around the world,
and huge shifts in the supply and demand for funds naturally follow
This burgeoning global system has been demonstrated to be a highly efficient structure
that has significantly facilitated cross-border trade in goods and services and, accordingly, has
made a substantial contribution to standards of living worldwide Its efficiency exposes and
punishes underlying economic weakness swiftly and decisively Regrettably, it also appears to
have facilitated the transmission of financial disturbances far more effectively than ever before
As I testified before this Committee three years ago, the then emerging Mexican crisis
was the first such episode associated with our new high-tech international financial system The
current Asian cnsis is the second
We do not as yet fully understand the new system's dynamics We are learning fast, and
need to update and modify our institutions and practices to reduce the nsks inherent in the new
regime Meanwhile, we have to confront the current cnsis with the institutions and techniques
we have
Many argue that the current cnsis should be allowed to run its course without support
from the International Monetary Fund or the bilateral financial backing of other nations They
assert that allowing this cnsis to play out, while doubtless having additional negative effects on
growth in Asia, and engendenng greater spill-overs onto the rest of the world, is not likely to
have a large or lasting impact on the United States and the world economy
They may well be correct in their judgment There is, however, a small but not negligible
probability that the upset in East Asia could have unexpectedly negative effects on Japan, Latin
America, and eastern and central Europe that, in turn, could have repercussions elsewhere,

-2including the United States Thus, while the probability of such an outcome may be small, its
consequences, in my judgment, should not be left solely to chance We have observed that
global financial markets, as currently organized, do not always achieve an appropriate
equilibrium, or at least require time to stabilize
Opponents of IMF support also argue that the substantial financial backing, by
cushioning the losses of imprudent investors, could exacerbate moral hazard Moral hazard
arises when someone can reap the rewards from their actions when things go well but do not
suffer the full consequences when things go badly Such a reward structure, obviously, could
encourage excessive risk taking To be sure, this is a problem, though with respect to Asia some
investors have to date suffered substantial losses Asian equity losses, excluding Japan, since
June 1997 worldwide are estimated to have exceeded $700 billion of which more than
$30 billion has been lost by U S investors Substantial further losses have been recorded in
bonds and real estate
Moreover, the policy conditionality, associated principally with IMF lending, which
dictates economic and financial discipline and structural change, helps to mitigate some of the
moral hazard concerns Such conditionahty is also critical to the success of the overall
stabilization effort As I will be discussing in a moment, at the root of the problems is poor
public policy that has resulted in misguided investments and very weak financial sectors
Convincing a sovereign nation to alter destructive policies that impair its own performance and
threaten contagion to its neighbors is best handled by an international financial institution, such
as the IMF What we have in place today to respond to crises should be supported even as we
work to improve those mechanisms and institutions
Accordingly, I fully back the Administration's request to augment the financial resources
of the IMF—U S participation in the New Arrangements to Borrow and an increase in the U S
quota in the IMF Hopefully, neither will turn out not to be needed, and no funds will be drawn

-3But it is better to have it available if that turns out not to be the case and quick response to a
pending crisis is essential I also believe it is important to have mechanisms, such as the
Treasury Department's Exchange Stabilization Fund, that permit the United States in exceptional
circumstances to provide temporary bilateral financial support, often on short notice, under
appropriate conditions and on occasion in cooperation with other countries
In my testimony before this Committee in mid-November, I endeavored to outline the
roots of the current crisis This morning I should like to carry the analysis a bit further
Companies in Korea and many other Asian countries have become formidable
world-class producers in a number of manufacturing sectors using advanced technologies, but
contmued very rapid growth Growth, however, was destined to slow

Asian economies to varying degrees over the last half century have tried to combine rapid
growth with a much higher mix of government-directed production than has been evident in the
essentially market-driven economies of the West Through government mducements, a number
of select, more sophisticated manufacturing technologies borrowed from the advanced market
economies were applied to these generally low-productivity and, hence, low-wage economies
Thus, for selected products, exports became competitive with those of the market economies,
engendering rapid overall economic growth
There was, however, an inevitable limit to how far this specialized Asian economic
regime could develop As the process broadened beyond a few select applications of advanced
technologies, overall productivity continued to increase and the associated nse in the average real
wage in these economies blunted somewhat the competitive advantage enjoyed initially As a
consequence of the slackening of export expansion caused in part by losses in competitiveness
because of exchange rates that were pegged to the dollar, which was appreciating against the yen,
aggregate economic growth slowed somewhat, even before the current crisis

-4For years, domestic savings and rapidly increasing capital inflows had been directed by
governments into investments that banks were required to finance As I pointed out in previous
testimony, lacking a true market test, much of that investment was unprofitable So long as
growth was vigorous, the adverse consequences of this type of non-market allocation of
resources were masked Moreover, in the context of pegged exchange rates that were presumed
to continue, if not indefinitely, at least beyond the term of the loan, banks and nonbanks were
willing to take the risk to borrow dollars (unhedged) to obtain the dollar-denominated interest
rates that were invariably lower than those available in domestic currency Western, especially
American investors, diversified some of their huge capital gams of the 1990s into East Asian
investments In hindsight, it is evident that those economies could not provide adequate
profitable opportunities at reasonable risk to absorb such a surge in funds This surge, together
with distortions caused by government planning, has resulted in huge losses With the inevitable
slowdown, business losses and nonperforrming bank loans surged Banks' capital eroded rapidly
and, as a consequence, funding sources have dned up, as fears of defaults have nsen
dramatically In an environment of weak financial systems, lax supervisory regimes, and vague
guarantees about depositor or creditor protections, bank runs have occurred in several countnes
and reached cnsis proportions in Indonesia Uncertainty and retrenchment have escalated The
state of confidence so necessary to the functioning of any economy has been torn asunder
Vicious cycles of ever nsing and reinforcing fears have become contagious Some exchange
rates have fallen to levels that are understandable only in the context of a ventable collapse of
confidence in the functioning of an economy
A similar breakdown was also evident in Mexico three years ago, albeit to a somewhat
lesser degree In late 1994, the government was rapidly losing reserves in a vain effort to support
a currency that had come under attack when the authonties failed to act expeditiously and

-5convincingly to contain a burgeoning current account deficit financed in large part by substantial
short-term flows denominated in dollars
These two recent crisis episodes have afforded us increasing insights into the dynamics of
the evolving international financial system, though there is much we do not yet understand
With the new more sophisticated financial markets punishing errant government policy
behavior far more profoundly than in the past, vicious cycles are evidently emerging more often
For once they are triggered, damage control is difficult Once the web of confidence, which
supports the financial system, is breached, it is difficult to restore quickly The loss of
confidence can trigger rapid and disruptive changes in the pattern of finance, which, in turn,
feeds back on exchange rates and asset prices Moreover, investor concerns that weaknesses
revealed in one economy may be present in others that are similarly situated means that the loss
of confidence can quickly spread to other countries
At one point the economic system appears stable, the next it behaves as though a dam has
reached a breaking point, and water (read, confidence) evacuates its reservoir The United States
experienced such a sudden change with the decline in stock prices of more than 20 percent on
October 19, 1987 There is no credible scenario that can readily explain so abrupt a change in
the fundamentals of long-term valuation on that one day Such market panic does not appear to
reflect a simple continuum from the immediately previous period The abrupt onset of such
implosions suggests the possibility that there is a marked dividing line for confidence When
crossed, prices slip into free fall—perhaps overshooting the long-term equilibrium—before
markets will stabilize
But why do these events seem to erupt without some readily evident precursor?
Certainly, the more extended the risk-taking, or more generally, the lower the discount factors
applied to future outcomes, the more vulnerable are markets to a shock that abruptly triggers a
revision in expectations and sets off a vicious cycle of contraction

-6Episodes of vicious cycles cannot be easily forecast, as our recent experience with Asia
has demonstrated The causes of such episodes are complex and often subtle In the case of
Asia, we can now say with some confidence that the economies affected by this crisis faced a
critical mass of vulnerabilities, ex ante, some were more apparent than others, but the
combination was not generally recognized as critical
Once the recent cnsis was triggered in early July with Thailand's forced abandonment of
its exchange rate peg, it was apparently the lethal combination of pegged exchange rates, high
leverage, weak banking and financial systems, and declining demand in Thailand and elsewhere
that transformed a correction into a collapse Normally the presence of these factors would have
produced a modest retrenchment, not the kind of discontinuous fall in confidence that leads to a
vicious cycle of decline But with a significant part of short-term liabilities, bank and nonbank,
denominated in foreign currencies (predominantly dollars), unhedged, the initial pressure on
domestic currencies led to a sharp crack in the fixed exchange rate structure of many East Asian
economies The belief that local currencies could, virtually without risk of loss, be converted
into dollars at any time was shattered Investors, both domestic and foreign, endeavored
en masse to convert to dollars, as confidence in the ability of the local economy to earn dollars to
meet their fixed obligations diminished Local exchange rates fell against the dollar, inducing
still further declines
The weakening of growth also led to lowered profit expectations and contracting net
capital inflows of dollars This was an abrupt change from the pronounced acceleration through
1996 and the first half of 1997 The combmation of continued strong demand for dollars to meet
debt service obligations and the slowed new supply, destabilized the previously fixed exchange
rate regime This created a marked increase in uncertainty and retrenchment, further reducing
capital inflows, still further weakening local currency exchange rates This vicious cycle will

-7contmue until either defaults or restructuring lowers debt service obligations, or the low local
exchange rates finally induce a pickup in the supply of dollars
These virulent episodes appear to be at the root of our most recent breakdowns in Mexico
and Asia Their increased prevalence may, in fact, be a defining characteristic of the new
high-tech international financial system We shall never be able to alter the human response to
shocks of uncertainty and withdrawal, we can only endeavor to reduce the unbalances that
exacerbate them
While, as indicated earlier, I do not believe we are as yet sufficiently knowledgeable of
the full complex dynamics of our increasingly developing high-tech financial system, enough
insights have been gleaned from the crises in Mexico and Asia (and previous experiences) to
enable us to list a few of the cntical tendencies toward disequilibrium and vicious cycles that will
have to be addressed if our new global economy is to limit the scope for disruptions in the future
These elements have all, in times past, been factors in international and domestic economic
disruptions, but they appear more stark in today's market
(1) Leverage
Certainly in Korea, probably in Thailand, and possibly elsewhere, a high degree of
leverage (the ratio of debt to equity) appears to be a place to start While the key role of debt in
bank balance sheets is obvious, its role in the efficient functioning of the nonbank sector is also
important Nevertheless, exceptionally high leverage often is a symptom of excessive risk taking
that leaves financial systems and economies vulnerable to loss of confidence It is not easy to
imagine the cumulative cascading of debt instruments seeking safety in a crisis when assets are
heavily funded with equity The concern is particularly relevant to banks and many other
financial intermediaries, whose assets typically are less liquid than their liabilities and so depend
on confidence in the payment of liabilities for their continued viability Moreover, both financial

and nonfinancial businesses can employ high leverage to mask inadequate underlying
profitability and otherwise have inadequate capital cushions to match their volatile environments
Excess leverage in nonfinancial business can create problems for lenders including their
banks, these problems can, in turn, spread to other borrowers that rely on these lenders
Fortunately, since lending by nonfinancial firms to other businesses is less prevalent than bank
lending to other banks, direct contagion is less likely But the leverage of South Korea's
chaebols, because of their size and the pervasive distress, has clearly been an important cause of
bank problems with their systemic implications
(2) Interest Rate and Currency Risk
Banks, when confronted with a generally rising yield curve, have a tendency to incur
interest rate or liquidity risk by lending long and funding short This exposes them to shocks,
especially those institutions that have low capital-asset ratios When financial intermediaries, in
addition, seek low-cost, unhedged, foreign currency funding, the dangers of depositor runs,
following a fall in the domestic currency, escalate
(3) Weak Banking Systems
Banks play a crucial role in the financial market infrastructure When they are
undercapitalized, have lax lending standards, and are subjected to weak supervision and
regulation, they become a source of systemic risk both domestically and internationally
(4)

Interbank Funding, especially in foreign currencies
Despite its importance for distributing savings to their most valued use, short-term

interbank funding, especially cross border may turn out to be the Achilles' heel of an
international financial system that is subject to wide variations in financial confidence This
phenomenon, which is all too common in our domestic expenence, may be particularly
dangerous in an international setting

-9(5) Moral Hazard
The expectation that monetary authorities or international financial institutions will come
to the rescue of failing financial systems and unsound investments has clearly engendered a
significant element of moral hazard and excessive risk taking The dividing line between public
and private liabilities, too often, becomes blurred
(6)

Weak Central Banks
To effectively support a stable currency, central banks need to be independent, meaning

that their monetary policy decisions are not subject to the dictates of political authorities
(7)

Securities Markets
Recent adverse banking experiences have emphasized the problems that can arise if banks

are almost the sole source of intermediation Their breakdown induces a sharp weakening in

economic growth A wider range of nonbank institutions, including viable debt and equity
markets, are important safeguards of economic activity when banking fails
(8)

Inadequate Legal Structures
Finally, an effective competitive market system requires a rule of law that severely

delimits government's arbitrary intrusion into commercial disputes
Defaults and restructuring will not always be avoidable Indeed "creative destruction," as
Joseph Schumpeter put it, is often an important element of renewal in a dynamic market
economy, but an efficient bankruptcy statute is required to aid in this process, including in the
case of cross-border defaults
* **
Interest and currency risk taking, excess leverage, weak financial systems, and interbank
funding are all encouraged by the existence of a safety net In a domestic context, it is difficult
to achieve financial balance without a regulatory structure that seeks to simulate the market
incentives that would tend to control these financial elements if there were not broad safety nets

-10It is even more difficult to achieve such a balance internationally among sovereign governments
operating out of different cultures Thus, governments have developed a patchwork of
arrangements and conventions governing the functioning of the international financial system
that I believe will need to be thoroughly reviewed and altered as necessary to fit the needs of the
new global environment A review of supervision and regulation of private financial institutions,
especially those that are supported by a safety net, is particularly pressing because those
institutions have played so prominent a role in the emergence of recent crises
As I have testified previously, I believe that, in this rapidly expanding international
financial system, the primary protection from adverse financial disturbances is effective
counterparty surveillance and, hence, government regulation and supervision should seek to
produce an environment in which counterparties can most effectively oversee the credit risks of
potential transactions
Here a major improvement in transparency, including both accounting and public
disclosure, is essential To be sure, counterparties often exchange otherwise confidential
information as a condition of a transaction But broader dissemination of detailed disclosures of
governments, financial institutions, and firms, is required if the risks inherent in our global
financial structure are to be contained A market system can approach an appropriate equilibrium
only if the signals to which individual market participants respond are accurate and adequate to
the needs of the adjustment process Among the important signals are product and asset prices,
interest rates, debt by maturity, detailed accounts of central banks, and private enterprises
Blinded by faulty signals, a competitive free-market system cannot reach a firm balance except
by chance In today's rapidly changing market place producers need sophisticated signals to
hone production schedules and investment programs to respond to consumer demand
There is sufficient bias in political systems of all varieties to substitute hope (read,
wishful thinking) for possibly difficult preemptive policy moves, both with respect to financial

-11systems and economic policy There is often denial and delay in instituting proper adjustments
Recent propensities to obscure the need for change have been evidenced by unreported declines
in official reserves, issuance by governments of the equivalent to foreign currency obhgations, or
unreported large forward short positions against foreign currencies It is very difficult for
political leaders to incur what they perceive as large immediate political costs to contain
problems that they see (often dimly) as only prospective
Reality eventually replaces hope, but the cost of delay is a more abrupt and disruptive
adjustment than would have been required if action had been more preemptive Increased
transparency for busmesses, financial institutions, and governments is a key ingredient in
fostering more discipline on pnvate transactors and on government policymakers Increased
transparency can counter political bias in part by exposing for all to see the risks to stability of
current policies as they develop Under such conditions, failure to act would also be perceived as
having political costs I suspect that recent political foot dragging by governments in both
developed and developing countries on the issue of greater transparency is credible evidence of
its power and significance
Transparency, which is so important to foster safe and sound lending practices, is, of
course, less relevant for local currency lending if banks are guaranteed with sovereign credits
Moreover, transparency becomes especially difficult to create for orgamzations and corporations
with large interlocking ownerships Cross holdings of stock lead too often to lending on the
basis of association, not economic value
The list of problems that must be addressed to achieve balance in our future global
financial system could be significantly extended, but let me end with a notion that is relevant also
to today's crisis It is becoming increasingly evident that supervision and regulation should
address excess nonperforming loans expeditiously The expected values of the losses on these
loans are, of course, a subtraction from capital But since these estimates are uncertain, they

-12embody an additional risk premium that reduces the markets' best estimate of the size of effective
equity capital even if capital is replenished It is, hence, far better to remove these dubious assets
and their associated risk premium from bank balance sheets, and dispose of them separately,
preferably promptly
***
As a consequence of the unwinding of market restrictions and regulations, and the rapid
mcrease in technology, the international financial system has expanded at a pace far faster than
either domestic GDP or cross-border trade To reduce the risk of systemic cnses in such an
environment, an enhanced regime of market incentives, involving greater sensitivity to market
signals, more information to make those signals more robust, and broader secunties
markets-coupled with better supervision—is essential Obviously appropnate macropolicies, as
ever, are assumed But attention to microdetails is becoming increasingly pressing
Nonetheless, it is reasonable to expect that despite endeavors at risk containment and
prevention the system may fail in some instances, tnggenng vicious cycles and all the associated
contagion for innocent bystanders A backup source of international financial support provided
only with agreed conditions to address underlying problems, the task assigned to the IMF, can
play an essential stabilizing role The availability of such support must be limited because its
size cannot be expected to expand at the pace of the mtemational financial system I doubt if
there will be worldwide political support for that
In closing, I should like to stress that the significant degree of volatility that contmues to
exist in Asian markets mdicates exceptionally high levels of uncertainty, bordenng on panic It
is not reasonable to expect that the substantial investments needed to implement meaningful
structural reforms can proceed very far until we observe a simmering down of frenetic changes in
asset pnces and exchange rates

-13That is likely to result only when stability of banking and financial systems generally is
achieved As I indicated in my November testimony, the failure of the fragile banking systems
of East Asia to hold steady as financial pressures increased was a defining element in the
developing crisis The stabilization of those banking systems is crucial, if confidence, that has
been so thoroughly undercut in this most debilitating crisis, is to be restored